jbosse sur le D - retour accueil
git clone git://bebou.netlib.re/darwin
Log | Files | Refs |
SeekingWisdom.txt (809988B)
1 Seeking Wisdom: From Darwin to Munger Peter Bevelin PCA Publications L.L.C. (2007)/Riddler Rating: **** 2 3 [1mPeter Bevelin begins his fascinating book with Confucius' great wisdom: [0m[1m[3m"A man who has committed a mistake and doesn't correct it, is committing another mistake." [0m[0mSeeking Wisdom is the result of Bevelin's 4 learning about attaining wisdom. 5 6 His quest for wisdom originated partly from making mistakes himself and observing those of others but also from the philosophy of super-investor and Berkshire Hathaway Vice Chairman Charles Munger. A man 7 whose simplicity and clarity of thought was unequal to anything Bevelin had seen. In addition to naturalist Charles Darwin and Munger, Bevelin cites an encyclopedic range of thinkers: from first-century BCE 8 Roman poet Publius Terentius to Mark Twain-from Albert Einstein to Richard Feynman-from 16th Century French essayist Michel de Montaigne to Berkshire Hathaway Chairman Warren Buffett. In the book, he 9 describes ideas and research findings from many different fields. This book is for those who love the constant search for knowledge. It is in the spirit of Charles Munger, who says, "All I want to know is 10 where I'm going to die so I'll never go there." 11 12 There are roads that lead to unhappiness. An understanding of how and why we can "die" should help us avoid them. We can't eliminate mistakes, but we can prevent those that can really hurt us. Using exemplars 13 of clear thinking and attained wisdom, Bevelin focuses on how our thoughts are influenced, why we make misjudgments and tools to improve our thinking. 14 15 Bevelin tackles such eternal questions as: 16 17 Why do we behave like we do? What do we want out of life? What interferes with our goals? Read and study this wonderful multidisciplinary exploration of wisdom. It may change the way you think and act in 18 business and in life. 19 20 [1mSEEKING WISDOM [0m 21 22 FROM DARWIN 23 24 TO MUNGER 25 26 PETER BEVELIN 27 28 CONTENTS 29 30 Part One One 31 32 Two 33 34 Three 35 36 Part Two One Two 37 38 Part Three One 39 40 Two 41 42 Three Four Five Six Seven Eight Nine 43 44 Part Four One 45 46 Two Three Four Five Six Seven Eight Nine Ten Eleven Twelve 47 48 WHAT INFLUENCES OUR THINKING 49 50 Our anatomy sets the limits for our behavior Evolution selected the connections that produce useful behavior for survival and reproduction Adaptive behavior for survival and reproduction 51 52 THE PSYCHOLOGY OF MISJUDGMENTS 53 54 Misjudgments explained by psychology Psychological reasons for mistakes 55 56 THE PHYSICS AND MATHEMATICS OF MISJUDGMENTS 57 58 Systems thinking Scale and limits Causes 59 60 Numbers and their meaning 61 62 Probabilities and number of possible outcomes Scenarios 63 64 Coincidences and miracles Reliability of case evidence Misrepresentative evidence 65 66 GUIDELINES TO BETTER THINKING 67 68 Models of reality Meaning Simplification Rules and filters Goals Alternatives Consequences Quantification Evidence 69 70 Backward thinking Risk 71 72 Attitudes 73 74 Charles T. Munger speech on prescriptions for guaranteed misery in life Wisdom from Charles T. Munger and Warren E. Buffett 75 76 Probability Checklists 77 78 To my two children, Victor and Sonia 79 80 SEEKING WISDOM 81 82 From Darwin to Munger 83 84 By Peter Bevelin Third Edition 85 86 Copyright© 2003, 2005, 2007 by Post Scriptum AB. All rights reserved. 87 88 For permission to use copyrighted material, grateful acknowledgment is made to 89 90 the copyright holders on next page, which is hereby made part ofthis copyright page. The author and publisher extend their apologies for any errors ofomissions and encourage any copyright owners inadvertently 91 missed to contact them. Any errors, oversight or omissions will be corrected in subsequent editions. 92 93 Original publisher Post Scriptum AB 94 95 Stora Nygatan 25, S-211 37 Malmo Sweden Fax + 46 40 97 42 66 96 97 PCA Publications L.L.C. Published under license from Post Scriptum AB, copyright owner. 98 99 Disclaimer ofWarranties and Exclusions ofDamages: The author and publisher make no representations or warranties with respect to the accuracy or completeness ofthe contents ofthis book and specifically 100 disclaim any implied warranties ofmerchantability or fitness for a particular purpose. The advice and strategies contained herein may not be suitable for your situation. You should consult with a professional 101 advisor before making any financial or life style decisions. Neither the publisher nor the author shall be liable for any loss of profit or any other commercial damages, including but not limited to special, 102 incidental, consequential, or other damages. 103 104 Some ofthe names, characters, places and incidents in this book are products of the author's imagination or are used fictitiously. Any resemblance to actual events, locales, or persons, living or dead, is 105 entirely coincidental. 106 107 Printed in the United States ofAmerica by Walsworth Publishing Company. ISBN-13: 978-1-57864-428-5 (hard cover: alk. paper) 108 109 ISBN-IO: 1-57864-428-3 (hard cover: alk. paper) 110 111 For more information, please contact Peter Bevelin, AB Possessor Stora Nygatan 25, S-211 37 Malmo, Sweden or by e-mail to p.bevelin@possessor.se 112 113 - PERMISSION ACKNOWLEDGMENTS - 114 115 Excerpt from "Track record is everything." From Across the Board, October 1991. Copyright 116 117 © 1991 by Across the Board. Reprinted by permission of The Conference Board Review; all rights reserved. 118 119 Excerpts from Berkshire Hathaway Inc. Annual Reports and An Owner's Manual. 120 121 Copyright © 1977-2006 by Warren E. Buffett. Reprinted by permission of Warren E. Buffett; all rights reserved. 122 123 Excerpts from Darwin, C.R. 1871. lhe decent of man, and selecion in relation to sex. 124 125 London: John Murray, 1st edition. Volume 1. Copyright © 2002-2007 lhe Complete Work of Charles Darwin Online - University of Cambridge - CRASSH 17 Mill Lane - Cambridge; all rights reserved. 126 127 Excerpt from Forbes Magazine. "The not-so-silent partner" by Robert Lenzner and David 128 129 S. Fondiller, January 22, 1996. Copyright © 1996 by Forbes Inc. Reprinted by permission of Forbes Magazine© 2009 Forbes Media LLC; all rights reserved. 130 131 Excerpt from Cheating Monkeys and Citizen Bees: lhe Nature of Cooperation in Animals and 132 133 Humans, by Lee Dugatkin. Copyright © 1999 by Lee Dugatkin. Reprinted with the permission of The Free Press, a Division of Simon & Schuster, Inc. 134 135 Excerpt from Living Within Limits: Ecology, Economics, and Population Taboos, by Garrett Hardin. Copyright © 1995 by Oxford University Press, Inc. Reprinted by permission of Oxford University Press, Inc.; all 136 rights reserved. 137 138 Excerpt from The Ostrich Factor: Our Population Myopia, by Garrett Hardin. Copyright 139 140 © 1999 by Oxford University Press, Inc. Reprinted by permission of Oxford University Press, Inc.; all rights reserved. 141 142 Excerpt from lhe Psychology ofSpeculation, by Henry Howard Harper. Copyright© 1966 143 144 by Fraser Publishing Company. Reprinted by permission of Fraser Publishing Company. Excerpt from "Speed, Simplicity, Self-Confidence: An Interview with Jack Welch." 145 146 Reprinted by permission of the Harvard Business Review. From "Speed, Simplicity, Self Confidence: An Interview with Jack Welch" by N. Tichy & R. Charan, Sept/Okt 1989. Copyright© 1989 by the Harvard Business 147 School Publishing Corporation; all rights reserved. Excerpt from OfPermanent Value: lhe Story ofWarren Buffett, by Andy Kilpatrick. Copyright 148 149 © 2000 by Andrew Kilpatrick. Reprinted by permission of Andrew Kilpatrick; all rights reserved. 150 151 Charles T. Munger. 152 153 Excerpts from Outstanding Investor Digest (OID) are reprinted by permission from Outstanding Investor Digest, Inc. Copyright © 1986-2006; 295 Greenwich Street, Box 282, New York, NY 10007. All rights 154 reserved. Telephone: (212) 925 3885. Website: www.oid.com. Excerpts from "What is science?" by Richard Feynman. Reprinted with permission from lhe Physics Teacher, Vol. 7, Issue 6, Page 313-320, 1969. 155 Copyright © 1969, American 156 157 Association of Physics Teachers, all rights reserved. 158 159 Excerpt from transcript #105 of Adam Smith®'s Money Game. Copyright© 1998 by Adam Smith® Educational Productions Ltd. Reprinted by permission of Adam Smith® Educational Productions Ltd.; all rights reserved. 160 161 Excerpt from lhe lheory of Investment Value, by John Burr Williams. Copyright © 1938 by John Burr Williams Jr. and John Burr Williams Family Trust. Published in 1997 by Fraser Publishing Company. Reprinted by 162 permission of John Burr Williams Jr. and John Burr Williams Family Trust; all rights reserved. 163 164 - ACKNOWLEDGMENTS - 165 166 Thanks to Charles Munger and Warren Buffett for their kind permission to quote extensively from their work. Thanks to Charles Munger who generously took the time to read the whole original manuscript. Thanks 167 to Warren Buffett for his early encouragement of my first private memorandum - the foundation for this book - and his compliments on this work. I am deeply grateful to Peter Kaufman for his generosity in 168 helping me getting this Third Edition into wide circulation. I am delighted to partner with him. 169 170 Thanks also to Jim Ross at Hudson BookSellers in Omaha for his fine job in promoting the earlier editions of this book. Thanks also to Rose-Marie Strandberg at Printing. Thanks to Henry Emerson who permitted 171 me to quote from Outstanding Investor Digest. Thanks to Ralph Greenspan at the Neurosciences Institute for many fruitful discussions. Thanks also to Gerald Edelman. Always a source of knowledge and joy. I 172 would also like to thank the following people who kindly commented on some of the issues covered in this book: Tom 173 174 Ackerman, Edward Beltrami, Charles Brenner, Nico Bunzeck, Bent Flyvbjerg, Daniel Gilbert, Mark Graber, Peter Gardenfors, Tom Hamill, Mathew Hayward, Vibeke Horstmann, John Ioannidis, Andrew Kilpatrick, Frank 175 Lambert, Chris Landsea, Jennifer Lerner, Richard Lucas, Ronald Newburgh, Robert Rauber, Robert Sapolsky, Kaveh Shojania, 176 177 Maria Stromme, Philip Swigard, Nassim Taleb, W illiam Thompson, and Carl Zimmer. The reader shouldn't assume that any of these people agree with what I have written in this book. Any misconceptions, 178 deficiences or errors are mine alone. 179 180 Thanks to JoAnna Barrett who gave valuable editing advice. 181 182 Finally, I wish to thank my wife, Monica, who read every sentence with critical eyes. Whatever I have achieved in life I owe her. She is the wind beneath my wings. Monica, you are the best. 183 184 Peter Bevelin 185 186 INTRODUCTION 187 188 PART ONE 189 190 - CONTENTS - 191 192 WHAT INFLUENCES OUR THINKING? 193 194 1 195 196 One 197 198 Our anatomy sets the limits for our behavior 199 200 3 201 202 Two 203 204 Evolution selected the connections that produce useful behavior 205 206 for survival and reproduction 207 208 11 209 210 Three 211 212 Adaptive behavior for survival and reproduction 213 214 21 215 216 PART Two 217 218 THE PSYCHOLOGY OF MISJUDGMENTS 219 220 37 221 222 One 223 224 Misjudgments explained by psychology 225 226 39 227 228 Two 229 230 Psychological reasons for mistakes 231 232 42 233 234 PART THREE 235 236 THE PHYSICS AND MATHEMATICS OF MISJUDGMENTS 237 238 115 239 240 One 241 242 Systems thinking 243 244 120 245 246 Two 247 248 Scale and limits 249 250 129 251 252 Three 253 254 Causes 255 256 135 257 258 Four 259 260 Numbers and their meaning 261 262 141 263 264 Five 265 266 Probabilities and number ofpossible outcomes 267 268 144 269 270 Six 271 272 Scenarios 273 274 158 275 276 Seven 277 278 Coincidences and miracles 279 280 165 281 282 Eight 283 284 Reliability of case evidence 285 286 169 287 288 Nine 289 290 Misrepresentative evidence 291 292 176 293 294 PART FouR 295 296 GUIDELINES TO BETTER THINKING 297 298 187 299 300 One 301 302 Models of reality 303 304 189 305 306 Two 307 308 Meaning 309 310 Three 311 312 Simplification 313 314 212 315 316 Four 317 318 Rules and filters 319 320 218 321 322 Five 323 324 Goals 325 326 223 327 328 Six 329 330 Alternatives 331 332 225 333 334 Seven 335 336 Consequences 337 338 228 339 340 Eight 341 342 Quantification 343 344 231 345 346 Nine 347 348 Evidence 349 350 238 351 352 Ten 353 354 Back ward thinking 355 356 244 357 358 Eleven 359 360 Risk 361 362 248 363 364 Twelve 365 366 Attitudes 367 368 252 369 370 Appendix One 371 372 Charles T. Munger speech on prescriptions for 373 374 guaranteed misery in life 375 376 260 377 378 Appendix Two 379 380 Wisdom from Charles T. Munger and Warren E. Buffett 381 382 264 383 384 Appendix Three 385 386 Probability 387 388 278 389 390 Appendix Four 391 392 Checklists 393 394 287 395 396 Source Notes 397 398 297 399 400 199 401 402 Bibliography 307 403 404 - INTRODUCTION - 405 406 A man who has committed a mistake and doesn't correct it, is committing another mistake. 407 408 - Confucius (Chinese thinker, 6th to 5th Century BC) 409 410 Why do we behave like we do? American writer Mark Twain once wrote: "The character of the human race never changes, it is permanent." Why is it so? 411 412 What do we want out of life? To be healthy, happy with our families, in our work, etc? What interferes with this? Isn't it often emotions like fear, anger, worry, disappointment, stress, and sadness caused by 413 problems, mistakes, losses, or unreal expectations? Maybe we misjudged people, situations, the time or some investment.We chose the wrong occupation, spouse, investment, or place to live. Why? 414 415 This book is about searching for wisdom. It is in the spirit of Charles Munger, Vice Chairman of Berkshire Hathaway, Inc. who says, ''All I want to know is where I'm going to die so I'll never go there." 416 There are roads that lead to unhappiness. An understanding of how and why we can "die" should help us avoid them. 417 418 This book focuses on how our thoughts are influenced, why we make misjudgments and tools to improve our thinking. If we understand what influences us, we might avoid certain traps and understand why others 419 act like they do. And if we learn and understand what works and doesn't work and find some framework for reasoning, we will make better judgments. We can't eliminate mistakes, but we can prevent those that 420 can really hurt us. 421 422 How do we achieve wisdom? It is hard to improve ourselves simply by looking at our own mistakes. The best way to learn what, how and why things work is to learn from others. Charles Munger says, "I believe in 423 the discipline of mastering the best that other people have ever figured out.I don't believe in just sitting down and trying to dream it all up yourself Nobody's that smart. " 424 425 The 16th Century French essayist Michel de Montaigne said: ''Anyone who 426 427 wishes to be cured of ignorance must first admit to it." My quest for wisdom originates partly from making mistakes myself and observing those of others but also from the philosophy of Charles Munger. A man 428 whose simplicity and clarity of thought is unequal to anything I have seen. What especially influenced me 429 430 were his lectures on worldly wisdom, many of them reproduced in the newsletter Outstanding Investor Digest. In one speech, he said that the best way to achieve wisdom was to learn the big ideas that underlie 431 reality. In another, he referred to Charles Darwin as one of the best thinkers who ever lived. Darwin's lesson is that even people who aren't geniuses can outthink the rest of mankind if they develop certain 432 thinking habits. 433 434 To learn more about Darwin's habits, I started to read his autobiography and other writings about him. I found him to be a fascinating character and a wonderful lesson on objectivity. In his autobiography, 435 Darwin said: 436 437 I think that I am superior to the common run of men in noticing things which easily escape attention, and in observing them carefully. My industry has been nearly as great as it could have been in the 438 observation and collection of facts. What is far more important, my love of natural science has been steady and ardent... From my early youth I have had the strongest desire to understand or explain whatever 439 I observed, that is, to group all facts under some general laws. These causes combined have given me the patience to reflect or ponder for any number of years over any unexplained problem. As far as I can 440 judge, I am not apt to follow blindly the lead of other men. I have steadily endeavoured to keep my mind free so as to give up any hypothesis, however much beloved (and I cannot resist forming one on every 441 subject), as soon as facts are shown to be opposed to it. 442 443 Darwin reinforced my interest in understanding human behavior. To improve my own thinking, I read books in biology, psychology, neuroscience, physics, and mathematics. fu the 17th Century French philosopher 444 Rene Descartes said: "The reading of all good books is like conversation with the finest minds of past centuries." 445 446 I started to write down what I learned. The result is this book. The ideas in it are built largely from the works and thoughts of others. fu the Roman poet Publius Terentius (c.190-159 BC) wrote: "Nothing has 447 yet been said that's not been said before." I have condensed what others have written in a usable form and added my own conclusions. 448 449 In this book you find a broad-based collection of wisdom from outstanding scientists like Darwin, Albert Einstein, Richard Feynman, and two of the world's most successful businessmen and investors, Charles 450 Munger and the Chairman of Berkshire Hathaway, Warren Buffett. Albert Einstein once said that there are only a few enlightened people with a lucid mind and good taste within a century. Warren Buffett and 451 Charles Munger are such people. I owe a great debt to them whose messages have been instructional as well as encouraging. lfl had listened 452 453 11 454 455 to them earlier in my life - so many expensive mistakes would have been avoided. They are my heroes! 456 457 I advise all of you to read the annual reports of Berkshire Hathaway and Wesco Financial (Charles Munger is chairman). These reports are the best educational tools about how to think about investing and 458 business. The lessons also show us how to behave in life. 459 460 This book has four parts. First, I explore what influences our thinking. This serves as a foundation. In the second part, I give examples of psychological reasons for misjudgments. The third part explores 461 reasons for misjudgments caused both by our psychology and a lack of considering some basic ideas from physics and mathematics. In the final part I reveal tools for better thinking. The appendix contains a 462 speech from Charles Munger and quotes from Munger and Warren Buffett. It also contains checklists. Checklists often eliminate biases and make it easier for us to be sure we've covered the important things. 463 464 Why spend time studying wisdom? Charles Munger gives a compelling reason: "I think it's a huge mistake not to absorb elementary worldly wisdom if you're capable of doing it because it makes you better able to 465 serve others, it makes you better able to serve yourself and it makes life more fun.. .I'm passionate about wisdom. I'm passionate about accuracy and some kinds of curiosity." 466 467 This book is for those who love the constant search for knowledge. I have focused on explaining timeless ideas. The number of pages I have devoted to each idea does not reflect on its importance. My goal is 468 to lay the foundation. 469 470 16th Century Spanish writer Miguel de Cervantes said: "He that publishes a book runs a very great hazard, since nothing can be more impossible than to compose one that may secure the approbation of every 471 reader." You may feel that much has been ignored and what is left has been exaggerated. Since I am writing this, I take full responsibility for the content. Any mistakes or inaccuracies are my responsibility. 472 If you, the reader, are convinced that I am dearly wrong about anything in this book, please send me an e-mail at the address given in the beginning of the book. 473 474 I have cited quotations from a wide range of sources. Some books and material have been especially useful. Obviously, books about Charles Darwin. Also speeches and reports from Charles Munger and Warren 475 Buffett. Most of these quotes are excerpted text from the excellent newsletter, Outstanding Investor Digest. The reader should refer to the source note section for the source of the excerpt. Robert Cialdini, 476 Regents Professor of Psychology at Arizona State University, gives an excellent summary of findings in social psychology in his great book Influence. Psychology Professors Daniel Kahneman and the late Amos 477 478 lll 479 480 Tversky's work on decision-making has also been useful. Richard Feynman (1918-1988), perhaps the most brilliant and influential physicist of modern times, was also a spellbinding teacher. I love his books and 481 autobiographies. The late Human Ecology Professor Garrett Hardin is one of my favorites. His books are treasures and offer many ways for dear thinking. I have also been fortunate to visit the Neurosciences 482 Institute in California. Every time I'm there, I learn something new about how our brain works. 483 484 I sometimes write in terms of "we", and other times I address "you", the reader. Just remember, "you" includes me, the writer. Italian mathematician and philosopher Gian-Carlo Rota's said in Indiscrete 485 Thoughts: "The advice we give others is the advice that we ourselves need." 486 487 Instead of writing "he" or "she", I have used "he". To quote the British zoologist, Professor of the public understanding of Science at Oxford University, Richard Dawkins from The Blind"Watchmaker: "I may 488 refer to the 'reader' as 'he', but I no more think of my readers as specifically male than a French speaker thinks of a table as female." 489 490 Let's start the journey for wisdom. I hope it will be inspiring. 491 492 Peter Bevelin April 2003 493 494 The Second Edition 495 496 The Second Edition has no major changes. Two short paragraphs have been added to Part One regarding sources of genetic variation and the benefits of bacteria. Otherwise, there are only minor clarifications. I 497 have also corrected a few mistakes in the text. 498 499 January 2005 500 501 The Third Edition 502 503 The Third Edition has been revised. Some of the content in Part Two has been rearranged. New material has been added to all Parts. 504 505 February 2007 506 507 IV 508 509 - PART ONE - 510 511 [1mWHAT INFLUENCES OUR THINKING? [0m 512 513 And men should know that from nothing else but from the brain come joys, laughter and jests, and sorrows, grief, despondency and lamentations. And by this ... we acquire wisdom and knowledge, and we see and 514 hear and know what are foul and what are fair, what sweet and what unsavory... and by the same organ we become mad and delirious and fears and terrors assail us. 515 516 - Hippocrates (Greek physician 460-377 BC) 517 518 - ONE - 519 520 OUR ANATOMY SETS THE LIMITS FOR OUR BEHAVIOR 521 522 To understand the way we think and why we make misjudgments, we must first determine what influences our behavior. 523 524 Why can't we fly? 525 526 To do what we do today demands the proper anatomical foundation. To fly we need wings. To walk we need legs, to see we need eyes, and to think we need a brain. Our anatomy, physiology and biochemistry are the 527 fundamental bases for our behavior. 528 529 If we change anatomy, we change behavior. Birds can't fly if their wings are 530 531 located in an area where no bones are present to anchor them. Apes can't talk because they need speech organs and these must be positioned in a certain way. For example, a small change in how our speech 532 organs are positioned could make speech impossible. 533 534 Another example on how a change in anatomy changes behavior comes from the Neurosciences Institute in California. In one experiment, scientists took a small portion of developing brain tissue from a quail and 535 put it into the same spot of a chicken embryo. When the chick hatched, it had both quail and chicken nerve cells. Depending on what cells were transplanted, the results were either a chicken that crowed like 536 a quail or a chicken that bobbed its head like a quail. 537 538 Studies have also shown that damage to a part of the brain, the prefrontal cortex (lying behind the forehead and eyes), results in a tendency to show a high degree of disrespect for social norms, including 539 violent behavior. A classic example is that of railway construction foreman Phineas Gage. In 1848, he was victim of an explosion that drove an iron rod through the frontal region of his brain, damaging his 540 prefrontal cortex. Before the accident he was considered stable, dependable, industrious, and friendly. Phineas survived the accident, but his personality changed. He became a drifter who was unreliable, 541 arrogant, impulsive and inconsiderate. 542 543 Other studies show that damage to the amygdala- a region of the brain, linked with emotional states and social behavior - reduces the tendency to feel and 544 545 3 546 547 respond to fear. Stimulating the amygdala can elicit intense emotional reactions. In 1966, Charles Whitman killed 14 people and wounded 38 from the clock tower at the University of Texas, Austin. An autopsy 548 revealed he had a tumor pressing against his amygdala. 549 550 It is our brain, its anatomy, physiology and biochemistry and how these parts function that set the limits for how we think. But since our brain's parts also interact with our body's anatomy, physiology and 551 biochemistry, we must see brain and body together. They are part of the same system - us. 552 553 Let's consider the anatomy of our brains to get a better understanding of what influences our behavior. 554 555 What we feel and think depends on neural connections 556 557 A lot is known about the brain, but far from everything. There are many controversies and unanswered questions. 558 559 Nobel Laureate Dr. Gerald Edelman, director of the Neurosciences Institute says: 560 561 The brain is the most complicated material object in the known universe. If you attempted to count the number of connections, one per second, in the mantle of our brain (the cerebral cortex), you would finish 562 counting 32 million years later. But that is not the whole story. The way the brain is connected - its neuroanatomical pattern - is enormously intricate. Within this anatomy a remarkable set of dynamic events 563 take place in hundredths of a second and the number oflevels controlling these events, from molecules to behavior, is quite large. 564 565 Weighing only three pounds, the brain is composed of at least 100 billion nerve cells or neurons. It also contains tens of billions of other cells called glial cells supporting neurons. Neurons are connected 566 to other neurons and interact. Each neuron has a cell body with tiny branches called dendrites that receive information from other neurons. Extending from the cell body is long fibers called axons that send 567 information to other neurons. 568 569 Since it is the connections between neurons that cause our mental capacities, it is not the number of cells that is important but the number of potential connections between them. 570 571 How do neurons connect and communicate? 572 573 Every neuron can connect with other neurons at contact points, the space between one neuron and another, called synapses. When a neuron fire an electrical impulse down the axon, the impulse is released as a 574 chemical substance 575 576 4 577 578 called a neurotransmitter. When this chemical reaches the dendrite of another neuron it triggers an electrical impulse. Thereafter a series of chemical reactions begins. Some stimulation must happen for the 579 neuron to fire. The strength of this firing and what kind of neurotransmitter is released depends on the incoming stimuli. 580 581 How does the neurotransmitter cause the electrical impulse? On the surface of the receiving neuron are proteins called receptors and every receptor is tailor made for a specific chemical. The chemical acts as 582 a key, and the receptor, or the lock, only "lets in" the right chemical. 583 584 Why does it feel good when our loved ones give us a kiss or a compliment? 585 586 It is the neurotransmitter dopamine that is being released. Dopamine is involved in the brain's reward and motivation system, and in addiction. High levels of dopamine are believed to increase feelings of 587 pleasure and relieve pain. 588 589 Another neurotransmitter is serotonin. Serotonin is linked with mood and emotion. Too much stress can lead to low levels of serotonin and low levels are associated with anxiety and depression. What happens 590 when we take an antidepressant drug? The drug increases the amount of serotonin in our brain. The drug mimics the structure of serotonin. Antidepressants don't make us happy; they just treat the state of 591 unhappiness. Observe that even if neurotransmitters and the drugs that affect them alter our mental functions, they are part of a complicated system of interactions between molecules, cells, synapses, and 592 other systems, including life experiences and environmental factors. 593 594 So far we know that the brain is a chemical system, and that neurons commu nicate with each other through the release of neurotransmitters (chemicals that carry messages between neurons). What we think and 595 feel depends on chemical reactions. And these chemical reactions are a function of how our neurons connect. What determines how these neurons connect and their patterns? Our genes and life experiences, 596 situational or environmental conditions, and a degree of 597 598 randomness. 599 600 Genes control brain chemistry but are turned on and off by the environment 601 602 What is a gene? What does it do? 603 604 Genes are what makes an individual, for example, to be built with two blue eyes, two arms, one nose, and a brain with certain architecture. 605 606 Our body is made up of different types of interconnected cells functioning together. Each cell has 46 chromosomes or a chain of genes. 23 chromosomes come from each parent. Every chromosome is made up of the 607 chemical DNA or 608 609 5 610 611 deoxyribonucleic acid. DNA is our inheritance; half is from our father and half from our mother. Genes are segments of our DNA and the units of our inheritance. A gene consists of four chemical molecules: 612 adenine, cytosine, guanine, thymine or A, C, G and T joined together in a chain. The short chemical name for a chain of any number of these molecules, in any order, is DNA. The order of these molecules 613 provides coded instructions for everything a cell does. 614 615 The job of genes is to make proteins - the building blocks oflife. Proteins are molecules that carry out most of our biological functions and are made up of amino acids. There are twenty kinds of amino acids 616 that can be used to make our skin, hair, muscles, etc. Some proteins called enzymes cause certain chemical reactions. One example is neurotransmitters. Proteins are also hormones that act as messengers 617 between our cells. 618 619 Sometimes a gene is "switched off" and can't make proteins. Messenger RNA is a genetic material that translates DNA into specific proteins. The Laureates of the Nobel Prize in Medicine, 2006, discovered a 620 mechanism called RNA interference that could "switch off" a gene by blocking this process. RNA interference plays a key role in our defenses against viral infections. 621 622 Recent studies also suggest that genes do more than make proteins. For example, there is a gene in yeast that turns on and off another protein-producing gene without making any protein itself 623 624 Every living thing uses the same genetic code - from cats to humans. This means we can transfer a single human gene into a cat and the cat "can read it" and follow its instructions. But no individual has the 625 same DNA or the same versions of genes (except for identical twins). Not all things are "spelled" alike. That's why people differ in eye color, height, etc. The closer related one living thing is to another, 626 the fewer spelling differences. But even if the differences are small, gene expression - where and when they are turned on or off and for how long - is the key. As an example take our closest relative - the 627 chimpanzee. Genetic studies show that humans and chimpanzees share at least 94% of their DNA sequences. This means that less than 6% of our DNA is responsible for the traits that make us different from 628 chimpanzees. What causes the large difference in behavior? Studies show that the human brain shows strikingly different patterns of gene expression compared to the chimpanzee's brain. 629 630 Since we inherit all of our genes from our parents, why don't we look like a mixture of them? 631 632 In most organisms, genes come in pairs. We inherit two versions of each gene for 633 634 a particular trait (for example one version for blue eyes and one for brown eyes) 635 636 6 637 638 from each parent. When a father and mother's genes combine, the effect of one gene may dominate the effect of the other. Certain characteristics are dominant. This is why a child who has one parent with blue 639 eyes and one with brown doesn't have eyes that are a blend of blue and brown. The child has brown eyes because the brown-eyed gene won the race. Blue eyes are recessive. But since the child inherited the 640 blue-eyed gene, it could still be passed on to future generations. Since the recombination of the versions happens by chance, they can always produce a new combination. On the other hand, if both the child's 641 parents have blue eyes, the child has no choice but to be blue-eyed. 642 643 Some versions of genes are dominant, in some cases they blend, and sometimes we'll see an equal expression of both versions. Since several pairs of genes govern most traits, lots of combinations are possible. 644 645 Interaction and flexibility characterize our biological functions 646 647 Does each gene have its own specific part to play? 648 649 No, we can't isolate one gene as causing something or arrange them in order of importance. They are part of an interconnected system with many possible combinations. And most genes contribute to more than one 650 characteristic. Genes can have different effects, depending on where, when and how they are switched on. Interaction is a fundamental property in biology. There are interactions between molecules, genes, 651 neurons, brain regions, cells, organs and among these individual systems. Each system does its own job but they are all coordinated to produce a functional and unique individual. 652 653 But doesn't the left and right side of the brain have different functions? Dr. Ralph Greenspan at the Neurosciences Institute says: 654 655 ... although in some sense it's poetic to speak of a "right brain/left brain'' difference. The fact of the matter is that things that are "right brain" are really happening everywhere and things that are 656 "left brain" are really happening everywhere. There are certain aspects ofit that may be more biased to one side versus another, but the brain is not highly localized in any sense at all. Everything that ever 657 happens in your brain is happening as a unification of many, many, many areas at once. 658 659 He continues: 660 661 Isaac Newton might have liked the neat view of biological systems made up of dedicated components, with causal roles that can be studied in isolation, and in which particular conditions give rise to uniquely 662 predictable responses. Charles Darwin, by contrast, might 663 664 7 665 666 have felt more at home with the idea of a complex, emergent system made up of many non-identical components, with non-exclusive roles, non-exclusive relationships, several ways of producing any given output, 667 and a great deal of slop along the way. 668 669 The most striking result of our interactive network is flexibility. A flexibility to take on new roles as conditions changes and an ability to produce the same result in different ways. For example, studies 670 show that different configurations between neurons can achieve the same result. The configuration depends on which alternatives that are available at a given moment in a given situation (since behavior 671 depends on context or situation), an individual's life experiences and an element of chance. Having alternative ways of producing the same outcome gives us a great benefit. For example, we can compensate for 672 injuries and readapt to new conditions. 673 674 Do our genes have a lift of their own? 675 676 No, gene expression depends on environmental conditions. Genes control the chemistry in the brain but need to be activated by the environment. An environmental event must switch them on, or modify their level 677 of activity, before they can start making proteins that influence neural connections. Our genes determine if we inherit a particular characteristic but it is the environment that causes our genes to make 678 proteins that produce certain "response tendencies." So our behavior emerges from the mutually dependent activity of genetic and environmental factors. 679 680 Neural connections are shaped by life experiences 681 682 The brain changes continually as a result of our experiences. Experiences produce physical changes in the brain either through new neural connections or through the generation of new neurons. Studies suggest 683 that the brain can change even during the course of a day. This means that the anatomy of the brain varies from individual to individual. Even identical twins with identical genes don't have identical brains. 684 They have had different life experiences. 685 686 Experiences are the reason that all individuals are unique. There are no individuals with exactly the same upbringing, nutrition, education, social stamping, physical, social and cultural setting. This 687 creates different convictions, habits, values and character. People behave differently because differences in their environment cause different life experiences. This is why it is sometimes hard to understand 688 other people's behavior. To do that, we must adapt to their environment and share their experiences. This is often impossible. 689 690 8 691 692 If we encounter a stressful situation, how we respond depends on what we were born with, what we have experienced, and the specific situation. Assume that a person "Sam" and you both have genes for "being 693 fearful." You are standing in a Savannah in Africa and are approached by a lion. Do both of you show the same reaction when exposed to the same situation? You are afraid but not Sam. Sam either knows that 694 this lion is tame or Sam is a lion tamer. Sam's reaction comes from his life experiences. Sam may also be genetically predisposed to react differently to certain dangers. But even if Sam has a low genetic 695 vulnerability to fear, he can develop a fear of the lion. One horrifying experience with a lion may be enough. 696 697 Behavior is influenced by our state of mind 698 699 Our life is what our thoughts make it. 700 701 Marcus Aurelius Antoninus (Roman emperor and philosopher, 121-180) 702 703 Our state of mind is a function of our life experiences and the specific situation. Assume (1) we are eating tasty chocolate, listening to wonderful music and feeling relaxed or (2) we suffer from a cold, 704 feel stressed and just ate a bad meal. If we have to make a judgment, will it be the same in both cases? Probably not, since our state of mind is different in case 1 and 2. 705 706 Can our state of mind influence our biochemistry and immune system? 707 708 It's not just what happens to us that counts - it's what we think happens to us. We convert our expectations to a biochemical reality meaning that our mental state and physical well-being are connected. 709 710 A placebo effect is a positive therapeutic effect that has nothing to do with the efficiency of a treatment, only with a patient's belief in the treatment. Whenever patients believe that a treatment will have 711 a particular physiological, behavioral, or psychological effect, they are susceptible to placebo effects. 712 713 The doctor gave me a pain-relief drug (when in fact it was a sugar pill) and after a short time I experienced significantly less pain. 714 715 A placebo is an inactive or ineffective treatment or substance (for example, sugar pills or injections with saline solution) that is often used in comparison with active treatments. Studies show that a 716 placebo can improve a patient's condition simply because the patient expects it will work. Clinical evidence shows placebos to have physical effects on the brain, just as drugs do. Studies in Sweden show that 717 a placebo activates the same brain circuits as painkilling drugs. Nine male 718 719 9 720 721 students were asked to voluntary participate in a study of painkilling drugs. Researchers first tested for the degree of pain the subjects would experience when a 48-degree Celsius metal surface was pressed 722 to the backs of their hands. The test was repeated after the subjects were given a painkilling drug. 723 724 Later the subjects were told to test two new painkilling drugs and that one of these drugs was similar to the one they earlier tested. Once more the 48-degree metal surface was pressed to the backs of their 725 hands. A man in a white coat, carrying a badge that said "professor", then entered the room. The "professor" gave the subjects intravenous injections of either an opioid (a drug acting like a drug made from 726 opium) painkiller or a placebo. During the experiment researchers scanned the subjects' brains and compared brain responses. Both the painkiller and the placebo produced the same effect. Both increased blood 727 flow in areas of the brain known to be rich in opioid receptors. Eight of the nine subjects said that the placebo produced a clear relief from the pain. 728 729 Other studies show that people who take sugar pills as a treatment for depression and other ills can undergo striking, although temporary, changes in brain activity and neural chemistry as their condition 730 improves. It has also been shown that placebos can improve blood pressure, cholesterol level and heart rate. It's like a pharmacy inside the body that has evolved during million of years of evolutionary time. 731 732 What happens when a healthy person finds out he may die? 733 734 Studies show that if people expect something to go wrong with their health, it often does. Negative expectations can influence our bodies and cause symptoms that over time may cause our body harm. In one 735 study, women who expected that they were inclined to heart attack were nearly four times as likely to die as women with similar risk factors but without these expectations. Another study found that patients 736 who were warned about the gastrointestinal side effects of taking aspirin were three times more likely to feel them. Other studies show that if people worry about drug side effects, they are more likely to 737 get them. Beliefs have biological consequences - good and bad. 738 739 Our genes and life experiences determine how neurons connect thereby influencing and setting the limits for our behavior. We were born with the basics of life. We had neural connections that regulated our 740 breathing, heartbeat, temperature, etc. How does our brain select those neural connections that produce useful behavior? Our brain is a product of evolution. 741 742 10 743 744 - Two - 745 746 EVOLUTION SELECTED THE CONNECTIONS THAT PRODUCE USEFUL BEHAVIOR FOR SURVIVAL AND REPRODUCTION 747 748 What do we mean by evolution? 749 750 Evolution is change (structural, physiological, behavioral) - which occurs over time through interaction with the environment. Paleontology Professor John Horner says in Dinosaur Lives: "When you flip through 751 the pages of the family album you're witnessing evolution at work." 752 753 The theory behind evolution is that all individuals alive today have evolved from simpler, more primitive forms oflife. Since every living thing uses the same genetic code, it is likely that life descended 754 from a distant common ancestor that had that code. If a monkey and we and any other organism trace our ancestors back far enough, we eventually find a common ancestor. 755 756 What major mechanisms are responsible for evolution and for how our brain evolved? Mutation and natural selection. 757 758 Mutations cause variations 759 760 Mutations are caused by a copying error in the sequence of A, C, G and T molecules when DNA is copied. This error in the genes "spelling" may cause a change in a protein leading to a modification in the 761 individual that inherits the gene. For example, the new instruction could be"build Peter with adifferent eye-color." Since the change is random and unpredictable, no one can tell which gene(s) may be 762 involved. 763 764 Natural selection 765 766 I have called this principle, by which each slight variation, 767 768 if usefol, is preserved, by the term Natural Selection. 769 770 Charles Darwin (British naturalist, 1809-1882) 771 772 Charles Darwin, and independently the British naturalist Alfred Russell Wallace, discovered the theory of evolution by natural selection. Darwin called his work On the Origin of Species by Means of Natural 773 Selection, or the Preservation of Favoured Races in the Struggle for Life. 774 775 Darwin was inspired by the Reverend Thomas Malthus's An Essay on the 776 777 11 778 779 Principle of Population in which Malthus wrote: "Human population grows exponentially, like compound interest in a bank account, but farm output rises at a slower, arithmetic rate; the result, human 780 population will inevitably and repeatedly outstrip its food supply." Malthus noted that population can always outstrip resources but are held in check by diseases, war, predators, and by limited resources 781 like food. 782 783 Darwin made the following three observations: 784 785 [3m(I) [0mCompetition and environmental change. In most species (a species is a group of individuals capable of producing fertile offspring; like snakes, lion, humans) there are always more offspring born than can 786 survive to adulthood and reproduce. Darwin saw two reasons for this: (1) Since there is a limited amount of resources (like food, space, mates) there is competition between individuals for these resources, 787 and (2) Since the environment changes over time and from one region to another, there are threats (predators, change in climate, isolation, diseases, change in the physical environment) to the children's 788 survival and their reproductive success. 789 790 Individual variability. Within a species, there is an enormous amount of 791 792 individual variation. No two individuals of the same species are alike in their anatomical structure, physiology or behavior (we're not an exact copy of our parents). Individuals vary in their cell structure, 793 fighting ability, and social skills. Variations make every individual unique and that variation must in some way be heritable otherwise children wouldn't resemble their parents more than they resemble other 794 individuals. 795 796 The world is not fixed but evolving. Species change, new ones arrive and 797 798 others go extinct. 799 800 Darwin called his principle natural selection. Any slight variation in traits that gives an individual an advantage in competing with other individuals of the same or different species or in adapting to 801 changes in their environment increases the chance that the individual will survive, reproduce, and pass along its characteristics to the next generation. Maybe they have greater resistance to disease, or can 802 run faster, or survive climate changes better. 803 804 Darwin used the word "selection," but nature doesn't care who gets selected for survival. Evolution has no goal. Another way to describe natural selection is as a process of elimination. Certain individuals 805 survive because they have structural, physiological, behavioral or other characteristics that prevent them from being eliminated. Those that don't have these characteristics are eliminated. Heredity enhances 806 the likelihood that the non-eliminated or "selected" variations 807 808 12 809 810 are preserved. Darwin didn't know about genetics. Therefore he couldn't know that these characteristics were caused by mutations and that they could be passed on through the genes. 811 812 After a mutation changes an individual, the environment determines if the change gives the individual an advantage. If the new trait is helpful, the mutated individual is more likely to survive, reproduce and 813 pass the new trait to his children. Take a poisonous spider as an example. Assume that a population (a group of individuals belonging to one species that occupy the same geographic/ecological niche at the 814 same time) of black widows differs in how toxic their venom is. If some spiders (mutants) are born with more toxins than others, two things could happen over time. If more toxins give an advantage in the 815 spiders' environment, more toxins might be "selected" for and the "more-toxins" characteristic might be passed to children. If the more toxic black widow spiders survive and reproduce better than the less 816 toxic ones, then black widow spiders, will, over time, evolve more toxic venom. The frequency of the "more-toxic" spiders in the population increases over time. If there is no advantage, the trait disappears 817 and 818 819 the population of less toxic spiders increases. 820 821 When organisms undergo selection, some characteristic may be carried along that wasn't selected. Even if some trait didn't provide an advantage it could still be carried along as long as it isn't harmful, 822 i.e., doesn't negatively influence survival and reproduction. But a situation may arise in the future when that trait can become useful. 823 824 What happens when the environment changes? 825 826 Since environments change over time and with geography, different variants are "selected" under different conditions. Characteristics that are successful in one environment may be unsuccessful in another. 827 This is well expressed by the late American paleontologist Stephen Jay Gould in Wonderful Life: "Even if fishes hone their adaptations to peaks of aquatic perfection, they will all die if the ponds dry up." 828 829 Studies show that different organisms respond differently to environmental stress. But there seems to be one creature that survives and reproduces independent of changes and stresses in the environment - the 830 cockroach. Writer Richard Schweid says in The Cockroach Papers, "If there is a God that made all life forms, a particularly rich blessing was bestowed on the roach, because it got the best design of all." 831 832 The cockroach is the oldest insect on our planet as evidenced by fossil records dating back 325 million years. It can eat almost anything, live 45 days without 833 834 13 835 836 food, and has an effective reproductive system with female sperm storing capabilities lasting a lifetime and a great defense system. The cockroach is about the same organism it was millions of years ago 837 because its characteristics were adaptive then and now. 838 839 Often a new trait or a change in an individual doesn't occur through a single step but through a gradual accumulation of small mutations being selected over a long period of time. By dating meteorites, most 840 scientists say that the earth is about 4.6 billion years old. The oldest bacteria fossils go back 3.5 billion years. Given enough variation and time, even such a complicated thing as the eye hasgradually 841 developed. Evolutionary changes can act fast. Studies of fruit flies show that differences in wing size could take place in as little time as adecade. A change in a species' territory (e.g. climatic) can also 842 bring on rapid structural changes (variation). Other studies show that a change that involves few genes could come about faster (and cause large 843 844 behavioral changes) than one that depends on small changes in many genes. 845 846 Mutation is not the only source of genetic variation. Other mechanisms (sometimes interacting) are genetic drift, gene flow, and symbiosis. Genetic drift happens when random events cause gene frequencies to 847 vary between generations (more important in small populations). Gene flow or migration is the movement of genes in a species from one population to another as the result of interbreeding. For example, there 848 is evidence of gene flow between cultivated plants and their wild relatives. Symbiosis is the cooperative interaction between different organisms that can produce genetic changes. There is also co-evolution 849 or the parallel evolution of two species. Another source of variation is gene duplication or the accidental duplication of entire genes. So natural selection is not the only mechanism that changes organisms 850 over time. But it is the only known process that seems to adapt organisms over time. 851 852 The evidence for evolution 853 854 There is fossil, anatomical and molecular evidence of evolution. The fossil record shows how morphology was modified. Similarities of organs in related organisms show common ancestry. There is also DNA 855 fossils evidence where human relative relatedness can be measured by DNA sequencing. 856 857 One example of evolution is industrial melanism. Before the Industrial Revolution in England, the color of the peppered moth was mainly light. When there was no industrial pollution, the darker moth cropped 858 up by mutation. But since the darker moths were easier to spot against the tree bark, hungry birds snapped them up. Only when the environment changed, when soot from new factories covered the tree trunks, did 859 darkness became an advantage. Selection 860 861 14 862 863 began to favor the darker moth. Darker moths were better disguised on tree trunks covered by soot. The lighter moths were eaten and the darker ones increased in numbers. Around 1950 the environment started 864 changing again. A decrease in the use of coal and better filtering equipment in the factories produced a cleaner environment and the peppered moth is in the process of returning to its lighter color. 865 866 Why aren't antibiotics as effective against dangerous bacteria as before? 867 868 Evolution is at work today. Evidence of evolution is seen in pesticide resistance among insects and the antibiotic resistance of bacteria. 869 870 There are a lot of bacteria around, and they can divide several times an hour. In any population of bacteria, there are some individuals that through mutations have developed genes causing them to escape 871 elimination. The more non resistant bacteria that are eliminated, the more opportunities for the resistant to reproduce and spread. Over time, the resistant bugs win the race, meaning the antibiotics become 872 less and less effective. Until someone develops a new type of antibiotic and then the race starts all over again. 873 874 Bacteria are immensely adaptable. Expose them to antibiotics long enough, they adapt and find a way to survive. This also means that the more we use antibiotics, the faster resistance spreads. And any method 875 we use to kill bugs will, unless it completely wipes out a species, cause a population of resistant bugs. 876 877 Just as we can't blame an animal for eating another animal to survive, we can't blame bacteria for giving us an infection. They have no intention of harming us. Bacteria do what comes natural to all of us - 878 survive and reproduce. 879 880 Are bacteria always bad far us? 881 882 No, they are important for our digestion and immune system. They are also vital for life on earth. Without them we wouldn't exist. In order to generate energy, we need oxygen. This oxygen is assumed to have 883 been generated by a group of bacteria called cyanobacteria (or blue-green algae), the light-harnessing microbes that live primarily in seawater. 884 885 The key source of energy for nearly all life is sunlight. This light energy is transformed into chemical energy in plants, algae and certain bacteria by photosynthesis. For example, plants make their food- 886 usually glucose-from carbon dioxide (through leaves) and water (mainly through roots). Sunlight provides the energy needed to run the biochemical process that yields sugar and the by-product oxygen (that 887 water molecules contain) which is released into the atmosphere. When we eat plants (or animals that eat plants), we take in their stored energy. 888 889 15 890 891 In plants, photosynthesis is handled by chloroplasts. They contain the molecule chlorophyll, allowing plants to absorb the energy from the sun. Chloroplasts may have evolved from cyanobacteria that were 892 fusioned with plants a long time ago. Fossil evidence shows that there were cyanobacteria-like microbes on earth 3.5 billion years ago. It is also believed that mitochondria (the non-bacterial cell structures 893 where oxygen is used to burn food for energy) evolved as a result from a fusion of different kind of bacterial cells. 894 895 Another activity of some cyanobacteria is nitrogen fixation. For example, in plants from which beans or peas are taken, bacteria live in the roots and chemically convert (fix) atmospheric nitrogen into 896 ammonia useful to other organ1sms. 897 898 Why isn't the world covered with dead plants and animals? 899 900 Partly because bacteria breaks down the tissue of dead plants and animals into nutrients like carbon and nitrogen that are then released back into the environment. 901 902 Go out and look at a recently dead bird. Then look at it a month later. There are only bones left. 903 904 Thus, evolution selected the behavior that made our ancestors survive and reproduce. What guidance system has evolution selected to help us make better decisions for survival and reproduction? 905 906 Guidance through values and life experiences Human beings are pulled forward toward and by nature seek pleasure, whereas they flee from and reject pain. 907 908 - Epicurus (Greek philosopher, 341-270 BC) 909 910 What drives us? 911 912 The 17th Century English philosopher John Locke said: "Good and evil, reward and punishment, are the only motives to a rational creature: these are the spur and reins whereby all mankind are set on work, and 913 guided." We are driven by our need to avoid pain (and punishment) and a desire to gain pleasure (and reward). Evolution has made any behavior that helps us survive and reproduce feel pleasurable or rewarding. 914 Behavior that is bad for us feels painful or punishing. Feelings of pain and pleasure are a useful guide to what is good or bad for us. If we eat, we feel pleasure. If we starve ourselves, we feel pain. 915 916 Harm avoidance first. Our brain is equipped to register pain more sensitively than any other emotion. We also remember negatively arousing stimuli better. 917 918 16 919 920 Neurology Professor Antonio Damasio says in Descartes' Error that "it is the pain related signal that steers us away from impending trouble." It makes evolutionary sense that we have the desire to avoid pain. 921 Psychology Professor Randolph Nesse and Biology Professor George Williams say in Why We Get Sick: "Pain is the signal that tissue is being damaged. It has to be aversive to motivate us to set aside other 922 activities to do whatever is necessary to stop the damage." 923 924 That we are sensitive to events or stimuli that have painful implications for us, explains why we have such an aversion to loss. Richard Dawkins says in The Blind Watchmaker: "However many ways there may be 925 of being alive, it is certain there are vastly more ways of being dead, or rather not alive." The fear ofloss is much greater than the desire to gain. Research shows that we feel more pain from losing than we 926 feel pleasure from gaining something of equal value and that we work harder to avoid losing than we do to win. That we pay more attention to possible losses than gains makes sense. In Steven Pinker's book, 927 How The Mind Works, social psychologist Timothy Ketelaar says, ''As things get better, increases in fitness show diminishing returns: more food is better, but only up to a point. But as things get worse, 928 decreases in fitness can take you out of the game: not enough food and you're dead." 929 930 Our aversion to pain also encourages a certain human behavior: to take the most rewarding view of events. We interpret choices and events in ways that make us feel better. We often prefer to hear supporting 931 reasons for our beliefs; think of ourselves as more talented than others, and make the best of bad situations. 932 933 How are certain connections strengthened? 934 935 If certain connections help us interact with our environment, we use them more often than connections that don't help us. Since we use them more often, they become strengthened. 936 937 Evolution has given us preferences that help us classify what is good or bad. When these values are satisfied (causing either pleasure or less pain) through the interaction with our environment, these neural 938 connections are strengthened. These values are reinforced over time because they give humans advantages for survival and reproduction in dealing with their environment. 939 940 For example, light is preferred to darkness, eating certain food is better than not eating, etc. When we drank our mother's milk, our brains told us that "eating" was pleasurable. Our chance of survival 941 increased. If we didn't eat after we were born, the feedback from our brain would be that "not eating" was painful. The chances are that we ate in the future. Since the feedback from eating 942 943 17 944 945 was pleasurable, certain neural connections were strengthened. In the future, when we were exposed to the same stimuli, this group of neurons reacted stronger. Any behavior that we find rewarding, either 946 pleasurable or less painful, are strengthened. 947 948 The connections in our brain are constantly strengthened and weakened, developing and changing. The more we are exposed to certain experiences, the more the specific connections are strengthened, and the 949 better we learn and remember those experiences. We then use these stored representations of what works when we respond to people and situations. Essentially what we do today is a function of what worked in 950 the past. We adapt to our environment by learning from the consequences of our actions. We do things that we associate with pleasure and avoid things that we associate with pain. 951 952 Does the brain work like a computer - systematically and logically? 953 954 No, it is a selection system that puts together patterns among neurons. Dr. Ralph Greenspan says: 955 956 In no sense does the brain work like a computer. Computers record, and computers have things stored in specific places that are stable. Our brains do none of that. When the great chess master Gary Kasparov 957 lost to Big Blue everybody said "Aha, this machine can think!" Big Blue was not thinking. Big Blue was simply replaying the entire history of chess. That's not the way that Gary Kasparov or any human being 958 plays chess. We do pattern recognition. Even though we are capable of logic, our brain does not operate by the principles oflogic. It operates by selection of pattern recognition. It's a dynamic network. It's 959 not an "if-then" logic machine. 960 961 A chess computer has no pattern-recognizingability. Instead, it explores all the possible moves on a given chessboard. Chess-masters look for patterns and decide what to do based on what have worked well in 962 the past. Why? Because what worked in the past is most likely to work in the future. Warren Buffett follows up with: 963 964 There was a great article in the New Yorker magazine ... when the Fischer/Spassky chess matches were going on. And it got into this speculation of whether or not humans would ever be able to take on computers 965 in chess. Here were these computers doing hundreds of thousands of calculations a second. And the article asked, "When all you're really looking 966 967 at is the results from various moves in the future, how can a human mind deal with a computer that's thinking at speeds that are so unbelievable?"... 968 969 18 970 971 Well, it turns out a mind like... that of a Fischer or a Spassky essentially was eliminating about 99.99% of the possibilities without even thinking about 'em. So it wasn't that they could outthink the 972 computer in terms of speed, but they had this ability of what you might call "grouping" or "exclusion", where essentially they just got right down to the few possibilities out of these zillions of 973 possibilities that really had any chance of success. 974 975 Now we reach a key question: What part of the value system is called "human nature?" 976 977 So far we've learned that connections between neurons determine how we think and behave. Our genes provide us with the framework for neural development and our life experiences and our environment shapes our 978 brain. 979 980 Since the brain is formed by life experiences and since an individual doesn't keep doing what doesn't work (learns through trial and error), evolution has reinforced the behavior and values that help us 981 survive and reproduce. This behavior must be the behavior that was adaptive in the environment in which humans spent most of their evolutionary history. The question then becomes: What was the operating 982 environment in which the human brain evolved? 983 984 The hunter-gatherer environment has formed our basic nature 985 986 Human evolution started about 4 to 7 million years ago and today's "modern" human brain appeared on the scene some 150,000 to 200,000 years ago. For most of that time our ancestors lived in primitive 987 hunter-gatherer societies. These societies existed until the end of the last Ice Age, around 13,000 years ago. Soon thereafter, some 10,000 years ago, agriculture was developed. 988 989 This means that humans have spent more than 99% of their evolutionary history in the hunter gatherer environment. If we compress 4 million years into 24 hours, and if the history of humans began at midnight, 990 agriculture made its appearance on the scene 23 hours and 55 minutes later. 991 992 If the conditions and challenges of the hunter gatherer environment is the 993 994 environment in which natural selection has selected the adaptive traits for survival and reproduction, we must find out what the environment looked like back then. What drove our ancestors' evolution? What 995 were the characteristics of the environment that have shaped today's brains? What were the environmental conditions in which the hunter-gatherers lived? What was the availability of resources like food and 996 mates? How was the climate and the geography? Social environment? Size of population? What enemies, predators, and dangers existed? There is no observational evidence from the hunter-gatherer environment. It 997 seems likely though, that the environment of our ancestors represented 998 999 19 1000 1001 ecological, social and human conditions that are quite different from today. People were living in small villages where everyone knew everyone else and strangers didn't show up often. There were enemies, 1002 predators and diseases. Limited resources created competition for food and mates. 1003 1004 What different roles did men and women likely play? Men were responsible for hunting, and defending the group from predators and enemies. Women gathered and prepared food near the home, and cared for the 1005 children. 1006 1007 If this were the environment, what would be appropriate behavior to increase the likelihood for survival and reproduction? What behavior has been natural during 99% of our history? 1008 1009 20 1010 1011 - THREE - 1012 1013 ADAPTIVE BEHAVIOR FOR SURVIVAL AND REPRODUCTION 1014 1015 The individual comes first 1016 1017 There's no such thing as society. There are individual men and women, and there are families. 1018 1019 - Margaret Thatcher (Former British Prime Minister) 1020 1021 Do people do what they perceive is in their best interest? 1022 1023 Yes, one basic trait that all individuals share is self-interest. We are interested in protecting our close family and ourselves. Why? 1024 1025 Since natural selection is about survival and reproduction, and individuals either survive or die and reproduce or not, it makes sense that individuals are predisposed to act in ways that enhance their own 1026 prospects for survival and reproduction. The ancestral environment consisted of limited resources, including reproductive resources, and fierce competition. Self-interest came naturally. 1027 1028 What if our ancestors were composed of altruists - individuals that helped others at their own expense? Altruistic individuals are at a disadvantage. They are always vulnerable to some mutants that take 1029 advantage of them. Altruistic behavior cannot evolve by natural selection since natural selection favors individuals that are best at promoting their own survival and reproductive success. Only behavior that 1030 is selfish or for the mutual good is in an individual's self-interest and therefore favored by natural selection. Some behavior may under certain conditions look like altruism but can often be explained by 1031 self-benefit. Social recognition, prestige, fear of social disapproval, shame, relief from distress, avoidance of guilt, a better after-life or social expectations are some reasons behind "altruistic" acts. 1032 1033 But how did our social and moral qualities develop? As Charles Darwin wrote in 1034 1035 chapter four of The Descent ofMan: "Whyshould a man feel that heought to obeyone instinctive desire rather than another? Why does he bitterly regret if he has yielded to the strong sense of self-preservation, 1036 and has not risked his life to save that of a fellow creature; or why does he regret having stolen food from severe hunger?" In chapter five of the book, Darwin wrote that there is a: "powerful stimulus to 1037 the development of the social virtues, namely, the praise and the blame of our fellow-men." 1038 1039 21 1040 1041 The love of approbation and the dread ofinfamy, as well as the bestowal of praise or blame, are primarily due... to the instinct of sympathy; and this instinct no doubt was originally acquired, like all the 1042 other social instincts, through natural selection ... We may therefore conclude that primeval man, at a very remote period, would have been influenced by the praise and blame of his fellows. It is obvious, 1043 that the members of the same tribe would approve of conduct which appeared to them to be for the general good, and would reprobate that which appeared evil. To do good unto others -to do unto others as ye 1044 would they should do unto you, - is the foundation-stone of morality. It is, therefore, hardly possible to exaggerate the importance during rude times of the love of praise and the dread of blame. A man who 1045 was not impelled by any deep, instinctive feeling, to sacrifice his life for the good of others, yet was roused to such actions by a sense of glory, would by his example excite the same wish for glory in 1046 other men, and would strengthen by exercise the noble feeling of admiration. He might thus do far more good to his tribe than by begetting offspring with a tendency to inherit his own high character. 1047 1048 A high standard of morality would also benefit a tribe. Darwin continues: 1049 1050 It must not be forgotten that although a high standard of morality gives but a slight or no advantage to each individual man and his children over the other men of the same tribe, yet that an advancement in 1051 the standard of morality and an increase in the number of well endowed men will certainly give an immense advantage to one tribe over another. 1052 1053 Often cooperation is in our best interest 1054 1055 If people aren't altruistic by nature, are they cooperative? 1056 1057 Mutual aid has tremendous survival value. But under what conditions do people cooperate? The game of the Prisoner's Dilemma may shed light on this: Suppose you and a partner commit burglary. Both of you are 1058 picked up by the police who then question you one by one. There is not enough evidence to convict you unless one of you confesses. The interrogator gives you a choice to cooperate or not. 1059 1060 ''Jfyou both deny the crime, there is still enough evidence to put you both in jail for 1 year." 1061 1062 "If you both confess, you both go to jail for 3 years. " 1063 1064 ''Jfyou confess but your partner denies, you will be free and your partner will go to jail for 10 years. " 1065 1066 ''Ifyou deny but your partner confesses, you will go to jail for 10 years. " 1067 1068 What should you do? The consequences for you depend on what your partner 1069 1070 22 1071 1072 does. From an outsider's perspective, it seems that both of you would be better off denying the crime (1 year). But from your point of view, it seems best to confess (freedom). The problem is that you don't 1073 know what your partner will do. If your partner betrays you, it is better that you also betray him and get 3 years in prison, instead of the 10 years you get if you deny, but your partner ends up confessing. 1074 If on the other hand your partner denies, it is still better that you confess because this way you will be free, instead of the 1 year you get if you deny. Since both you and your partner follow this "logic" 1075 and confess, you will both go to jail for 3 years. Doing what you believe is in your best interest leads to a worse outcome than if you cooperate and deny. But here is the dilemma. You don't know if you can 1076 trust your partner. Cooperation only works if you and your 1077 1078 partner can trust each other. 1079 1080 Tests show that if people play the game over and over, they learn that it is more profitable to cooperate. Repetition tests trust. Trust is key and fragile. It can vanish in a moment. As the 19th Century 1081 American President Abraham Lincoln wrote: "If you once forfeit the confidence of your fellow citizens, you can never regain their respect and esteem." 1082 1083 Another way to create cooperation is to let the partners communicate during the game. Talking encourages cooperation. Since people are social animals, they may change their behavior to keep others goodwill. 1084 In the end, it's a matter of trust and giving individuals an incentive to cooperate. 1085 1086 In chapter three of The Descent of Man, Charles Darwin wrote: 1087 1088 At the moment of action, man will no doubt be apt to follow the stronger impulse; and though this may occasionally prompt him to the noblest deeds, it will far more commonly lead him to gratify his own 1089 desires at the expense of other men. But after their gratification, when past and weaker impressions are contrasted with the ever-enduring social instincts, retribution will surely come. Man will then feel 1090 dissatisfied with himself, and will resolve with more or less force to act differently for the future. This is conscience; for conscience looks backwards and judges past actions, inducing that kind of 1091 dissatisfaction, which if weak we call regret, and if severe remorse. 1092 1093 But we also have to recognize that communication may be deceptive. People may bluff Also, communications are imperfect- mistakes are made or intentions are misunderstood. 1094 1095 The strategy that is effective in the long run is a modern version of"a tooth for a tooth" or TIT-FOR-TAT. It says that we should cooperate at the first meeting and then do whatever our "opponent" did the 1096 last time. When our opponent 1097 1098 23 1099 1100 cooperates, we should cooperate. When our opponent doesn't cooperate, we should retaliate. Then forgive and go back to cooperating next round. This rewards past cooperation and punishes past defection. This 1101 assumes that the game is repeated time after time. In reality we never know if we meet our opponent again in the future. As long as neither our opponent nor we knows when the game ends, it pays to be nice. Of 1102 course, the game of the Prisoner's Dilemma is only a two-player game. Reality often involves many-person interactions. 1103 1104 There is one group that scientists say we treat better than others - our close genetic relatives. This is kin selection. We act altruistic to our kin because they share our genes. Studies show that in all 1105 social species, relatives are more likely to help each other. The greater degree ofgenetic relatedness between two individuals, the more likely it is that an individual treats the other individual better. If 1106 you sacrifice something for your children, it may harm you but since your children share your genes, the overall effect is positive. Scientists say that one test of kin selection is what we would do if a 1107 relative and a good friend were both close to drowning. We can only save one of them. What if oneof them was adistant cousin that you'd seen only twice in your life and the friend was a person you spent every 1108 day with? Who would you save? 1109 1110 What other behavior was appropriate for our ancestors? 1111 1112 A tendency for fear 1113 1114 Our fears are always more numerous than our dangers. 1115 1116 - Lucius Annaeus Seneca (Roman philosopher, c.4 BC-65 AD) 1117 1118 The passengers boarded flight 651 to Chicago. Two hours after takeoff, the flight attendant heard suspicious noise ftom the lavatory. The passengers started to talk among themselves. Panic erupted. 1119 1120 We fear dramatic and threatening events. We fear the loss of our health, family, friends, security, money, social status, power, or jobs. We also fear violence, crime, punishment, rejection, failure, the 1121 unknown, the immediate, the unpredictable or the uncontrollable. Studies show that even witnessing a traumatic event can produce the same fear response as experiencing the event ourselves. 1122 1123 Fear is our most basic emotion. Fear has evolved to help us anticipate danger and avoid pain. As science writer Rush Dozier writes in Fear Itself "Fear is fundamental because life is fundamental. If we die, 1124 everything else becomes irrelevant." 1125 1126 Humans have developed a strong emotion for fear. Our ancestors environment was fraught with dangers. Fear of physical danger, social disapproval, lack of food, 1127 1128 24 1129 1130 no mate, predators, etc. Self-survival was a powerful incentive. Mistakes could be extremely costly. Assume two individuals heard a strange sound behind the bushes. One of them looked behind the bushes, was 1131 bit by a poisonous snake and died. The other one saw what happened, ran away and survived. To always assume there was a threat behind the bushes and run away could save an individual's life. The cost of being 1132 wrong and running when there was no snake was minimal. But the cost of staying around when there was a snake could be life threatening. Failure to detect threats is often more costly than false alarms. Our 1133 ancestors learned through trial and error that in the long run, pain could be avoided if they were fearful. They survived the dangers because they learned how to respond. 1134 1135 If pain and pleasure are guides to the behavior that leads to survival and 1136 1137 reproduction, fear is our biological warning signal for avoiding pain. Fear warns us of potential harm and keeps us from acting in self-destructive ways. It helps us avoid threats and makes us act to prevent 1138 further damage. Fear guides us to avoid what didn't work in the past. Fear causes worry and anxiety, a normal response to physical danger. It activates hormones like adrenaline and cortisol, which keeps us 1139 attentive to harm since we need full attention to escape from a threat. 1140 1141 The degree of fear we feel depends on our interpretation of the threat and our perception of control. The more helpless and vulnerable we feel, the stronger our emotion for fear becomes. 1142 1143 Assume that you are walking alone late at night on a deserted street in New York City. Suddenly, you hear steps behind you. What happens? Immediately you fear the worst - robbery, assault, etc. Your autonomic 1144 nervous system takes over and prepares you for fight or flight. Your response begins in your brain and activates a biochemical process. Your heart rate, breathing, blood pressure, pulse and blood sugar 1145 increase. Normal behavior when you are the victim of stress, either perceived or real. You reacted with fear on the deserted street because evolution equipped your brain to register pain more sensitively than 1146 any other emotion. You were using the "memory" of your ancestral past - your primitive fear system of fight or flight. 1147 1148 What we fear and the strength of our reaction depend on our genes, life experiences, and the specific situation. You may react instinctively at first, but if the situation is one that you've experienced 1149 before (since our brain is continuously being "rewired" with life experiences), the final reaction may be to calm down. You could turn around to find an old lady walking her dog. Or you may run away, because 1150 you avoid situations that in the past have been painful. The more we are exposed to a stimulus, even a terrifying one, the higher our 1151 1152 25 1153 1154 threshold of fear becomes. If you for example had walked the same deserted street many times before but found out each time that the noise was the old lady walking her dog, you would be less careful. Until 1155 something terrifying happened. Often our emotions provide affective information that helps us make better decisions. For example, guilt may make us regret doing wrong things, and correct them. It may also 1156 induce cooperation. Disgust seems to be a response to danger to protect us from disease or harm. Shame may help us avoid certain temptations or reduce the risk of group-conflict. People who can't experience 1157 emotional responses because of brain damage seem unable to learn from their mistakes or 1158 1159 to make choices in a coherent manner. 1160 1161 Seeking explanations 1162 1163 '1 ate a plant and now I feel sick. Therefore, I believe the plant was not good for me. " In chapter two of The Descent of Man, Charles Darwin wrote: ''As soon as the important faculties of the imagination, 1164 wonder, and curiosity, together with some power of reasoning, had become partially developed, man would naturally have craved to understand what was passing around him." 1165 1166 We don't like uncertainty or the unknown. We need to categorize, classify, organize, and structure the world. Categorizing ideas and objects helps us to recognize, differentiate and understand. It simplifies 1167 life. To understand and control our environment helps us to deal with the future. We want to know how and why things happen and what is going to happen in the future. To understand how an event happened helps 1168 us predict how it could happen again. This is why we always look for patterns and causal relationships among objects, actions, and situations. This makes it easier to identify and understand things and to 1169 make predictions based on similarities in patterns. Finding and recognizing connections between things and events in our environment helps us to learn what does and does not work. Patterns also give us 1170 comfort, making our need to find them even more important. 1171 1172 To learn what works and does not and what is good or bad for us means we have to explore. Exploring our environment successfully enables our survival and reproduction. 1173 1174 Remembering places, facts and events is important. But sometimes, the brain seems particularly attracted to new information and novel experiences. Recent studies suggest that the brain responds to novelty. 1175 The unknown is potentially rewarding, thereby motivating us to explore our environment and learn for the future. 1176 1177 We must be flexible in order to deal with constant change and unpredictability. We often explore the unknown in a random fashion. For example, many animals, 1178 1179 26 1180 1181 when foraging, start with a random search, and only change their behavior when they find a rewarding stimulus. Then they move towards it. 1182 1183 Being flexible and learning a variety of options to choose from to deal with the world is of great value. This implies that finding new ways to deal with the world is superior to overtraining old patterns. 1184 For example, studies of honeybees show that they navigate according to a map-like organization of spatial memory. When bees are over-trained to find a single nectar site, it is easy for them to find their way 1185 back to the hive from that site, but not very well from other sites. But when the same bees are trained to many nectar sites, they are much better in finding their way home to the hive from a range of 1186 different locations. Further studies suggest that we learn better when we mix new information with what we already know. 1187 1188 Making fast classifications 1189 1190 There is a story about a man who went to visit a professor at his home. Outside the house a dog was playing on the lawn. When the professor opened the door to let the man in, the dog ran into the house. Later 1191 the professor asked the man, "Do you always travel with your dog?" The man replied, "It's not my dog. I thought it was yours." 1192 1193 Our brain is wired to perceive before it thinks - to use emotions before reason. fu a consequence of our tendency for fear, fast classifications come naturally. Limited time and knowledge in a dangerous and 1194 scarce environment made hasty generalizations and stereotyping vital for survival. Waiting and weighing evidence could mean death. Don't we often draw fast conclusions, act on impulse and use our emotions to 1195 form quick impressions and judgments? 1196 1197 We are especially wary of things that move. They may imply danger. That is why we automatically assume agency - someone was responsible - when we detect motion. Better safe than sorry. 1198 1199 Males and females have different priorities 1200 1201 "What is the brain for?" asked Neuroscience Professor Michael Gazzaniga in [3mThe [0mMind's Past. "The smart-aleck answer to the question is sex. Put more completely, the brain exists to make better decisions about 1202 how to enhance reproductive success." Reproduction is the central act in the life of every living thing. Once an individual has survived past the age of reproduction, the individual is evolutionarily useless. 1203 1204 The struggle to reproduce can sometimes have peculiar effects. In nature, things are not always what they seem. 1205 1206 27 1207 1208 An ant climbs to the top ofa grass stem, falls down and tries again and again... until a sheep comes along and eats the grass (and the ant}. WHY does the ant persist in climbing the grass? How does the ant 1209 benefit? 1210 1211 There is no benefit to the ant. Its behavior was manipulated by a parasitic flatworm that needed to get into the gut of the sheep in order to reproduce. By commandeering its intermediate ant host to climb to 1212 the tips of the grass blades, the parasite increased the ant's chances of being eaten by a grazing animal. The benefit was to the reproductive success of the parasite, not the ant. Another parasite, 1213 Toxoplasma, can only reproduce within cats. It causes rats to lose their inherited fear of cats (cat scent) and thereby makes the rat more likely to end up as cat dinner. Another parasite causes fish to swim 1214 in shallow waters so birds can eat them, this parasite's final host. 1215 1216 Most animals (including humans) do something to attract the opposite sex. Since natural selection is ultimately about reproduction in a world of limited mates, some individuals were better at getting mates 1217 than others. The individuals that had an advantage in attracting prospective mates were "selected." What characteristics gave them the advantage? What anatomical features or behavioral traits attract the 1218 opposite sex or intimidate rivals? 1219 1220 Darwin realized that many anatomical and behavioral characteristics didn't have any survival value but could play an important role in attracting mates. Strength and beauty were such signals. He called this 1221 mechanism sexual selection. It has for example been shown that colors spark sexual interest among butterflies. And peahens prefer peacocks with big, colorful tails. 1222 1223 In Parental Investment and Sexual Selection, biologist Robert Trivers says that 1224 1225 the force behind sexual selection is parental investment, or "any investment by the parent in an individual offspring that increases the offspring's chance of surviving (and hence reproductive success) at the 1226 cost of the parent's ability to invest in other offspring." 1227 1228 Men need to attract women. But they also need to keep other men away from "their" woman. A woman must invest in each of her children. There is a nine month pregnancy and thereafter many years of child-caring. 1229 She invests time, energy and increases her chance of earlier death. There are limits to how many children she can produce during her lifetime. A man has less costs of reproduction. He can interact with many 1230 women and produce an enormous amount of children. He doesn't need to be around all the time. Many women can raise their children without help. 1231 1232 Since the goal of evolution is reproduction, a man should want to have sex with as many women as possible. This causes competition among men for women. 1233 1234 28 1235 1236 How does a man eliminate this competition? He can either make himself more attractive to the woman or he can eliminate or reduce the competition. 1237 1238 The reproductive success of women doesn't depend on how many men she has sex with, but on her ability to get access to resources (like food, shelter, and protection) for herself and her children. Women are 1239 therefore more discriminating than men. She won't pick the first guy around. This causes women to compete with each other for access to resources. A man that is perceived as wealthy and having status has an 1240 advantage. So mating choices (showing up as unconscious preferences) are influenced by the fact that women have more at stake than men do. 1241 1242 In 1989, Psychology Professor David Buss published a study of thousands of men and women from 37 cultures around the world showing the ranking of qualities that are most important in choosing someone to date 1243 or marry. Women placed more emphasis on a potential mate's financial prospects. Women also preferred ambitious and industrious men. Women preferred older men. Men preferred younger women. Men ranked physical 1244 attractiveness higher than women did. The study also showed that a man felt most jealous when his woman was having sex with someone else. A woman felt most jealous when her man became emotionally attached to 1245 someone else. 1246 1247 Studies show other differences between the sexes. Women are less inclined to take risks. They are more influenced by the chance of loss. They are less competitive and status-conscious. Other studies show that 1248 men and women differ in their behavioral and cognitive capabilities. Some of this reflects varying hormonal influences on brain development. Like most things, this is context dependent. 1249 1250 The Social Animal 1251 1252 We do not care about our reputation in towns where we are only passing through. But when we have to stay sorne tirne we do care. How rnuch tirne does it take?A tirne proportionate to our vain and paltry 1253 existence. 1254 1255 - Blaise Pascal (French mathematician and philosopher, 1623-1662) 1256 1257 Isn't it likely that a good reputation, status, resources and being socially accepted helped our ancestors survive, get a mate, and reproduce? 1258 1259 In a small hunter-gatherer society, what was good for the group often paid off for the individual. Cooperation was critical in an environment with limited resources, individual weaknesses and many dangers. 1260 Isolation from a group or society could mean destruction. There was safety in numbers. The group protected the individual against predators, hunted together, exchanged 1261 1262 29 1263 1264 information about where food was, cooperated to defend food from enemies, and was a key resource for mates and help with infants. Together the group stood a greater chance of survival. 1265 1266 If we help another member of the small society, he may help us when we need it. If he doesn't, we may never help him again. This behavior is called reciprocation 1267 1268 - the idea of "I scratch your back and you scratch mine." A reputation for being reliable and trustworthy is important because how we acted in the past is the only guide to how we act in the future. Ifwe fool 1269 someone, he tells his friends, destroying our future possibilities for cooperation with others. Isn't that why we trust our friends but are careful when we meet strangers whom we know nothing about? 1270 1271 We have a strong concern for fairness. We get upset when things are unfair. We sometimes even punish others at a cost to ourselves. Maybe we don't want to appear weak or easily taken advantage 0£ Since we 1272 evolved in small communities with repeated interactions, it made sense to build up a reputation for not appearing weak. We wanted to encourage people to treat us better the next time around. 1273 1274 What happens if we help someone but the next time we need help, this person conveniently disappears? What about people who don't return favors? True reciprocity only works if (1) we live in the same small 1275 society so we recognize each other, can keep track of "services" given and received, and have future opportunities to interact, and (2) the cost of the act is pretty much the same as the future favor the 1276 recipient receives. One-shot encounters encourage selfishness as told by Biology Professor Lee Alan Dugatkin: 1277 1278 At a small dinner gathering... one of the dinner guests noted that when he looked for a mechanic, he always stayed away from garages on big highways and near "strips." Such mechanics, he said, knew that they 1279 were never going to see you again and were notorious shysters. Go to a neighborhood garage, where word of mouth serves as advertising, and they know you will be a long-term customer. 1280 1281 ''Do good when others can see it. " 1282 1283 Reputation matters. Do we behave differently when we are watched or when our identities are made public? It pays to be nice when others are watching. One lab study showed that people gave much more to charity 1284 when they were "watched" by images of a robot. A real-world setting showed that people nearly trebled the amount of money they put in a psychology department coffee room box when they were watched by a pair 1285 of eyes on a poster, compared with a poster with an image of flowers. Further studies have shown that we donate more when we get public recognition for our good deeds. American 20th Century writer Henry 1286 1287 30 1288 1289 Louis Mencken said: "Conscience is the inner voice that tells us someone might be looking." 1290 1291 Traits like fear of failure, losing social status or reputation were important because they affected an individual's standing in the ancestral hunter-gatherer society. Access to food and sex depended on it. 1292 Survival and reproduction could be threatened. Social punishment was dangerous. It could lead to exile. According to Human Ecology Professor Garrett Hardin, it is the same today: 1293 1294 Fear of disapproval is the major force that keeps a society intact: fear of God, fear of the police, and fear of the judgment of neighbors. Religious authorities want the fear of God 1295 1296 to be the predominant controller. Civil authorities want fear of police and court to 1297 1298 dominate. But, says Locke [John], the opinion of one's neighbors trumps all others. 1299 1300 Providing resources is another behavior that increases chances of survival and getting a mate.The better our ability to provide, the higher our status would be in the community. 1301 1302 As we saw earlier there is competition among men for women. Women compete with each other for access to resources.Women wanted males who could take care of the children. Resources like food, lodging, and 1303 status attracted them. Striving for authority, dominance, esteem, position, and respect were advertisements for wealth. Charles Darwin said: "Man admires and often tries to exaggerate whatever characteristics 1304 nature may have given him." 1305 1306 What other evidence is there that humans are social animals? One study of a group of men whose wives suffered fatal cases of breast cancer showed that the widowers had lower immune system activity. Another 1307 study showed that men who were socially isolated were more likely to die than more socially integrated people were. It has also been shown that social rejection feels similar to physical pain. Rejection 1308 hurts! 1309 1310 Pecking order also matters. As we strive for status, hierarchies emerge. 1311 1312 Norwegian zoologist Thorleif Schjelderup-Ebbe discovered that in the world of hens there is a linear hierarchy where every hen knows its place. Science writer Robert Wright says in The Moral Animal: "Throw a 1313 bunch of hens together, and, after a time of turmoil, including much combat, things will settle down. Disputes...will now be brief and decisive, as one hen simply pecks the other, bringing quick deferral." 1314 1315 The pecking order determines who gets the first chance to eat, and which hen can peck the other hens.Each hen knows who it can dominate, and in turn, who will dominate it. 1316 1317 31 1318 1319 Status hierarchies aren't only valid for hens. Studies show that when we put a group of children together, they will shortly fall into separate grades. The ones at the top are best liked, most often imitated, 1320 and most obeyed. It is painful to lose status once it has been obtained. 1321 1322 Studies show that where we stand on the social ladder influences our health, well-being and length of life. The higher our status in the pecking order, the healthier we are likely to be. 1323 1324 We must be careful not to carry these evolutionary explanations about adaptive behavior too far. There are many causes for behavior. We can't extrapolate the conditions of the ancestral environment to explain 1325 every behavior. No one knows what the ancestral environment was like. Unlike bone and tissue, there is no fossil evidence of behavior. Neither is there any neurological or genetic evidence for or against 1326 certain behavior. And evolutionary explanations about the brain can't be experimentally tested. A trait that is found everywhere isn't necessarily genetically specified. But much of the behavior described is 1327 consistent with evidence we have from other organisms and documented human history. 1328 1329 Let's go back one million years and assume you were living in a small community with 150 people where everybody knew each other, and where the mating opportunities were limited. The environment was fraught 1330 with danger and challenges. The key was to avoid danger, get food and attract a partner. What behavior was critical to survival and reproduction? 1331 1332 Isn't it rewarding to make fast judgments?- "If noise behind the bush, then run." It is a natural tendency to act on impulse - to use emotions before reason. The behavior that was critical for survival and 1333 reproduction in our evolutionary history still applies today. Wouldn't being fearful help you survive? Social failure be costly? Maintaining status, resources and social approval help you survive and get a 1334 mate? Wouldn't you present yourself as honest, nice and trustworthy so others will cooperate with you? Wouldn't a common threat or a common goal make people cooperate? Wouldn't following social norms make 1335 sense? Wouldn't you have a strong aversion to losses and only take big risks when you were threatened? Wouldn't you be concerned with the short-term interest of yourself and loved ones? 1336 1337 Much of our psychology is the result of cultural influences 1338 1339 Human society is not only shaped by the evolution of genes, but also by cultural evolution. Practices, methods, tools, myths, ethics, and social norms that are important in the evolution of our behavior. 1340 Customs that we learn from the experience of our parents and others - either by teaching or observation. 1341 1342 32 1343 1344 Cultural evolution is faster than genetic evolution since it allows much of what we learn to be passed on and combined with what others around us have learned. Unlike biological evolution, cultural evolution 1345 is not inherited. We don't inherit our parents' habits. We learn from them. 1346 1347 In a sense, genetic and cultural evolution interact. Biology influences our culture. Take language as an example. We come equipped with an anatomy, physiology and biochemistry that give us the ability to 1348 learn a language. But we are not born with a language. The language we speak is a product of our culture. Our culture also influences our biology by creating the environment in which natural selection is 1349 tested. If a certain behavior proves to be beneficial generation over generation, that behavior is favored by natural selection. Assume individuals over time make certain social behavior choices. These 1350 choices were transmitted through learning and culture. Over time, they will be favored by natural selection 1351 1352 since they positively influence survival and reproduction. 1353 1354 Our basic nature 1355 1356 Men's natures are alike; it is their habits that carry them far apart. 1357 1358 - Confucius 1359 1360 What is our basic nature? 1361 1362 Our nature is a product of our biological and cultural history. Evolution explains how we are shaped and biologically constrained. Like our bones, kidney, eyes, and legs, our brain has been shaped by natural 1363 selection. Natural selection equipped us with traits that increase our chances for survival and reproduction. It then follows that we consciously or unconsciously behave according to what we perceive is in 1364 our own best interest. This is our biological base nature. It is strengthened or weakened depending on our life experiences. If we assume that people on average act out of self-interest we'll be less 1365 disappointed than if we assume that people on average act out of altruism. This does not mean that we can't make things better. But doing so demands that we first understand why we are the way we are. Richard 1366 Dawkins said in The Selfish Gene: "Be warned that if you wish, as I do, to build a society in which individuals cooperate generously and unselfishly towards a common good, you can expect little help from 1367 biological nature. Let us try to teach generosity and altruism, because we are born selfish." 1368 1369 Let's summarize the forces that influence and set the limits for our judgments. Genes- environmental stimuli cause response tendencies from our genes. Our genes have evolved and their functions are primarily 1370 based on what was beneficial in the hunter-gatherer environment - the environment where humans spent 1371 1372 33 1373 1374 most of their time. To survive, we must avoid all perceived threats to our survival and reproduction. Evolution has developed a value system based on pain and pleasure that help us deal with the environment. 1375 Since the ancestral environment consisted oflimited resources and danger, we developed a strong aversion for loss and a tendency for fear. We made fast evaluations and became social animals. We were 1376 predisposed to evaluate situations by being fearful. To not respond with fear could be more costly than responding with fear and being wrong. We also acted in ways where the reward was important and the cost 1377 was minimal. 1378 1379 Life experiences - upbringing, nutrition, education, social stamping, physical, 1380 1381 social and cultural settings create certain convictions, habits, values, attitudes and character traits. This in turn creates our individual beliefs and assumptions. Our judgments are influenced by our state 1382 of mind. 1383 1384 Present environment - outside factors like the environment, the context or circumstances, or the specific situation. 1385 1386 Randomness - we are prepared to be open minded to new experiences since environments vary; handling new challenges is a means of adaptation. 1387 1388 The consequences of our actions reinforce certain behavior. If the consequences were rewarding, our behavior is likely to be repeated. What we consider rewarding is individual specific. Rewards can be 1389 anything from health, money, job, reputation, family, status, or power. In all of these activities, we do what works. This is how we adapt. The environment selects our future behavior. But it's not just what 1390 happens to us that counts. It's what we think happens. 1391 1392 When we face a situation, our brains create an expectation. We can act in ways contrary to our self-interest if we don't understand the consequences. 1393 1394 Our behavior creates feedback from our environment. If we do dumb things and suffer the consequences, we may still do dumb things in the future even if it causes pain. Either because we don't understand the 1395 cause of our mistake, or the pain is less painful than other behavior. 1396 1397 Our experiences are stored in the brain and influence us in the future. New connecting patterns between neurons are created. 1398 1399 Some decisions are not in our best interest 1400 1401 There must certainly be a vast fond of stupidity in human nature, else men would not be caught as they are, a thousand times over, by the same snare, and while they yet remember their past misfortunes, go on 1402 to court and encourage the 1403 1404 causes to which they are owing, and which will again produce them. 1405 1406 - Marcus Porcius Cato (Roman statesman and writer, 234-149 BC) 1407 1408 34 1409 1410 If we often act out of self-interest, why do we make decisions that are clearly not in our best interests? 1411 1412 There is a disconnect between the ancestral world to which our brains adapted and today's world. Many of our traits are better adapted for the demands of the ancestral world such as: keeping away from 1413 predators, risking social exclusion, finding mates, getting enough food, maintaining relationships, acquiring status and a safe place to live, and bearing children. 1414 1415 Genetic and cultural evolution equipped us with behavioral tendencies (like the tendency for fear, reciprocal cooperation, fast classifications, concern for social approval, etc.) that help us interact with 1416 our environment. These tendencies are on average more helpful than not (otherwise we wouldn't be here today). Sometimes they lead us astray and cause us to make misjudgments. 1417 1418 For example, we may be biased by our automatic tendency to trust the people we like. Liking is often based on first impressions. We are superbly equipped to read other people for signs of trustworthiness. We 1419 look at their emotional state - their voice and general expression. However, it is often difficult to spot the difference between a good and bad actor. An individual may be secretive and hostile, or warm and 1420 open. What consequences would these different behaviors have on our perception of that individual? We forget to think about other factors that are important in evaluating a person or a situation. Appearances 1421 may be deceiving. The best con artists always behave as though they are not acting in their best interest. The 16th Century Italian political philosopher Niccolo Machiavelli said in The Prince: "Princes who 1422 have achieved great things have been those who have given their word lightly, who have known how to trick men with their cunning, and who, in the end, have overcome those abiding by honest principles." 1423 1424 In Part One we have learned about our nature and our limitations. With this background let us now look at how our psychological abilities affect our decision making. 1425 1426 Warren Buffett gives us some introductory remarks on why even smart people get bad results: 1427 1428 It's ego. It's greed. It's envy. It's fear. It's mindless imitation of other people. I mean, there are a variety of factors that cause that horsepower of the mind to get diminished dramatically before the 1429 output turns out. And I would say if Charlie and I have any advantage it's not because we're so smart, it is because we're rational and we very seldom let extraneous factors interfere with our thoughts. We 1430 don't let other people's opinion 1431 1432 35 1433 1434 interfere with it... we try to get fearful when others are greedy. We try to get greedy when others are fearful. We try to avoid any kind of imitation of other people's behavior. And those are the factors 1435 that cause smart people to get bad results. 1436 1437 I always look at IQ and talent as representing the horsepower of the motor, but then in terms of the output, the efficiency with which the motor works, depends on rationality. That's because a lot of people 1438 start out with 400-horsepower motors and get a hundred horsepower of output. It's way better to have a 200-horsepower motor and get it all into output. So why do smart people do things that interfere with 1439 getting the output they're entitled to? It gets into the habits, and character and temperament, and it really gets into behaving in a rational manner. Not getting in your own way. 1440 1441 In Part Two, Three, and Four we use two fictional characters named John and Mary. At 40, John is a senior executive ofTransCorp; a US company engaged in widely varied businesses. John is married to Mary, a 1442 part-time schoolteacher. 1443 1444 36 1445 1446 - PART Two - 1447 1448 [1mTHE PSYCHOLOGY OF MISJUDGMENTS [0m 1449 1450 Why oh why are human beings so hard to teach, but so easy to deceive. 1451 1452 - Dio Chrysostom 1453 1454 (Greek philosopher and orator, 2nd Century) 1455 1456 37 1457 1458 - ONE - 1459 1460 MISJUDGMENTS EXPLAINED BY PSYCHOLOGY 1461 1462 I came to the psychology of human misjudgment almost against my will; I rejected it until I realized that my attitude was costing 1463 1464 me a lot of money, and reduced my ability to help everything I loved. 1465 1466 - Charles Munger 1467 1468 Part One gave us a background of our behavior, psychology and limitations. We learned how pain and pleasure guide our behavior, how we tend to take the most rewarding view of events, how we make quick 1469 judgments, and are social animals. We also saw how we have developed a strong aversion to loss and uncertainty, and how it is natural for people to behave in ways they perceive is in their best interests. 1470 Charles Munger says, "If you want to avoid irrationality, it helps to understand the quirks in your own mental wiring and then you can take appropriate precautions." This part explores 28 reasons for 1471 misjudgments that can be explained by our psychological make-up. Many of the reasons are rooted in psychological tendencies and biases that often influence us subconsciously. The more emotional, confused, 1472 uncertain, insecure, excited, distracted, tired or 1473 1474 stressed we are, the easier we make mistakes. Geniuses aren't excluded. 1475 1476 Below is a list of 28 reasons for misjudgments and mistakes. It can be used as a checklist to explain or predict behavior or as a pilot's checklist to avoid fooling ourselves. Each item on the list will be 1477 explained in the next chapter. 1478 1479 Bias from mere association - automatically connecting a stimulus with pain or pleasure; including liking or disliking something associated with something bad or good. Includes seeing situations as identical 1480 because they seem similar. Also bias from Persian Messenger Syndrome - not wanting to be the carrier of bad news. 1481 1482 Underestimating the power of rewards and punishment - people repeat actions that result in rewards and avoid actions that they are punished for. 1483 1484 Underestimating bias from own self-interest and incentives. 1485 1486 Self-serving bias - overly positive view of our abilities and future. Includes over-optimism. 1487 1488 39 1489 1490 Self-deception and denial - distortion of reality to reduce pain or increase pleasure. Includes wishful thinking. 1491 1492 Bias from consistency tendency - being consistent with our prior commitments and ideas even when acting against our best interest or in the face of disconfirming evidence. Includes confirmation bias - looking 1493 for evidence that confirms our actions and beliefs and ignoring or distorting disconfirming evidence. 1494 1495 Bias from deprival syndrome - strongly reacting (including desiring and valuing more) when something we like and have (or almost have) is (or threatens to be) taken away or "lost." Includes desiring and 1496 valuing more what we can't have or what is (or threatens to be) less available. 1497 1498 Status quo bias and do-nothing syndrome -keeping things the way they are. Includes minimizing effort and a preference for default options. 1499 1500 Impatience -valuing the present more highly than the future. 1501 1502 Bias from envy and jealousy. 1503 1504 Distortion by contrast comparison - judging and perceiving the absolute magnitude of something not by itself but based only on its difference to something else presented closely in time or space or to some 1505 earlier adaptation level. Also underestimating the consequences over time of gradual changes. 1506 1507 Bias from anchoring - over-weighing certain initial information as a reference point for future decisions. 1508 1509 Over-influence by vivid or the most recent information. 1510 1511 Omission and abstract blindness - only seeing stimuli we encounter or that grabs our attention, and neglecting important missing information or the abstract. Includes inattentional blindness. 1512 1513 Bias from reciprocation tendency- repaying in kind what others have done for or to us like favors, concessions, information and attitudes. 1514 1515 Bias from over-influence by liking tendency - believing, trusting and agreeing with people we know and like. Includes bias from over-desire for liking and social acceptance and for avoiding social 1516 disapproval. Also bias from disliking - our tendency to avoid and disagree with people we don't like. 1517 1518 Bias from over-influence by social proof - imitating the behavior of many others or similar others. Includes crowd folly. 1519 1520 Bias from over-influence by authority - trusting and obeying a perceived authority or expert. 1521 1522 Sensemaking - Constructing explanations that fit an outcome. Includes 1523 1524 40 1525 1526 being too quick in drawing conclusions. Also thinking events that have happened were more predictable than they were. 1527 1528 Reason-respecting - complying with requests merely because we've been given a reason. Includes underestimating the power in giving people reasons. 1529 1530 Believing first and doubting later - believing what is not true, especially when distracted. 1531 1532 Memory limitations - remembering selectively and wrong. Includes influence by suggestions. 1533 1534 Do-something syndrome - acting without a sensible reason. 1535 1536 Mental confusion from say-something syndrome - feeling a need to say something when we have nothing to say. 1537 1538 Emotional arousal- making hasty judgments under the influence of intense emotions. Includes exaggerating the emotional impact of future events. 1539 1540 Mental confusion from stress. 1541 1542 Mental confusion from physical or psychological pain, the influence of chemicals or diseases. 1543 1544 Bias from over-influence by the combined effect of many psychological tendencies operating together. 1545 1546 These psychological tendencies (that also interact) have been verified by a number of experiments. Some people are more vulnerable to them than others. But we can't study them independent of an individual's 1547 values and the situation. Behavior that seems irrational may be fully rational from the individual's point of view. There is always some background within which behavior makes sense. Behavior can't be seen as 1548 rational or irrational independent of context. We are created with a series of emotions that are appropriate depending on 1549 1550 circumstances. If we change context or environment, we change behavior. 1551 1552 The next chapter describes the 28 psychological reasons why we make misjudgments and mistakes. Observe that these biases and tendencies are often not independent of one another. There is some overlap. Observe 1553 also that there are many reasons for a given behavior. Many of the real-world illustrations can be explained by more than one tendency and also by non-psychological factors. Misjudgments are often caused by 1554 many factors working together. 1555 1556 Most of the explanations are based on work done by Charles Munger, Psychology Professor Robert Cialdini, Behavioral Science and Economics Professor Richard Thaler, Psychology Professor Robyn Dawes, Psychology 1557 Professor Daniel Gilbert, and Psychology Professors Daniel Kahneman and the late Amos Tversky. 1558 1559 41 1560 1561 - Two - 1562 1563 PSYCHOLOGICAL REASONS FOR MISTAKES 1564 1565 Man is, and always was, a block-head and dullard, much readier to feel and digest than to think and consider. 1566 1567 -Thomas Carlyle (Scottish historian, 1795-1881) 1568 1569 MERE Assoc1ATION 1570 1571 Inside the jewelry boutique, surrounded by enchanting music and gorgeous women, how could John resist not buying Mary the $5,000 necklace? 1572 1573 We automatically feel pleasure or pain when we connect a stimulus - a thing, situation or individual - with an experience we've had in the past or with values or preferences we are born with. As we've 1574 learned, we move towards stimuli we associate with pleasure and away from those we associate with pain. We most easily associate to the events whose consequences we have experienced most often and the ones we 1575 easily remember. The more vivid or dramatic an event is, the easier we remember it. 1576 1577 Every time Mary served bacon for breakfast, she sung a special melody. After awhile, 1578 1579 if john heard her singing the melody, he expected bacon. 1580 1581 The Russian scientist Ivan Pavlov studied the digestive system of dogs when he observed that a stimulus unrelated to food made the dogs salivate. In one experiment he rang a bell just before giving food to 1582 the dog. He repeated this several times until the dog salivated at the sound of the bell alone. No sight or smell of food was present. The sound of the bell produced the same response as the food. The dog 1583 learned to associate the bell with food. 1584 1585 Experiments have shown that we can learn to fear a harmless stimulus if it is paired with an unpleasant one. If for example rats consistently receive mild electrical shock after hearing a tone, the rats learn 1586 to develop a fear of the tone alone. Association can influence the immune system. One experiment studied food aversion in mice. Mice got saccharin-flavored water (saccharin has incentive value due to its 1587 sweet taste) along with a nausea-producing drug. Would the mice show signs of nausea the next time they got saccharin water alone? Yes, but the mice also 1588 1589 42 1590 1591 developed infections. It was known that the drug in addition to producing nausea, weakened the immune system, but why would saccharin alone have this effect? The mere pairing of the saccharin with the drug 1592 caused the mouse immune system to learn the association. Therefore, every time the mouse encountered the saccharin, its immune system weakened making the mouse vulnerable to infections. 1593 1594 john's supplier took him to the best steakhouse in town andpicked up the check. The next time it was time to buy new supplies, john associated the supplier with pleasant feelings. People can influence us by 1595 associating a product, service, person, investment, or a situation with something we like. Many times we buy products, enter relationships, and invest our money merely because we associate them with positive 1596 things. No wonder advertisers or politicians connect what they want to sell with things we like and avoid associating themselves with negative events. Pair a sports car with something that produces a positive 1597 feeling- a beautiful and sexy model - and we automatically associate the car with pleasure. 1598 1599 john was afraid to deliver bad news to the CEO. 1600 1601 Whether we like someone is influenced by the events with which an individual is associated. Bad news isn't welcome. We tend to dislike people who tell us what we don't want to hear even when they didn't cause 1602 the bad news i.e., kill the messenger. This gives people an incentive to avoid giving bad news. To protect themselves, they tell the news in a way they believe we want to hear it. This tendency is called the 1603 Persian Messenger Syndrome and traces its origins back to ancient Greece. In Antigone, a messenger feared for his life since he knew the king would be unhappy with the news he brought. 1604 1605 Warren Buffett says on being informed of bad news: "We only give a couple of instructions to people when they go to work for us: One is to think like an owner. And the second is to tell us bad news 1606 immediately - because good news takes care of itself. We can take bad news, but we don't like it late." 1607 1608 Seeing the fish salad, john remembered the time when he'd eaten fish salad andgotten sick, and once more felt nauseous. 1609 1610 We see similar situations where they don't exist because a situation resembles an earlier experience. We therefore believe that the future mirrors the past and that history will repeat itself. 1611 1612 Keep in mind 1613 1614 Evaluate things, situations and people on their own merits. 1615 1616 43 1617 1618 Individuals are neither good nor bad merely because we associate them with something positive or negative. 1619 1620 Encourage people to tell you bad news immediately. 1621 1622 Merely because you associate some stimulus with earlier pain or pleasure doesn't mean the stimulus will cause the same pain or pleasure today. Past experiences are often context dependent. 1623 1624 Create a negative emotion if you want to end a certain behavior. If you want 1625 1626 someone to stop smoking, one way could be to show them what they stand to lose. Terrifying pictures may cause them to associate smoking with death. 1627 1628 REWARD AND PUNISHMENT 1629 1630 The iron rule of nature is: you get what you reward for. 1631 1632 Ifyou want ants to come, you put sugar on the floor. 1633 1634 Charles Munger 1635 1636 [3mjohn's actions brought him praise and money, making him continue his behavior. [0mWe do what is rewarding and avoid what we are punished for. We learn - right and wrong- from the consequences of our actions. 1637 Whatever causes us to repeat a certain behavior is reinforcing and whatever makes us stop is punishing. Behavior that is rewarding or feels pleasurable tends to be repeated. We don't continue doing what we're 1638 being punished for. Give people what they desire (or take away something undesirable) and their behavior will repeat. Give them something undesirable (or take away what they desire) and their behavior will 1639 stop. In the beginning, rewarding (or punishing) people is most effective when it is administered without delay and each time the behavior is repeated. 1640 1641 Once a behavior becomes learned, variable rewards strengthen the behavior. Behavior that is rewarded on an unpredictable basis has the highest rate of response and is the most difficult to extinguish. This 1642 is, for example, how gamblers are rewarded. When they don't know when the reward will arrive, they try again and again. Furthermore, the greater the reward, the more resistant the behavior is to extinction. 1643 1644 We base what is rewarding or punishing on our associations to past experiences and their consequences or with values or preferences we are born with. 1645 1646 An action that is reinforced becomes stronger over time. This is how habits, superstitions and addictions are created. Both are hard to change. As the great 18th Century English writer Samuel Johnson said: 1647 "The chains of habit are too weak to be felt until they are too strong to be broken." 1648 1649 What does all this mean? It means that people do what works. Like bees to 1650 1651 44 1652 1653 honey, they go where there is a reward. This also implies that if we reward what we don't want, we get it. As Garrett Hardin says in The Ostrich Factor: "If the laws of society reward for bank robbing, 1654 society will get more bank robbing. If our methods of winnowing candidates for high positions favor stupidity, we will get stupid politicians." 1655 1656 Studies in Sweden show that changes in the sickness insurance system affect sick leave behavior. Reforms implying more generous compensation for sick leave tenq to be associated with permanent increases in 1657 total sick leave per person employed. Other studies from the U.S. regarding health services have shown that in cases where someone else picks up the costs, patients tend to over-consume the health services. 1658 1659 Why do people abuse the health care and welfare system? Isn't it natural that people use the system if they don't have to pay anything? And if people don't have to pay for a benefit, they often overuse it. 1660 The more people that benefit from misusing the system, the less likely it is that anyone will draw attention to what really happens. Individually they get a large benefit and it's a small loss for society. 1661 Until everyone starts thinking the same. The ancient Greek philosopher Aristotle said: "That which is common to the greatest number gets the least amount of care. Men pay most attention to what is their own; 1662 they care less for what is common." 1663 1664 Why do people steal? 1665 1666 Studies show that 23% of people say they would steal if they couldn't get caught. It is estimated that U.S. businesses lose $400 billion a year from fraud and about a third of that is from employees stealing 1667 from their employer. Why? Opportunity and reward. In Charles Munger's words: ''The worst abuses come where people have the greatest temptations." If we make it easy for people to steal, they steal (and bad 1668 behavior will spread). 1669 1670 Charles Munger tells us how a bad policy can become the norm: 1671 1672 In the New York Police Department, they have a simple system. Your pension is based on your pay in your final year. So when anyone reaches the final year, everybody cooperates to give him about 1,000 hours of 1673 overtime. And he retires - in some cases after a mere 20 years of service - with this large income. Well, of course his fellow employees help him cheat the system. In substance, that's what's happened. But 1674 the one thing I guarantee you is that nobody has the least sense of [3mshame. [0mThey soon get the feeling they're [3mentitled [0mto do it. Everybody did it before, everybody's doing it now - so they just keep doing it. 1675 1676 45 1677 1678 Why does a tennis player always wear his lucky shirt in the finals? 1679 1680 In one experiment, American psychologist B.F. Skinner fed pigeons small quantities of food at regular intervals. After some time the pigeons began to behave superstitiously. If a pigeon was bobbing its head 1681 when food appeared, it got the idea that bobbing its head must have made the food appear. The pigeons continued with the behavior that worked - every time they performed the behavior, food appeared. But food 1682 appeared independent of what the pigeons did. Skinner wrote in "Superstition" in the pigeon: "There are many analogies in human behavior... A few accidental connections between a ritual and favorable 1683 consequences suffice to set up and maintain the behavior in spite of many nonreinforced instances." 1684 1685 Are the right incentives important? 1686 1687 Incentives act as reinforcers. Charles Munger tells a story about the importance of getting the incentives right: 1688 1689 From all business, my favorite case on incentives is Federal Express. The heart and soul of their system -which creates the integrity of the product- is having all their airplanes come to one place in the 1690 middle of the night and shift all the packages from plane to plane. If there are delays, the whole operation can't deliver a product full of integrity to Federal Express customers. And it was always screwed 1691 up. They could never get it done on time. 1692 1693 They tried everything- moral suasion, threats, you name it. And nothing worked. Finally, somebody got the idea to pay all these people not so much an [3mhour, [0mbut so much a [3mshift [0mand when it's all done, they can 1694 all go home. Well, their problems cleared up overnight. 1695 1696 john invested in a biotech start-up that went sour and he lost money. 1697 1698 After a success, we become overly optimistic risk-takers. After a failure, we become overly pessimistic and risk-averse - even in cases where success or failure was merely a result of chance. Good 1699 consequences don't necessarily mean we made a good decision, and bad consequences don't necessarily mean we made a bad decision. 1700 1701 The next time someone presents John an investment opportunity in a biotech start-up the chances are he will decline. He associates the new proposal to his earlier experience. And since people tend to believe 1702 that the future mirrors the past, he declines. But what happens if John's first investment made him a lot of money? Wouldn't John associate the new proposal to his old pleasurable experience? Isn't he 1703 therefore more likely to invest? This automatic association to what worked in the past causes people to under-react to new conditions and circumstances. 1704 1705 46 1706 1707 Mark Twain understood the dangers of blindly trusting past experience for dealing with the future. "We should be careful to get out of an experience only the wisdom in it, and stop there, lest we be like the 1708 cat that sits down on a hot stove-lid. She will not sit down on a hot stove-lid again - but also she will never sit down on a cold one anymore." 1709 1710 Does it matter in which size or order rewards or punishments arrive? 1711 1712 Mary never wraps the kids Christmas presents in one box. 1713 1714 Since our experiences seem longer when broken into segments, we like to have pleasurable experiences broken into segments but painful ones combined. That is why Mary puts presents in many boxes. Frequent 1715 rewards feel better. For example, it feels better to gain $50 twice than $100 once since every gain is rewarding. It feels better to lose $100 once than $50 twice since every loss is painful. 1716 1717 We prefer a sequence of experiences that improve over time. Losing $100 first and then gaining $50 seems more rewarding than gaining $50 and then losing 1718 1719 $100. We want to get rid of the bad experiences first. Immediate losses are preferred over delayed ones. Just as we don't like bad experiences, we also don't like waiting for them. We like to get over them 1720 fast. 1721 1722 Mere association and reinforcement are both examples of conditioned reflexes. Charles Munger gives an example how these forces can be used as he describes the invention of non-alcoholic drinks: 1723 1724 The food value and so forth of the beverage is the reinforcer. And the trade dress, trade name and look of the beverage is the stimulant... 1725 1726 Then, you go on to the second kind of conditioned reflex- and that's straight Pavlov... Well, how do you get Pavlovian mere-association effects? Obviously, you associate this beverage and its trademarks with 1727 every good thing that people like generally: exalting events, sex objects, happy times - you name it. 1728 1729 How can we lose a conditioned reflex that's working for us? Charles Munger continues: 1730 1731 Well, the customer tries something else and discovers that it's a big reinforcer. So he shifts brands. We know, in matrimony, that if you're always available, the spouse is less likely to shift brands. And 1732 people don't tend to organize marriage to include permanent long separations. Similarly, if you're selling a product and it's always available, people are less likely to shift to some other product and get 1733 reinforced by it. 1734 1735 47 1736 1737 Keep in mind 1738 1739 American statesman, scientist and philosopher Benjamin Franklin tells us that: ''A spoonful of honey will catch more flies than a gallon of vinegar." Praise is more effective in changing behavior than 1740 punishment. It is better to encourage what is right than to criticize what is wrong. 1741 1742 Set examples. Michel de Montaigne said: "It is a custom of our justice to punish some as a warning to others. For to punish them for having done wrong would, as Plato says, be stupid: what is done cannot be 1743 undone. The intention is to stop them from repeating the same mistake or to make others avoid their error. We do not improve the man we hang: we improve others by him." 1744 1745 Don't over-learn from your own or others bad or good experience. The same action under other conditions may cause different consequences. 1746 1747 Separate between skill and chance. Charles Munger says, "As you occupy some high-profit niche in a competitive order, you must know how much of your present prosperity is caused by talents and momentum 1748 assuring success in new activities, and how much merely reflects the good fortune of being in your present niche." 1749 1750 American novelist Upton Sinclair said: "It is difficult to get a man to understand something when his salary depends upon him not understanding it." Since people do what works, be sure to make the incentives 1751 right. Tie incentives to performance and to the factors that determine the result you want to achieve. Make people share both the upside and downside. And make them understand the link between their 1752 performance, their reward and what you finally want to accomplish. For example, tie a manager's compensation to gain in business value (of the unit under his control) minus a cost factor for capital that is 1753 used to produce this value. The auto insurer GEICO's plan exemplifies Berkshire Hathaways's incentive compensation principles. Warren Buffett says: 1754 1755 Goals should be (1) tailored to the economics of the specific operating business; (2) simple in character so that the degree to which they are being realized can be easily measured; and 1756 1757 (3) directly related to the daily activities of plan participants. As a corollary, we shun "lottery ticket" arrangements, such as options on Berkshire shares, whose ultimate value 1758 1759 which could range from zero to huge - is totally out of the control of the person whose behavior we would like to affect. In our view, a system that produces quixotic payoffs will not only be wasteful for 1760 owners but may actually discourage the focused behavior we value m managers. 1761 1762 48 1763 1764 Reward individual performance and not effort or length in organization and reward people after and not before their performance. 1765 1766 Don't let money be the only motivation. If we reward people for doing what they 1767 1768 like to do anyway, we sometimes turn what they enjoy doing into work. The reward changes their perception. Instead of doing something because they enjoy doing it, they now do it because they are being paid. 1769 The key is what a reward implies. A reward for our achievements makes us feel that we are good at something thereby increasing our motivation. But a reward that feels controlling and makes us feel that we are 1770 only doing it because we're paid to do it, decreases the appeal. Blaise Pascal said: "We are generally the better persuaded by the reasons we discover ourselves than by those given to us by others." 1771 1772 Install systems and rules that encourage the behavior you want. Never let it pay someone to behave in a way you don't want. Have systems that make it hard for people to get away with undesirable behavior. 1773 Make undesirable behavior costly. The painful consequences of undesirable behavior must outweigh its pleasurable consequences. For example, the consequences of spending time in jail ought to be more painful 1774 than the pleasure of getting away with burglary. 1775 1776 Systems can be hard to change as Warren Buffett observes, "It's very hard to change a system when the guy whose hand is on the switch benefits enormously and, perhaps, disproportionately from that system." 1777 1778 Decision-makers should be held accountable for the consequences of their actions. In The Case for Modern Man, American philosopher Charles Frankel defines responsibility: ''A decision is responsible when the 1779 man or group that makes it has to answer for it to those who are directly or indirectly affected by it." Charles Munger adds, ''An example of a really responsible system is the system the Romans used when 1780 they built an arch. The guy who created the arch stood under it as the scaffolding was removed. It's like packing your own parachute." 1781 1782 SELF-INTEREST AND INCENTIVES 1783 1784 "Damn it all, we want to get at the truth" [said Lord Peter Wimsey}"Do you" said Sir Impey dryly. "I don't. I don't care two pence about the truth. I want a case." 1785 1786 Dorothy Sayers (British writer, 1893-1957) 1787 1788 The organizers of a tennis tournament needed money. They approached the CEO of TransCorp and asked him to sponsor the tournament. 1789 1790 49 1791 1792 "How much?" asked the CEO. "One million,"said the organizer. 1793 1794 "That is too much money," said the CEO. 1795 1796 ''Not if you consider the fact that you personally can p/,ay one match, sit at the honorary stand next to a member of the presidential family and be the one that hands over the prize,"said the organizer. 1797 1798 "Where do I sign?" said the CEO. 1799 1800 People do what they perceive is in their best interest and are biased by incentives. For example, when the first Dead Sea scrolls were discovered and the archeologists wanted more fragments of the scrolls to 1801 be found, they offered a reward per fragment. The result: the fragments were split into smaller pieces before they were turned in. 1802 1803 The comedian Groucho Marx once interviewed a U.S. Senator about a miracle cure-all vitamin and mineral tonic that the Senator had invented. When Groucho asked him what it was good for, the Senator answered: 1804 "It was good for five and a half million for me last year." 1805 1806 Incentives for the decision-maker determine behavior. This means that we have to recognize self-interested behavior in others. 1807 1808 Are advisors always to be trusted? 1809 1810 There is an old saying: "Never ask the village barber if you need a haircut." We are biased by our incentives as are others including lawyers, accountants, doctors, consultants, salesmen, organizations, the 1811 media, etc. What is good for them may not be good for us. Advisors are paid salesmen and may trick us into buying what we don't need. 1812 1813 For an attorney, litigation is often more lucrative than settlement. Lawyer William F. Coyne, Jr. says in The Case for Settlement Counsel there are "significant incentives for lawyers not to embrace early 1814 settlement ... These incentives include the need to market services, the desire not to appear weak, the obligation to represent a client zealously, the thirst for justice, but perhaps not least, the desire to 1815 maximize income." 1816 1817 Warren Buffett tells us that one of Berkshire's compensation arrangements was worked out: "without the "help" of lawyers or compensation consultants. This arrangement embodies a few very simple ideas - not 1818 the kind of terms favored by consultants who cannot easily send a large bill unless they have established that you have a large problem (and one, of course, that requires an annual review)." 1819 1820 Charles Munger tells us about the common tendency of salesmen: 1821 1822 50 1823 1824 All commissioned salesmen have a tendency to serve the transaction instead of the truth. 1825 1826 ...I put consultants in the same category, sometimes even lawyers - sometimes especially lawyers. 1827 1828 Many years ago, a Pasadena friend of mine made fishing tackle. I looked at this fishing tackle - it was green and purple and blue - I don't think I'd ever seen anything like them. I asked him "God! Do fish 1829 bite these lures?" He said to me, "Charlie, I don't sell to fish." 1830 1831 Let's look at the brokerage and investment banking business. Brokers have a strong incentive to get us to trade. They advise us what to buy and sell. Volume creates commissions. Investment bankers encourage 1832 overpriced acquisitions to generate fees. Investment bankers have every incentive to get initial public offerings (IPO) deals done, regardless of the company's quality. Their compensation is tied to the 1833 revenues the deal brings in. Analysts are rewarded for helping sell the IPO. Brokers want to move the stock. What did Groucho Marx say? "I made a killing on Wall Street a few years ago.. .I shot my broker." 1834 1835 Similarly, in the medical field, some psychologists ensure themselves successive 1836 1837 paydays by telling their patients that another visit is required. And they don't talk about the limits of their knowledge. Their careers are at stake. As American actor Walther Matthau said, "My doctor gave 1838 me six months to live. When I told him I couldn't pay the bill, he gave me six more months." 1839 1840 Why do bankers approve risky loans? 1841 1842 People who are rewarded for doing stupid things continue to do them. From their frame of reference, they acted logically based on how they were rewarded. The incentive system paid them to do the wrong thing. 1843 So if market share rather than profits pay a banker, he will write as many loans as possible. He is being rewarded every year while the net consequences of the bad loans won't be realized for a long time. 1844 1845 Charles Munger gives an example of how Lloyd's Insurance rewarded their people: 1846 1847 They were paid a percentage of the gross volume that went through. And paying everybody a percentage of the gross, when what you're really interested in is the net, is a system - given the natural bias of 1848 human beings toward doing what's in their own interest even though it has terrible consequences for other people - that really did Lloyd's in. 1849 1850 Be carefal what you pay for, you may get it. 1851 1852 The city of New Orleans introduced a program under which districts that 1853 1854 51 1855 1856 showed improvement in cnme statistics received awards that could lead to bonuses and promotions, while districts that didn't faced cutbacks and firings. What happened? In one police district, nearly half of 1857 all serious crimes were reclassified as minor offences and never fully investigated. 1858 1859 Studies show that teachers help students cheat on standardized tests when their jobs or pay increases depend on the outcome of the tests. 1860 1861 john knew that if he didn't show good figures, his project wouldn't be fonded so he cooked the books. 1862 1863 Why do people give a biased picture of reality? Why do they make figures look better than they are or fake data to support something? Behavior that is not acceptable but results from the tendency of people 1864 doing what they perceive is in their best interest. 1865 1866 There may be powerful economic and prestige-related incentives to underestimate costs and overestimate benefits when people try to sell projects. For example, studies based on data from several hundred large 1867 transportation infrastructure projects in twenty nations and five continents found evidence that in a number of cases, project promoters and forecasters of billion-dollar projects intentionally misrepresented 1868 the costs, benefits and risks of projects in order to get them approved. 1869 1870 Charles Munger says that projections should be handled with care: 1871 1872 Mark Twain used to say, "A mine is a hole in the ground with a liar on the top." And a projection prepared by anybody who stands to earn a commission or an executive trying to justify a particular course of 1873 action will frequently be a lie - although it's not a deliberate lie in most cases. The man has come to believe it himself. And that's the worst kind. Projections should be handled with great care - 1874 particularly when they're being provided by someone who has an interest in misleading you." 1875 1876 Warren Buffett adds: 1877 1878 I have no use whatsoever for projections or forecasts. They create an illusion of apparent precision. The more meticulous they are, the more concerned you should be. We never look at projections, but we care 1879 very much about, and look very deeply at, track records. If a company has a lousy track record, but a very bright future, we will miss the opportuniry... I do not understand why any buyer of a business looks 1880 at a bunch of projections put together by a seller or his agent. You can almost say that it's naive to think that those 1881 1882 projections have any utiliry whatsoever. We're just not interested. 1883 1884 52 1885 1886 If we don't have some idea ourselves of what the future is, to sit there and listen to some other guy who's trying to sell us the business or get a commission on it tell us what the future's going to be - 1887 like I say, it's very naive. 1888 1889 Buffett also gives us a test: 1890 1891 When they make these offerings, investment bankers display their humorous side: They dispense income and balance sheet projections extending five or more years into the future for companies they barely had 1892 heard of a few months earlier. If you are shown such schedules, I suggest that you join in the fun: Ask the investment banker for the one-year budgets that his own firm prepared as the last few years began 1893 and then compare these with what actually happened. 1894 1895 The consultant to TransCorp was hired and paid by the company to advise the CEO on how he should be paid. "If I tell the CEO what he wants to hear, he will pay me well, rehire me and recommend me to other 1896 CEOs. And if I make it sound complicated it will be easier to send a larger bill " 1897 1898 How do we act as an employee? If our boss wants a particular answer, do we give it? To quote the German proverb: "Whose bread I eat, his song I sing." Warren Buffett says: 1899 1900 I would say that the typical corporate organization is structured so that the CEOs opinions, biases and previous beliefs are reinforced in every possible way. Staffs won't give you any contrary 1901 recommendations - they'll just come back with whatever the CEO wants. And the Board of Directors won't act as a check, so the CEO pretty much gets what he wants. 1902 1903 "I don't like to be embarrassed and have my name and reputation threatened with disgrace," said the CEO ofTransCorp. 1904 1905 How can we change people? Benjamin Franklin said: "Would you persuade, speak of interest not of reason." Since the risk of losing is more motivating than the chance of gaining, we stand a better chance 1906 changing people if we appeal to their fear oflosing something they value - job, reputation, status, money, control, etc. 1907 1908 It is often better to avoid situations where we need to change people. Changing people is hard as Warren Buffett says, "I'd say that the history that Charlie and I have had of persuading decent, intelligent 1909 people who we thought were doing unintelligent things to change their course of action has been poor.. . When 1910 1911 53 1912 1913 people want to do something, they want to do something." 1914 1915 Changing people affects their motivation, feelings of responsibility, and tendency to reciprocate. It is better when people act out of their own free will. Warren Buffett illustrates: 1916 1917 We want the manager of each subsidiary to run their business in the way they think is best for their operation we'll never tell a subsidiary manager which vendor to patronize or 1918 1919 anything of that sort. Once we start making those decisions for our managers, [3mwe [0mbecome responsible for the operation and they're no longer responsible for the operation. And they're responsible for their 1920 operations. That means that they get to make the call, that it's up to them to do what's best for their subsidiary and that it's up to any other company that wants to do business with their operation to prove 1921 to them why it's best That's the 1922 1923 Berkshire approach. I think, on balance, our managers like it that way - because they're 1924 1925 not going to get second-guessed and nobody will go over their heads. 1926 1927 Keep in mind 1928 1929 Don't automatically trust people who have something at stake from your decision. Ask: What are the interests? Who benefits? 1930 1931 Understand people's motivations. Money, status, love of work, reputation, position, power, envy? What are they rewarded or punished for? Are they benefiting or losing from the present system? 1932 1933 People's interests are not only financial. They could also be social or moral. For example, public embarrassment, social exclusion, conscience, shame or guilt may cause people to stop some undesirable 1934 behavior. For example, by requiring restaurants to post hygiene quality scores in their front windows, the Los Angeles county health department caused a dramatic improvement in restaurant hygiene and a 1935 reduction in food-related illnesses. 1936 1937 The ancient Greek philosopher Plato said: "Do not train boys to learning by force and harshness, but lead them by what amuses them, so that they may better discover the bent of their minds." Pressuring people 1938 or giving them orders often doesn't work. It is better to convince people by asking questions that illuminate consequences. This causes them to think for themselves and makes it more likely that they discover 1939 what's in their best interest. 1940 1941 SELF-SERVING TENDENCIES AND OPTIMISM 1942 1943 Man suffers much because he seeks too much, is foolishly ambitious and grotesquely overestimates his capacities 1944 1945 Isaiah Berlin (Russian-British philosopher, 1909-1997) 1946 1947 54 1948 1949 "Things that happen to others don't happen to me. " 1950 1951 We see ourselves as unique and special and we have optimistic views of ourselves and our family. We overestimate the degree of control we have over events and underestimate chance. 1952 1953 The 18th Century English poet Edward Young said: "All men think all men are mortal but themselves." Most of us believe we are better performers, more honest and intelligent, have a better future, have a 1954 happier marriage, are less vulnerable than the average person, etc. But we can't all be better than average. 1955 1956 We tend to overestimate our ability to predict the future. People tend to put a higher probability on desired events than on undesired events. For example, we are over-optimistic about the outcome of planned 1957 actions. Optimism is good but when it comes to important decisions, realism is better. 1958 1959 After making a huge mistake, john said· "I was arrogant. My past success caused me to believe I could do anything. " 1960 1961 Marcus Porcius Cato said: "Men's spirits are lifted when the times are prosperous, rich and happy, so that their pride and arrogance grow." We tend to over-estimate our abilities and future prospects when we 1962 are knowledgeable on a subject, feel in control, or after we've been successful. As financial writer Roger Lowenstein writes in When Genius Failed· The Rise and Fall of Long-Term Capital Management: "There is 1963 nothing like success to blind one of the possibility of failure." 1964 1965 What tends to inflate the price that CEO's pay for acquisitions? Studies found evidence of infection through three sources of hubris: 1) overconfidence after recent success, 2) a sense of self-importance; the 1966 belief that a high salary compared to other senior ranking executives imply skill, and 3) the CEO's belief in their own press coverage. The media tend to glorify the CEO and over-attribute business success to 1967 the role of the CEO rather than to other factors and people. This makes CEO's more likely to become both more overconfident about their abilities and more committed to the actions that made them media 1968 celebrities. 1969 1970 '1t worked because we made the right decisions. " '1t didn't work because of a bad business climate. " 1971 1972 Experiments show that when we are successful (independent ifby chance or not), we credit our own character or ability. Warren Buffett says: 1973 1974 Any investor can chalk up large returns when stocks soar, as they did in 1997. In a bull market, one must avoid the error of the preening duck that quacks boastfully after a 1975 1976 55 1977 1978 torrential rainstorm, thinking that its paddling skills have caused it to rise in the world. A right-thinking duck would instead compare its position after the downpour to that of the other ducks on the pond. 1979 1980 When we fail, we blame external circumstances or bad luck. When others are successful, we tend to credit their success to luck and blame their failures on foolishness. When our investments turn into losers, 1981 we had bad luck. When they turn into winners, we are geniuses. This way we draw the wrong conclusions and don't learn from our mistakes. We also underestimate luck and randomness in outcomes. 1982 1983 When using advisers and if something turns out well, we take the credit, assigning the outcome to our skill. But if something turns out bad, we blame the advisor. 1984 1985 Charles Munger tells us about the toast we seldom hear: 1986 1987 ... Arco was celebrating their huge triumph of making a lot of money out of the North Slope oilfields in Alaska. And the house counsel there was an Irishman who was very outspoken and had a fair amount of 1988 charm. And he was highly regarded. So he could get by with talking frankly. And the whole group was toasting one another: "Aren't we great people for having done this great thing?" and this Irish house 1989 counsel raised his glass and said "Well, I'd like to toast the man who really caused our triumph." He said, "Here's to King Faisal ... Every calculation we made was off by 200%. All the costs were way higher, 1990 and the difficulties way greater than we ever conceived. All the predictions we made were totally asinine and wouldn't have worked with the oil prices we projected. But along came King Faisal and the oil 1991 cartel and raised the price of oil so high that they made us all look good. Let's honor the proper man here tonight. " 1992 1993 This is the kind of toast you will seldom hear in corporate life - because for most people, a toast like that will get you fired. And a guy who's bringing reality into a pleasant party, and making people face 1994 their own limitations and errors, will have poor prospects. 1995 1996 Bill is a surgeon who always uses surgery to handle health problems even if they could be cured by a less invasive procedure. 1997 1998 As the old saying goes: "If the only tool you have is a hammer, you approach every problem as ifit were a nail." The more we know or think we know about a subject, the less willing we are to use other ideas. 1999 Instead, we tend to solve a problem in a way that agrees with our area of expertise. And the more useful a given idea is 2000 2001 -whether or not it's appropriate to the problem at hand- the more overconfident we are about its usefulness. In Bill's case, there may also be financial incentives to recommend a medical procedure. 2002 2003 56 2004 2005 Experts love to extrapolate their ideas from one field to all other fields. They define problems in ways that fit their tools rather than ways that agree with the underlying problem. Give someone a tool and 2006 they'll want to use it, and even overuse it, whether it's warranted or not. 2007 2008 Why is man-with-a-hammer syndrome always present? Charles Munger answers: "Well if you stop to think about it, it's incentive-caused bias. His professional reputation is all tied up with what he knows. He 2009 likes himself and he likes his own ideas, and he's expressed them to other people - consistency and commitment tendency [see 6. Consistency]. 2010 2011 '1 hired heras my assistant since she was good-looking, articulate and hada university degree. She gave a great first impression. " 2012 2013 How good are we at judging personalities? Sherlock Holmes says in Arthur Conan Doyle's The Sign of Four that: "It is of the first importance not to allow your judgment to be biased by personal qualities. I 2014 assure you that the most winning woman I ever knew was hanged for poisoning three little children for their insurance-money, and the most repellent man of my acquaintance is a philanthropist who has spent 2015 nearly a quarter of a million upon the London poor." 2016 2017 We immediately classify people which brings to mind a host of associations. We often allow one trait to color all other characteristics and therefore judge people as better or worse than they really are. 2018 Preconceived ideas about certain people, races, religions, or occupations cause us to automatically assume that an individual from a particular group has special characteristics. 2019 2020 Physics Professor Roger Newton observes in The Truth of Science: "Scientists are human... they sometimes succumb to weaknesses such as jealousy, vanity, and, on very rare instances, even dishonesty." 2021 Gian-Carlo Rota says in Indiscrete Thoughts: "A good mathematician is not necessarily a nice guy." 2022 2023 "When I interview someone I have already formed an impression from reading the job applications. Then I just try to find confirming evidence at the interviews. " Interviews are often of limited use to predict 2024 a potential employee's future behavior. As Psychology Professor Robyn Dawes notes in Rational Choice in an Uncertain World· "What can an interviewer learn in a half-hour to an hour that is not present in the 2025 applicant's record?" 2026 2027 An articulate person may be more persuasive than a reserved person, but the latter may know what he is talking about. 2028 2029 Why do some people seem to have an intuition for evaluating people? Maybe 2030 2031 57 2032 2033 their life experiences gives them the ability (by asking questions and observing behavior) to look for clues to an individual's character. 2034 2035 Warren Buffett says on how to identify people that may cause problem: ''I'm not saying that you can take 100 people and take a look at 'em and analyze their personalities or anything of the sort. But I think 2036 when you see the extreme cases 2037 2038 - the ones that are going to cause you nothing but trouble and the ones that are going to bring you nothing but joy - well, I think you can identify those pretty well." Charles Munger adds, ''Actually, I 2039 think it's pretty simple: There's integrity, intelligence, experience, and dedication. That's what human enterprises need to run well." 2040 2041 Keep in mind 2042 2043 German missionary Dr. Albert Schweitzer said: "An optimist is a person who sees a green light everywhere, while the pessimist sees only the red stoplight. The truly wise person is colorblind." 2044 2045 Overconfidence can cause unreal expectations and make us more vulnerable to disappointment. 2046 2047 Recognize your limits. How well do you know what you don't know? Don't let your ego determine what you should do. Charles Munger says, "It is remarkable how much long-term advantage people like us have gotten 2048 by trying to be consistently not stupid, instead of trying to be very intelligent. There must be some wisdom in the folk saying: 'It's the strong swimmers who drown."' 2049 2050 Warren Buffett says: "We won't do anything that we don't think we understand ourselves." 2051 2052 Focus on what can go wrong and the consequences. Build in some margin of safety in decisions. Know how you will handle things if they go wrong. Surprises occur in many unlikely ways. Ask: How can I be wrong? 2053 Who can tell me ifl'm wrong? 2054 2055 By developing only a handful of strengths, we have an impoverished toolbox 2056 2057 only hammers. We need a full toolkit. Since problems don't follow territorial boundaries, we must compensate for the bias of one idea by using important ideas from other disciplines. 2058 2059 Consider people's actual accomplishments and past behavior over a long period of time rather than first impressions. Since people leave track records in life, an individual's paper record is often predictive 2060 of future performance and behavior. 2061 2062 When comparing records or performances, remember that successes draw far more attention than failures. 2063 2064 58 2065 2066 SELF-DECEPTION AND DENIAL 2067 2068 Nothing is easier than self-deceit. For what 2069 2070 each man wishes, that he also believes to be true. 2071 2072 Demosthenes (Greek statesman, 384-322 BC) 2073 2074 john couldn't admit to others that he'd made a bad deal. "I was almost right! I lost money, but others lost more. It wasn't my fault. It was outof my control! You win some, you lose some. " 2075 2076 We deny and distort reality to feel more comfortable, especially when reality threatens our self-interest. To quote the Austrian psychologist Sigmund Freud: "Illusions commend themselves to us because they 2077 save us pain and allow us to enjoy pleasure instead." We view things the way we want to see them. We hear what we want to hear and deny what is inconsistent with our deeply held beliefs. We deny unpleasant 2078 news and prefer comfort to truth. We choose the right people to ask. We make sense of bad events by telling ourselves comforting stories that give them meaning. 2079 2080 '1 hope the project succeeds in time and on budget. " 2081 2082 In relating the events of the 5th Century B.C. war between the main adversaries Athens and Sparta, the Greek historian Thucydides wrote: "... their judgment was based more upon blind wishing than upon any 2083 sound prediction; for it is a habit of mankind to entrust to careless hope what they long for, and to use sovereign reason to thrust aside what they do not desire." Wishful thinking is rooted in denial, 2084 offering us a more pleasant reality. In business, this is one reason for project delays and cost overruns. 2085 2086 We believe something is true because it sounds believable or we want to believe it, especially with issues of love, health, religion, and death. This is one reason why people follow gurus. They encourage 2087 followers to trust their hearts and forget their heads. Philosopher and mathematician Bertrand Russell said in Skeptical Essays: "What is wanted is not the will to believe, bur the will to find out, which is 2088 the exact opposite." 2089 2090 Keep in mind 2091 2092 In his famous 1974 commencement address at Caltech, American physicist Richard Feynman warned against self-deception: "The first principle is that you must not fool yourself- and you are the easiest person to 2093 fool." 2094 2095 Austrian philosopher Ludwig Wittgenstein said in Culture and Value: 2096 2097 "Nothing is so difficult as not deceiving oneself." We have to see the world as 2098 2099 59 2100 2101 it is. Not for what it was or for what we want it to be. Refusing to look at unpleasant facts doesn't make them disappear. Bad news that is true is better than good news that is wrong. 2102 2103 Denial must be weighed against social, financial, physical and emotional costs. When the cost of denial is worse than the benefit of facing reality, we must face reality. 2104 2105 CONSISTENCY 2106 2107 The difficulty lies not in the new ideas, but in escaping the old ones, which ramify, for those brought up as most of us have been, into every corner of our minds. 2108 2109 John Maynard Keynes (British economist, 1883-1946) 2110 2111 Once we've made a commitment - a promise, a choice, taken a stand, invested time, money or effort - we want to remain consistent. We want to feel that we've made the right decision. And the more we have 2112 invested in our behavior the harder it is to change. 2113 2114 '1 can't behave in a way that is inconsistent with my self-image. I have a reputation to uphold I don't want to look weak, dumb or lose face. I want to be seen as nice, smart and in control " 2115 2116 Scottish philosopher and economist Adam Smith said in The Theory of the Moral Sentiments: "The opinion which we entertain of our own character depends entirely on our judgments concerning our past conduct. It 2117 is so disagreeable to think ill of ourselves, that we often purposely turn away our view from those circumstances which might render that judgment unfavorable." 2118 2119 We want to maintain a positive self-image. When that is violated, we use different defenses in order to justify our behavior. We also behave in ways that are consistent with how others see us. If people label 2120 us as talented, we try to appear talented whether or not it is true. 2121 2122 Why do we hang on to a bad idea, an unhappy relationship or a losing investment? Why do politicians continue fighting wars long after it is clear the war is a bad idea? 2123 2124 The more time, money, effort or pain we invest, the more we feel the need to continue, and the more highly we value something - whether or not it is right. We don't want to waste our efforts. This way we 2125 protect our reputation and avoid the pain of accepting a loss. If people challenge our decisions, we become even 2126 2127 60 2128 2129 more committed we are right. And the more individual responsibility we feel for a commitment, the harder it is to give up. 2130 2131 In Too Much Invested to Quit, psychologist Allan Teger said about the Vietnam War: "The longer the war continued, the more difficult it was to justify the additional investments in terms of the value of 2132 possible victory. On the other hand, the longer the war continued, the more difficult it became to write off the tremendous losses without having anything to show for them." 2133 2134 John wanted to employ a new vice president. He told everyone that the guy was terrific but the new employee turned out to be a disaster. Instead of dealing with the mistake, john kept the guy, costing him 2135 much money and aggravation. 2136 2137 We tend to make fast judgments. It is hard to change a first conclusion since a change implies we may be wrong (especially if we need to explain the change to others). We associate being wrong with a threat 2138 to our self-interest. 2139 2140 Warren Buffett says: "What the human being is best at doing is interpreting all new information so that their prior conclusions remain intact." The 17th Century English philosopher Francis Bacon adds: "it is 2141 the peculiar and perpetual error of the human intellect to be more moved and excited by affirmatives than by negatives; whereas it ought properly to hold itself indifferently disposed towards both alike." We 2142 look for evidence that confirms our ideas, beliefs, and actions. Devising reasons why we might be wrong doesn't come easily. For example, when we've made an investment, entered into a relationship, or made 2143 other types of commitments, we tend to seek out evidence confirming that it was the right decision and to ignore information that shows it was wrong. 2144 2145 '1 don't want to sell this declining stock and face a loss. I put $100,000 into this. I must prove to others and myself I made the right choice. " 2146 2147 After we buy a stock, we are more confident it was a good buy than before the investment. We want to feel we did the right thing and keep our beliefs consistent with what we've done. But nothing has changed. 2148 It is the same business before and after. 2149 2150 '1 think it's foolish to abandon a project on which $10 million has been sunk,"said the CEO ofTransCorp. 2151 2152 Why do we do things merely because we've paid for them? 2153 2154 Assume John paid a $1,000 non-refundable fee for a conference, but he no longer wants to participate. He feels he can't afford to waste the already spent 2155 2156 $1,000. Should he go to the conference because he already spent $1,000? Should 2157 2158 61 2159 2160 he pay $1,000 to do something he doesn't want to do? The money is lost forever. Isn't it better to say that the already spent $1,000 is the cost of doing what he really wants to do? Isn't it better to pay to 2161 do what you want? 2162 2163 John and Mary sit through a lousy movie simply because they bought the tickets. They can't get the eight dollars they spent back so it shouldn't make a difference whether they leave or not. The consequences 2164 are the same - the money has already been spent. The choice is between having a good time or a lousy time. 2165 2166 "We invested in a new machine based on the volume-increase set out in the strategic plan. Unfortunately, volume decreased. " 2167 2168 We are most consistent when we have made a public, effortful or voluntary commitment. The more public a decision is, the less likely it is that we will change it. Written commitments are strong since they 2169 require more effort than verbal commitments and can also be made public. 2170 2171 Isn't it better to do what makes sense than to stay consistent with a strategic plan that isn't working? Warren Buffett says, "We do have a few advantages, perhaps the greatest being that we don't have a 2172 strategic plan. Thus we feel no need to proceed in an ordained direction (a course leading almost invariably to silly purchase prices) but can instead simply decide what makes sense for our owners." 2173 2174 Charles Munger says on the value oflong-term plans: 2175 2176 We have very much the philosophy of building our enterprise that Sir William Osler had when he built the John Hopkins Medical School from a very poor start into a model medical school for the whole world. And 2177 what Sir William Osler said - and he quoted this from Carlyle - was: "The task of man is not to see what lies dimly in the distance, but to do what lies clearly at hand." 2178 2179 We try to respond intelligently each day, each week, each month, each year to the information and challenges at hand - horrible assaults that have to be deflected, things that have to be scrambled out of, the 2180 unusual opportunities that come along- and just do the best job we can in responding to those challenges. Obviously, you look ahead as far as you can. But that's not very far. But if you respond intelligently 2181 and diligently to the challenges before you, we think you'll tend to end up with a pretty good institution. 2182 2183 In his Scientific Autobiography and Other Papers, German physicist Max Planck said: "A new scientific truth does not triumph by convincing its opponents and making them see the light, but rather because its 2184 opponents eventually die and a new generation grows up that is familiar with it." 2185 2186 62 2187 2188 Warren Buffett adds: 2189 2190 I think it was Keynes who said, "Most economists are [3mmost [0meconomical about [3mideas [0m- they make the ones they learned in graduate school last a lifetime." What happens is that you spend years getting your Ph.D. 2191 in finance. And [in the process], you learn theories with a lot of mathematics that the average layman can't do. So you become sort of a high priest. And you wind up with an [3menormous [0mamount of yourself in 2192 terms of your ego - and even professional security- invested in those ideas. Therefore, it gets very hard to back off after a given point. 2193 2194 '1 have invested 15 years of my life in this, so I won't walk away now. " 2195 2196 Let's say that a couple is in a bad marriage but have spent 15 years together. Should they get a divorce or should they "stay in there" and remain unhappy because they have invested 15 years of their life? 2197 2198 What other traps may consistency cause us to fall into? 2199 2200 John and his family decided to buy a new car. They chose a dealership that agreed to sell the car $1,000 below the competition. Then the salesman changed the terms. He had discovered an error. In the end, the 2201 price ended up $200 above competition. 2202 2203 In the low-ball technique, the salesperson gives the customer an incentive to enter into an agreement with the intention of changing the terms to the seller's advantage (either by removing the advantage or 2204 adding something undesirable). Once John made the decision and took the time and effort to buy a new car, he committed to the purchase. Otherwise he would appear inconsistent. Instead of backing out of the 2205 deal, he found new reasons to justify his purchase of the car. Low-ball is often used by politicians in elections. 2206 2207 "What a great deal for a refrigerator,"Mary said, reading the advertisements. When she gets to the store, the salesperson tells her that they ran out of the advertised specials. But they have a similar one in 2208 stock. And it is only $150 more. She buys the refrigerator. She is already committed to buying a refrigerator and the salesperson only forces her to be consistent. 2209 2210 Sitting at the negotiation table, the opponent asked John, ''Did you know that you and the managers ofTransCorp are widely known to be cooperative and fair?" 2211 2212 In the labeling technique, people try to get us committed by first applying a label to our personality or values that is consistent with the behavior they want us to take. We often comply to later requests 2213 that are consistent with the label. That is why John's opponent gave John a reputation to uphold. 2214 2215 63 2216 2217 "Will you take my kids to school today?" Mary's neighbor asked One month later, Mary found herself still driving her neighbors' kids to school and even to the movies. How do people seduce us financially, 2218 politically or sexually? They make us first agree to a small request, so small that no one would refuse. This way they create a commitment. Then they make a second and larger request (the one they wanted all 2219 along). We are then more likely to comply. This "foot-in-the-door technique" is based on the principle that if people ask us to make a small commitment, we are more likely to agree to a larger request because 2220 we want to appear consistent. One study showed that 76% of a group of homeowners agreed to put a large billboard on their front lawn, saying "Drive Carefully." Two weeks earlier, the homeowners had been 2221 approached by other researchers, asking them to place a tiny sign saying "Be a Safe driver" on their car windows. They now saw themselves as concerned citizens and people who care enough about driver safety 2222 to take a stand. They also believed that was how other people saw them. When they were later approached, 76% agreed putting up the large sign just to be consistent. In contrast, only 17% of subjects who 2223 hadn't received the earlier visit agreed to put 2224 2225 up the large sign. 2226 2227 When people get us to commit, we become responsible. One experiment staged a theft to find out if onlookers would risk personal harm to stop a crime. A researcher sat on a beach blanket and listened to his 2228 portable radio five feet from the blanket of a randomly chosen person. After awhile, the researcher left the blanket to stroll the beach. A few minutes later a second researcher, pretending to be a thief, 2229 grabbed the radio and ran away. Four people out of twenty put themselves in harm by challenging the thief. But when the procedure was tried somewhat differently, nineteen people became vigilantes, and tried 2230 to stop the thie£ The difference? Before taking his stroll, the researcher asked the subject to "please watch my things" which they all agreed to do. 2231 2232 The 17th Century English poet Samuel Butler wrote: "He that complies against his will, is of his own opinion still." How do we get people to take inner responsibility for their actions? Make it voluntary. We 2233 take responsibility for our behavior in cases when we are internally motivated by satisfaction or interest, when we feel in control, and when we are free from incentives or outside pressure. 2234 2235 Strong convictions can be dangerous. 2236 2237 The German philosopher Friedrich Wilhelm Nietzsche wrote: "Convictions are more dangerous enemies of truth than lies." Intense commitments for political, religious or philosophical ideas create an ideological 2238 bias. People with various political, religious, and philosophical interests are motivated to seek the truths that 2239 2240 64 2241 2242 confirm these interests. Never underestimate the power of ideology. They can act as a device for justifying war and violence. As Blaise Pascal wrote: "Men never do evil so completely and cheerfully as when 2243 they do it from religious conviction." 2244 2245 Charles Munger tells us about the danger of ideology: 2246 2247 Heavy ideology is oneof the most extreme distorters of human cognition. Look at these Islamic Fundamentalists who just gunned down a bunch of Greek tourists shouting, "God's work!" 2248 2249 Ideology does some strange things and distorts cognition terribly. If you get a lot of 2250 2251 heavy ideology young - and, then, you start expressing it - you are really locking your brain into a very unfortunate pattern. And you are going to distort your general cognition. There's a very interesting 2252 history if you take Warren Buffett as an example of worldly wisdom: Warren adored his father - who was a wonderful man. But he was a very heavy ideologue, (right wing, it happened to be), who hung around with 2253 other very heavy ideologues, (right wing, naturally). Warren observed this as a kid. And he decided that ideology was dangerous - and that he was going to stay a long way away from it. And he has throughout 2254 his whole life. That has enormously helped the accuracy of his 2255 2256 cognition. 2257 2258 I learned the same lesson in a different way. My father hated ideology. Therefore, all I had to do was imitate my father and, thereby, stay in what I regard as the right path. People like Dornan on the right 2259 or Nader on the left have obviously gone a little daft. They're extreme examples of what ideology will do to you - particularly violently expressed ideology. Since it pounds ideas in better than it convinces 2260 out, it's a very dangerous thing to do. 2261 2262 Keep in mind 2263 2264 A decision must be active. Lucius Annaeus Seneca said: "There is nothing wrong with changing a plan when the situation has changed." Irish writer Jonathan Swift said: ''A man should never be ashamed to own 2265 that he has been in the wrong, which is but saying, in other words, that he is wiser today than he was yesterday." J.M. Keynes said: "When somebody persuades me that I am wrong, I change my mind. What do you 2266 do?" Sometimes things don't go the way we believe they will. The solution is to face it and act. Charles Munger says: "We've done a lot of that - scrambled out of wrong decisions. I would argue that that's a 2267 big part of having a reasonable record in life. You can't avoid wrong decisions. But if you recognize them promptly and do something about them, you can frequently turn the lemon into lemonade." 2268 2269 If we can get people committed in advance, they tend to live up to their 2270 2271 commitment. For example, make people take a voluntary and public position on some issue. 2272 2273 65 2274 2275 Don't force people to publicly make commitments that you don't later want the opportunity to change. 2276 2277 When you are asked to perform a future action but are uncertain, ask yourself: Would I do this ifI had to do it tomorrow? 2278 2279 Warren Buffett says, "The most important thing to do when you find yourself in a hole is to stop digging." Merely because you've spent money or time on some project or investment doesn't mean you must 2280 continue to spend it in the future. Time, effort, and money spent are gone. Decisions should be based on where you want to be. Not where you've been. Base decisions on the present situation and future 2281 consequences. What happened in the past may be a guide for estimating how likely something is to happen in the future. Ask: What do I want to achieve? What causes that? Considering what I know today and what 2282 is likely to happen in the future, how should I act to achieve my goal? Will new money and time invested achieve my goal? Assume I never invested in this and it was presented to me for the first time, would I 2283 invest in it today? If not, then stop and do something about it. As Charles Munger says: 2284 2285 Berkshire extracted a lot of capital out ofit [the textile business] and put it elsewhere. And if Berkshire had tried to keep fighting the decline of that business with more and more money, it would have 2286 blown most of its capital. There's a time to fight and there's a time to run away. One of my favorite stories, relevant to this story, involves a town in the South. There was this huge grocery store owned by 2287 one of the great national chains. They're a formidable competitor and they had the dominant big grocery store in this town for many, many years doing big volume. Sam Walton of Wal-Mart announced that he was 2288 opening a much bigger, better grocery store with a lot of other wonderful products at incredibly low prices. And the existing very experienced and successful chain, did not wait for Sam Walton's store to 2289 open. They just closed their store right away. 2290 2291 Let someone who wasn't committed to an earlier decision take over the issue. 2292 2293 "Facts do not cease to exist because they are ignored," said British novelist Aldous Huxley. If we only look to confirm our beliefs, we will never discover if we're wrong. Be self-critical and unlearn your 2294 best-loved ideas. Search for evidence that disconfirms ideas and assumptions. Consider alternative outcomes, viewpoints, and answers. Have someone tell you when your thinking is wrong. Warren Buffett says, 2295 "Charlie and I believe that when you find information that contradicts your existing beliefs, you've got a special 2296 2297 obligation to look at it - and quickly. " 2298 2299 Follow the advice of the Italian artist and scientist Leonardo da Vinci: "We 2300 2301 66 2302 2303 know well that mistakes are more easily detected in the works of others than in one's own. When you are painting you should take a flat mirror and often look at your work within it, and it will then be seen 2304 in reserve, and will appear to be by the hand of some other master, and you will be better able to judge of its faults than in any other way." 2305 2306 DEPRIVAL SYNDROME 2307 2308 You don't change something people love. 2309 2310 Faith Popcorn (American futurist) 2311 2312 As we've seen in Part One, we have an aversion to loss. We dislike losing the things we have more than we appreciate gaining the things we don't have. 2313 2314 When something we like is (or threatens to be) taken away, we often value it higher. Take away people's freedom, status, reputation, money or anything they value, and they get upset. We don't like to lose the 2315 freedom to choose how to act or believe or what to have. For example, people are likely to fight a restrictive law that takes away a benefit they have enjoyed for a long time. The more we like what is taken 2316 away or the larger the commitment we've made, the more upset we become. This can create hatred, revolts, violence and retaliations. 2317 2318 How do people react when we try to lower their income? 2319 2320 Charles Munger illustrates the power of deprival when negotiating takeaways in labor negotiations: 2321 2322 You're facing deprival super-reaction syndrome - people just go bananas. And (B) the union representative has to bring his members the deprival message and endure the Pavlovian mere-association hatred that 2323 results. Therefore, he won't do it - largely for that reason. So you have [3mtwo [0mpowerful psychological effects making it hell. 2324 2325 All of those strikes in the late 1800s and the early 1900s where Pinkerton guards were shooting people were about takeaways. Arriving immigrants were willing to work cheap. And capitalist proprietors tried to 2326 reduce wages - sometimes because they felt they had to because their competitors were doing it and sometimes because they simply wanted to make more money. At any rate, all of that murder and mayhem was the 2327 result of deprival super-reaction syndrome plus the reality that nobody wanted to be the carrier of bad news. 2328 2329 '1 shou/,d take the conservative approach. Failure is embarrassing and mayget me fired " People's aversion to losing may make people overly conservative or engage in cover-ups. 2330 2331 67 2332 2333 The doctor told Mary: "You may die ifyou do not change your behavior. " 2334 2335 Our loss aversion makes us more sensitive to information that has negative implications for us. For example, health-related messages can either focus on the benefits of performing an act (gain) or the 2336 possible costs of not doing it (loss). One study showed that women were more likely to engage in breast self examination when they were presented with information emphasizing the possible negative 2337 consequences (loss of good health, longevity) of not performing self-examination compared to information that focused on the benefits of doing it. Other studies show that when persuading people to undergo 2338 risky medical procedures, it is more effective to focus on positive outcomes (e.g. survival rate) than negative ones (e.g. mortality rate). 2339 2340 john tells Mary: '1 can't sell the stock now. I have to wait until it gets back up to what I paid for it. Anyway, I don't realize a loss unless I sell. " 2341 2342 We hate to admit we've lost money. Our loss aversion contributes to status quo bias - we prefer to hang on to what we have. We even put a higher value on the things we already own than we are willing to pay 2343 for the same things if we didn't own them (giving them up feels like a loss). This is why many companies offer money-back guarantees on their products. Once we have taken possession of some item, we are not 2344 likely to return it. 2345 2346 Charles Munger says, "The deprival super-reaction syndrome of man helps cause much ruin as people's cognition is distorted as a result of their suffering losses and seeing near misses." We hate to sell losing 2347 stocks. It is the same as admitting to others and ourselves that we've made a mistake. We therefore hold on to our losers too long and sell our winners too soon. A realized loss feels worse than suffering the 2348 same loss on paper. The pain of feeling responsible for making a bad decision also plays a role (regret). The stock may bounce back after we've sold. And the more money and effort we've put in, the harder it 2349 is to let it go. 2350 2351 We also feel that losing the opportunity to make money is less painful than losing the same amount of money. But a lost opportunity of making $100 has the same value as a real loss of $100. 2352 2353 john's friend Allan bought a house five years ago for $200,000. 2354 2355 Four years later, Allan's company moves to another city. The local real estate market is depressed. He is offered $170,000 but feels he can't afford a loss. So he waits another year and this time the offered 2356 price is $150,000. 2357 2358 Isn't it better for Allan to concentrate on what the house is worth rather than on what he paid? 2359 2360 68 2361 2362 John kept pouring dollars in the machine. ''I got Cherry, Cherry, Bar. Tm close now. " We want and place higher value on something when we almost have it and lose it. Charles Munger says, "One reason why 2363 horse races, bingo and these things have always been so popular is because of all these near misses." Frequent near misses are like small reinforcements and make us want to try again and again. 2364 2365 Just as people take larger risks when threatened, after a loss, we want to catch up, so we end up taking more risks to get even. But as Warren Buffett and Charles Munger say: 2366 2367 Buffett: A very important principle in investing is that you don't have to make it back the way you lost it. In fact, it's usually a mistake to try to make it back the way you lost it. 2368 2369 Munger: That's the reason so many people are ruined by gambling - they get behind and then they feel like they have to get it back the way they lost it. It's a deep part of human nature. It's very smart just 2370 to lick it - by will... 2371 2372 Buffett: One of the important things in stocks is that the stock does not know that you own it. You have all these feelings about it: You remember what you paid. You remember who told you about it - all these 2373 little things. And it doesn't give a [3mdamn. [0mIt just sits there. If a stock's at $50, somebody's paid $100 and feels terrible; somebody else has paid $10 and feels wonderful - all these feelings. And it has no 2374 impact whatsoever ... 2375 2376 John and Mary's daughter didn't want the toy they gave her; she wanted the toy they didn't give her. 2377 2378 Michel de Montaigne said: "To forbid us something is to make us want it." We want what we can't have. Forbidden fruit tastes best. Mark Twain said, "It was not that Adam ate the apple for the apple's sake, 2379 but because it was forbidden. It would have been better for us - oh infinitely better for us - if the serpent had been forbidden." Forbid someone to do something and they find it more attractive than they did 2380 before it was forbidden. For example, when Miami banned the use of phosphate-based detergents, people turned to smuggling in supplies and hoarding (since fear of scarcity encourages hoarding) and even rated 2381 the banned products as better than before. 2382 2383 "Since a real estate lot in this area is both rare and hard to obtain, I want it. " 2384 2385 We want and value more what is scarce or unique. We want what is (or threatens to be) less available. The less available it is, the more we desire it. That's why we subscribe to newsletters containing 2386 exclusive and restricted information. And why we participate in initial public offerings and buy stocks on hot tips. 2387 2388 We value higher what has recently been less available than things that have 2389 2390 69 2391 2392 been scarce all along. We fall for limited offers and deadlines like, "The offer ends at midnight. We only have a few left. This is the last chance. "By making things less available, merchants make them seem 2393 more valuable. 2394 2395 lot of people are competing for this lot at the auction." 2396 2397 How do we create demand? Create competition. Make people perceive there is a huge competition for the item and limit the number of people that can participate in the bidding. If others want what's scarce, we 2398 want it even more. 2399 2400 When we can't get something, we lower our opinion of it. When we can get something that others don't want, we don't want it either. 2401 2402 Keep in mind 2403 2404 Know your goals and options. Ask: Why do I want this? For emotional or rational reasons? 2405 2406 What you paid for your house, stock, or car has no relevance to its value. If the 2407 2408 value is below what you paid, you don't have to get even. If you bought a stock for $100 and it is now $50, you should sell it, if it is not worth more than $50. Ask: Suppose I hadn't made the investment, 2409 would I make this investment today at today's price? 2410 2411 Remember that people respond to immediate crisis and threats. Anything that happens gradually, they tend to put off. If we want people to take a risk, we should make them feel behind (losing). If we want them 2412 to stay with the status quo or reject risk, we should make them feel safe. 2413 2414 Charles Munger shows how we can use the force of deprival to persuade (for a reputable reason): 2415 2416 In Captain Cook's day, he took these long voyages. At the time, scurvy was the dread of the long voyage. And in scurvy, your living gums putrefy in your mouth - after which the disease gets unpleasant and 2417 kills you. And being on a primitive sailing ship with a bunch of dying sailors is a very awkward business. So everybody was terribly interested in scurvy, but they didn't [3mknow [0mabout Vitamin C. Well, Captain 2418 Cook, being a smart man with a multiple-model kind of approach, noticed that Dutch ships had less scurvy than English ships on long voyages. So he said, "What are the Dutch doing that's different?" 2419 2420 And he noticed they had all these barrels of sauerkraut. So he thought: 'Tm going on these long voyages. And it's very dangerous. Sauerkraut may help." So he laid in all this sauerkraut which, incidentally, 2421 happens to contain a trace of vitamin C. But English sailors were a tough, cranky and dangerous bunch in that day. They hated "krauts". And they were used to their standard food and booze. So how do you get 2422 such English sailors to eat sauerkraut? 2423 2424 70 2425 2426 Well, Cook didn't want to tell 'em that he was doing it in the hope it would prevent scurvy - because they might mutiny and take over the ship if they thought that he was taking them on a voyage so long that 2427 scurvy was likely. 2428 2429 So here's what he did: Officers ate one place where the men could observe them. And for a long time, he served sauerkraut to the officers, but not to the men. And then, finally, Captain Cook said, "Well, the 2430 men can have it one day a week." 2431 2432 In due course, he had the whole crew eating sauerkraut. I regard that as a very constructive use of elementary psychology. It may have saved God knows how many lives and caused God knows how much achievement. 2433 2434 STATUS Quo AND Do-NOTHING SYNDROME 2435 2436 Nothing will ever be attempted if all possible objections must first be overcome. 2437 2438 Samuel Johnson 2439 2440 When john and Mary bought their new car, they stuck to their usual brand. 2441 2442 We prefer to keep things the way they are. We resist change and prefer effort minimization. We favor routine behavior over innovative behavior. 2443 2444 The more emotional a decision is or the more choices we have, the more we prefer the status quo. This is why we stick with our old jobs, brand of car, etc. Even in cases where the costs of switching are very 2445 low. 2446 2447 '1 fear the social consequences if I make the wrong choice, so I decide to do nothing. " We want to feel good about the choices we make so we can justify our actions for others and ourselves. We are more 2448 bothered by harm that comes from action than harm that comes from inaction. We feel worse when we fail as a result of taking action than when we fail from doing nothing. 2449 2450 We prefer the default option, i.e., the alternative that is selected automatically unless we change it. In a real-life experiment on auto insurance rates, car drivers in New Jersey and Pennsylvania were given 2451 the choice ofa limited right to sue for pain and suffering in exchange for lower insurance rates. But the default option was different for each state. Car owners in New Jersey were automatically given the 2452 limited right unless they made an active decision and said differently. In Pennsylvania, the default option was the full right to sue. What happened? Citizens of both states preferred the default option. 79% 2453 of New Jersey drivers preferred the limited right to sue, whereas 70% of Pennsylvania drivers preferred the full right to sue. The difference in amount spent on insurance in the two states was about $200 2454 million. The preference for defaults has also been found in decisions about organ donation, health care plans, and pension savings. 2455 2456 71 2457 2458 Sometimes we don't act when we know we should. We ignore Warren Buffett's Noah principle: "Predicting rain doesn't count; building arks does." 2459 2460 "Why invest resources in something today since we don't get any credit for preventing something we don't even know will happen. " 2461 2462 We often ignore distant problems and we are reluctant to prevent future threats. Warren Buffett says: "It took Noah 20 years to build an ark. And people said he was being silly because the skies were 2463 beautiful. And of course, the whole time, he looked stupid- until it started raining. You can spend a long time building an ark while everybody else is out there enjoying the sun." 2464 2465 Keep in mind 2466 2467 Deciding to do nothing is also a decision. And the cost of doing nothing could be greater than the cost of taking an action. 2468 2469 Remember what you want to achieve. 2470 2471 Once we know what to do, we should do it. The 19th Century British biologist Thomas Henry Huxley said: "Perhaps the most valuable result of all education is the ability to make yourself do the thing you have 2472 to do when it ought to be done whether you like it or not. It is the first lesson that ought to be learned and however early a person's training begins, it is probably the last lesson a person learns 2473 thoroughly." 2474 2475 IMPATIENCE 2476 2477 The CEO ofTransCorp wants his bonus today and therefore he makes a decision that increases this year's profit at the cost of a possibly larger profit in the foture. 2478 2479 We give more weight to the present than to the future. We seek pleasure today at a cost of what may be better in the future. We prefer an immediate reward to a delayed but maybe larger reward. We spend today 2480 what we should save for tomorrow. This means that we may pay a high price in the future for a small immediate reward. For example, we buy things we can't afford on credit cards. 2481 2482 We are impatient in the short run and patient in the far away future. Studies show that we tend to become less patient when rewards are more immediate. Our discount rates (the values we assign to something) 2483 are higher in the short run than in the long run. For example, when a small reward is due tomorrow and a larger reward is due in one year, people often prefer the small immediate reward. But when the small 2484 reward is due in one year and the larger reward in two years, people tend to prefer the larger long-term reward. Studies show that one explanation for this is that outcomes occurring in the future are 2485 perceived as less certain. 2486 2487 72 2488 2489 Keep in mind 2490 2491 Michel de Montaigne said: "I conceive that pleasures are to be avoided if greater pains be the consequence, and pains to be coveted that will terminate in greater pleasures." Consider both the short and 2492 long-term consequences of a decision. Weigh present good/bad against future good/bad. Short-term suffering may lead to long term pleasure. 2493 2494 IO. ENVY [1mAND JEALOUSY [0mMan will do many things to get himself loved; he will do all things to get himself envied. 2495 2496 -MarkTwain 2497 2498 Aristotle said: "Envy is pain at the good fortune of others." We evaluate our own situation by comparing what we have with what others have. Aristotle continues: "We envy those who are near us in time, place, 2499 age or reputation." It is people similar to us we envy most. Financial historian Charles P. Kindleberger says in Manias, Panics, and Crashes: "There is nothing so disturbing to one's well-being and judgment 2500 as to see a friend get rich." For example, studies show that how happy we are is partly determined by where we stand in relation to similar others. The 19th Century German philosopher Arthur Schopenhauer 2501 said: ''As Hobbes observes, all mental pleasure consists in being able to compare oneself with others to one's own advantage." 2502 2503 We are jealous when we perceive a threat to a valued relationship. Studies show that jealousy is ranked among the top three motives for murder. 2504 2505 Keep in mind 2506 2507 Bertrand Russell said that envy is one of the fundamental causes of human suffering. The 18th Century French philosopher and mathematician Marquis de Condorcet said: "Enjoy your own life without comparing it 2508 with that of another." As long as you achieve your goals, it shouldn't matter if someone else does better. 2509 2510 Studies show that it matters whether we believe that others deserve their success. Aristotle said: "The best way to avoid envy is to deserve the success you get." 2511 2512 On the other hand, the 18th Century Dutch physician Bernard de Mandeville said that vices such as greed, envy, and vanity all lead to public benefits by encouraging enterprise. 2513 2514 73 2515 2516 II. CONTRAST COMPARISON 2517 2518 Fill one bucket with cold water, another with hot water, and a third with water at room temperature. Put one hand in the bucket of cold water and the other hand in the bucket of hot water. Then put both your 2519 hands in the bucket of room temperature water. What happens? You will feel that your cold hand feels warmer and that your warm hand feels colder. 2520 2521 We judge stimuli bydifferences and changes and not absolute magnitudes. For example, we evaluate stimuli like temperature, loudness, brightness, health, status, or prices based on their contrast or difference 2522 from a reference point (the prior or concurrent stimuli or what we have become used to). This reference point changes with new experiences and context. 2523 2524 This means that how we value things depend on what we compare them with. 2525 2526 The grossly overpriced $100 tie seemed reasonable after john bought the fairly priced 2527 2528 $1,500 suit. 2529 2530 The order in which something is presented matters. Sales people often try to sell the more costly item first. We are out buying a computer and some diskettes. In comparison to $1,500 computer, diskettes at 2531 $10 seem like a bargain. After we buy the big ticket items, the add-ons seem cheap in comparison. 2532 2533 Experiments have shown that we go across town to save $10 on a clock radio but not to save $10 on a large-screen TV. The difference between $100 and $110 seems like a larger saving than the difference between 2534 $2850 and $2860. But it's the same $10 saving. 2535 2536 "What I am used to getting in social benefits is the norm against how I measure fairness,"says john's friend Mark. 2537 2538 A hotel has been renting rooms for $100 a night. The day after a hurricane, the hotel raises its prices to $150. Studies show that we consider this unfair. We determine what is fair or not in reference to 2539 what we have been used to. This means that policies that have habit-forming consequences may be hard to reverse if they are seen as a loss. 2540 2541 One ofTransCorp's subsidiaries developed a high-priced version of the machine. Even if it doesn't sell well, it will help induce customers to buy their cheaper (but still expensive) version. 2542 2543 The same thing may appear attractive when compared to less attractive things and unattractive when compared to more attractive things. For example, studies show that a person of average attractiveness is seen 2544 as less attractive when 2545 2546 74 2547 2548 compared to highly attractive others. Charles Munger gives another example: "In my generation, when women lived at home until they got married, I saw some perfectly terrible marriages made by highly desirable 2549 women because they lived in terrible homes. And I've seen some terrible second marriages which were made because they were slight improvements over an even worse first marriage." 2550 2551 In one experiment, a group of people was asked to choose between $6 and an elegant pen. Most choose the cash. Another group of people was asked to choose between $6, the elegant pen, or an inferior pen. Most 2552 choose the elegant pen. By adding an inferior option, another option seemed more attractive. 2553 2554 Mary is looking at houses. The real estate broker knows that the house he is trying to sell Mary is in poor shape and a bad area. He starts by showing Mary bad properties in an ugly neighborhood. Afterwards, 2555 he takes her to the house he wanted to sell all along. Suddenly this house and the area seem great in comparison to the other houses she saw. 2556 2557 Another example of contrast comparison is when we interview one job candidate after another. 2558 2559 "If we slowly and gradually over time manipu/,ate the numbers, the auditors won't notice it." 2560 2561 Contrasts may blind us to change until it's too late. For example, we often don't notice the bad behavior of others if it goes sour gradually over time. 2562 2563 Often we see reality as constant, although it gradually changes. A stimulus must reach an absolute threshold before we can detect it. Before we notice a change in a stimulus, a certain relative change most 2564 occur. If the change is slow enough, we don't notice the change. Our ability to detect and react to changes in a stimulus decreases as its magnitude increases. To a small stimulus, only a small amount must be 2565 added. To a larger stimulus, a large amount must be added. 2566 2567 Sometimes it is the small, gradual, invisible changes that harm us the most. Warren Buffett says: "One of the problems in society is that the most important issues are often these incremental type things." He 2568 continues: 2569 2570 The world is not going to come to an end because tomorrow there are 200 or 250 thousand more people on the planet than there were today. That's about the number it grows every day... it is like eating about 2571 300 calories more each day than you burn up; it has no effect on you today. You don't get up from the table and all of a sudden everybody says, "My God, you look fat compared to when you sat down!" But, if 2572 you keep doing it over time, the incremental problems are hard to attack because that one extra piece of piedoesn't really seem to make a difference. The 250,000 people tomorrow don't seem to make any 2573 difference, but 2574 2575 75 2576 2577 the cumulative effects of them will make a huge difference over time, just like overeating will make a huge difference over time. The time to attack those problems is early. 2578 2579 Keep in mind 2580 2581 Evaluate people and objects by themselves and not by their contrast. 2582 2583 12 . .ANCHORING 2584 2585 The CEO informs john what he told the board members of TransCorp: "Our costs were one million over budget but I told them we were three million over. They were thrilled when I later told them it was only one 2586 million. I always set low targets to exceed expectations. " 2587 2588 We are over-influenced by certain information acting as a reference "anchor" for future judgments. 2589 2590 '1 made a bad investment, paying $50 for something now worth $40,"says John. We don't price a thing according to its value but its relative price. If we for example bought a stock for $50 with a present price 2591 of $40, we judge how good our decision was in reference to our purchase price. Or if a stock we consider buying trades around $50 for some time and drops to $35, we tend to get anchored on the $50 and 2592 automatically assume that $35 is a bargain. The present 2593 2594 price of a stock in relation to some past quote doesn't mean anything. The underlying business value is what matters. 2595 2596 One of TransCorp's employees was on trial for backdating options. '1 demand a sentence of 5 years,"said the prosecutor. '1 suggest 4.5 years,"countered the defense. The initial figures being presented can 2597 also influence legal decisions. For example, the value at which a lawsuit settles or the damages a judge awards in a civil case. Having the last word in court is sometimes disadvantageous. Studies show that 2598 the defense's sentencing recommendation is strongly influenced by the prosecutor's demand, which in turn drives judicial sentencing. 2599 2600 Studies also show that even randomly determined numbers may influence experienced legal professionals. 2601 2602 John's friend said· /ls a used car salesman, I anchor a potential buyer to a high price and then slowly reduce it. This way I get a good final price and the customer perceives he got a good deal. " 2603 2604 A friend of John and Mary was selling his chain of ice cream stores. The buyer had discussed a price of $10 million. But the seller researched prices of similar 2605 2606 76 2607 2608 businesses. He outlined his research for the buyer and told him his target price of $15 million. Then the seller started to negotiate on his methodology, not on the price. The $15 million got anchored with 2609 the buyer as the basis for further discussion. The seller finally sold his stores for $13 million. 2610 2611 Keep in mind 2612 2613 • Consider choices from a zero base level and remember what you want to achieve. 2614 2615 • Adjust information to reality. 2616 2617 VIVIDNESS AND RECENCY 2618 2619 The attention which we lend to an experience is proportional to its vivid or interesting character; and it is a notorious fact that what interests us most vividly at the time is, other things equal, what we 2620 remember best. 2621 2622 William James (American psychologist and philosopher, 1842-1910) 2623 2624 John invests in a company based on a beautifully written quarterly earnings report and an entertaining presentation. 2625 2626 The more dramatic, salient, personal, entertaining, or emotional some information, event or experience is, the more influenced we are. For example, the easier it is to imagine an event, the more likely we are 2627 to think that it will happen. 2628 2629 We are easily influenced when we are told stories because we relate to stories better than to logic or fact. We love to be entertained. Information we receive directly, through our eyes or ears has more 2630 impact than information that may have more evidential value. A vivid description from a friend or family member is more believable than true evidence. Statistical data is often overlooked. Studies show that 2631 jurors are influenced by vivid descriptions. Lawyers try to present dramatic and memorable testimony. 2632 2633 "Seeing the face of a 9-year old girl who is suffering feels awful. " 2634 2635 Joseph Stalin said: ''A single death is a tragedy; a million deaths is a statistic." Information that moves us emotionally makes us pay greater attention to the event itself than to its magnitude. Statistics 2636 rarely spark our emotions. An individual face and name will. 2637 2638 A Chinese proverb says: "Kill one, frighten ten thousand." We often overestimate events that are unlikely to happen merely because they receive attention in the news. Drama and danger sells. The media 2639 capitalizes on fear because there is money in it. Major accidents, such as airplane crashes or shark attacks, grab people's attention and make headlines regardless of their probability. This causes us to 2640 believe a problem is 2641 2642 77 2643 2644 larger than it really is. Sometimes we believe an event has increased in frequency because we see it more. But the media may only cover it more. 2645 2646 john sold every stock he owned since the media reported bad economic news. 2647 2648 We give too much weight to information we've seen, heard, read or experienced most recently. For example, when judging performance, we overweigh what happened most recently and underweigh or ignore the long 2649 term evidence or what on average happens (assuming those are representative of reality). 2650 2651 We make predictions by extrapolating recent trends and conditions. The stock market falls into nose bleed territory and we assume the world is going under. After a bad event happens, we tend to overestimate 2652 the likelihood of it happening again. For example, studies show that after an earthquake, the number of people carrying earthquake insurance rises sharply. 2653 2654 Keep in mind 2655 2656 • The media has its weaknesses, biases and vulnerability to manipulation and deception. Consider what is relevant and the normal outcome in similar situations. 2657 2658 • Accurate information is better than dramatic information. Back up vivid stories with facts and numbers. 2659 2660 • Separate noise and chance events from what is important. Ask: Is it relevant? Does it make sense? Is it representative evidence? Was it a random event? 2661 2662 • Trends may be wrong. Ask: Is it a permanent or temporary effect? 2663 2664 OMISSION AND ABSTRACT BLINDNESS 2665 2666 We react to stimuli that we personally encounter or that grabs our attention. We react more strongly to the concrete and specific than to the abstract. We overweigh personal experiences over vicarious. We see 2667 only what we have names for. We tend to focus only on the present information rather than what information may potentially be missing. For example, when planning, we often place too much importance on the 2668 specific future event and not enough on other possible events and their consequences that can cause the event to be delayed or not happen. 2669 2670 Today 14 million people didn't win the lottery. 2671 2672 We base what is likely to happen on what we see. Not on what we don't see. We don't see what could have happened. We see the winners because they are vocal or visible and get media coverage. We don't see the 2673 quiet losers. We see the successful forecasters. We don't see those who didn't predict well. We see the kind 2674 2675 78 2676 2677 of risk that makes headlines. We don't see the statistical risk. We see the benefits of government expenditure. We don't see the costs and benefits of resources alternative use. We don't see the alternative 2678 uses of taxpayers money for consumption, saving or investing. 2679 2680 We see the available information. We don't see what isn't reported. Missing information doesn't draw our attention. We tend not to think about other possibilities, alternatives, explanations, outcomes or 2681 attributes. When we try to find out if one thing causes another, we only see what happened, not what didn't happen. We see when a procedure works, not when it doesn't work. When we use checklists to find out 2682 possible reasons for why something doesn't work, we often don't see that what is not on the list in the first place may be the reason for the problem. 2683 2684 john asks his son Adam which university he would like to attend. Mary instead asks Adam which university he doesn't like. Adam both selects and rejects university B. Why would Adam both like and not like 2685 university B? Because when we choose, we compare positive attributes but when we reject, we compare negative attributes. Since university B had more positive and negative qualities than the other schools, 2686 Adam picked B. 2687 2688 Studies show that when deciding which parent should receive sole custody of a child, juries focus on information that makes one parent seem better than the other. But when deciding which parent should be 2689 denied custody, juries focus on information that makes one parent seem inferior to the other. This means that if one parent has average economic, social and emotional features and the other parent more 2690 striking positive and negative features, we will both choose and reject the same parent. This means that we often both choose and reject options that are of a more striking or complex nature over average 2691 ones. 2692 2693 John's mother was concentrating on talking on her cell phone so she didn't see the other car coming. 2694 2695 We don't see much of what passes our eyes when we are focused on something else. We only see what we focus our attention on. Sometimes we don't see what is right in front of us. One study showed that a few 2696 experienced pilots trying to land a plane in a flight simulator were so concentrated on the flight information display, they didn't see that a second plane was blocking their runway. Until it was too late to 2697 avoid a collision. 2698 2699 Keep in mind 2700 2701 • Look for alternative explanations. 2702 2703 79 2704 2705 • Consider missing information. Know what you want to achieve. 2706 2707 • Compare both positive and negative characteristics. 2708 2709 REc1PROCATION 2710 2711 There is no duty more indispensable than that of returning a kindness. All men distrust one forgetful of a benefit. 2712 2713 Marcus Tullius Cicero (Roman statesman and writer, 106-43 BC) 2714 2715 In return for his loyalty to the CEO, John received a promotion. 2716 2717 We tend to repay in kind what others have done for us - good or bad. 2718 2719 Do you return Christmas cards? In one study a researcher sent out cards to strangers. Dozens of people sent back cards, even though they'd never heard of the person. Whenever someone does something for us we 2720 want to do something back. No wonder companies use free trials and send out free samples. A gift with our name on it is hard not to reciprocate. 2721 2722 '1 praised him for a job well done, and I received a motivated employee. " 2723 2724 '1 told him about his mistake, and he became hostile towards me. " 2725 2726 We respond the same way as we are treated. If we are unfair to others, people are unfair back. If people trust us, we tend to trust them. If people criticize us, we criticize them back. If people we don't 2727 like do us a favor or an uninvited favor, we reciprocate anyway. 2728 2729 Warren Buffett tells us how Berkshire treats management: 2730 2731 Three quarters of our managers are independently wealthy. They don't need to get up and go to work at all. Most of them have tens and tens of million of dollars. So I've got to create or I've got to maintain 2732 an environment where the thing they want to do most in the world is to go to work that day and the next day. And, I say to myself, "What would make me feel that way?" One way is to feel you are running your 2733 own show. If I had people second guessing me all day, I would get sick of it. I would say, "What the hell do I need this for?" And, that's exactly the way our managers would feel if I went around 2734 second-guessing them or telling them how to run their business. 2735 2736 A woman in Houston caught her husband and his mistress in a hotel parking lot, and proceeded to run the husband down with her car. 2737 2738 We reciprocate unfair behavior even if it costs us. Some examples are: ugly divorces that cost people large sums, trade retaliations, costly strikes in connection with union negotiations, sabotage by a 2739 mistreated employee or failure to agree in legal nuisance cases. 2740 2741 80 2742 2743 John is negotiating to buy a small business. The seller asks a higher price than john is prepared to pay, so he declines. The seller then makes a concession and reduces the price. We make a concession to 2744 people who have first made a concession to us. Since John views the lower price as a concession, he feels a need to reciprocate and accepts the lower price. This price was what the seller wanted in the first 2745 place. Contrast comparison is also involved - the seller's second request seems smaller and therefore much better. This method of making an exaggerated request and settling for a smaller one is often used in 2746 negotiations. It also increases the chance that John will live up to the deal since he feels responsible for having "dictated" the final terms. 2747 2748 The "that's-not-all" technique is related to reciprocal concessions and often used in infomercials. For example, a company presents a product at $49.00, and before the customer can respond, they add an 2749 additional product "for free." 2750 2751 Keep in mind 2752 2753 • People don't want to feel indebted. We are disliked if we don't allow people to give back what we've given them. 2754 2755 • A favor or gift is most effective when it is personal, significant, and unexpected. 2756 2757 • Before you make concessions, think about what you want to achieve. 2758 2759 • The American car manufacturer Henry Ford said: "If there is any one secret of success, it lies in the ability to get the other person's point ofview and see things from his angle as well as from your own." 2760 2761 • Follow Confucius: "What you don't want yourself, don't do to others. Reward hostility with justice, and good deeds with good deeds." Give people what you want in return from them. Ask: Assuming others are 2762 like me, how would I like to be treated if the roles were reversed? 2763 2764 • Set the correct example. In Confucius words: "Example is better than law. For where the laws govern, the people are shameless in evading punishment. But where example governs, the people have a sense of 2765 shame and improve." 2766 2767 LIKING AND SOCIAL ACCEPTANCE 2768 2769 The deepest principle in human nature is the craving to be appreciated. 2770 2771 William James 2772 2773 "john likes his colleague, Ted, because they share the same values and prefer the same type of suits. " 2774 2775 We want to be liked and accepted. We believe, trust and agree with people we know and like. We do things for people we like. We like the people who like us 2776 2777 81 2778 2779 (because we like to be liked.) And if we feel that a person likes us, we tend to like them back. 2780 2781 What can people do to make us like them? We tend to like our kin and romantic partners and people who are similar to us in background, opinion, lifestyle, interest, attitude, looks, values, and belief. Also, 2782 those who are physically attractive, popular, cooperative, or people we have positive associations with. We also like and trust anything familiar. 2783 2784 Aristotle said: "Personal beauty is a greater recommendation than any letter of introduction." Studies show that we believe that physically attractive people have a more desirable personality than 2785 average-looking or unattractive people. Experiments show that attractive criminals are seen as less aggressive and get a milder punishment than ugly criminals. But like the 6th Century Greek writer Aesop 2786 wrote, "Appearances often are deceiving." 2787 2788 '1 am a sucker far flattery. " 2789 2790 We like people who compliment us - true or not - and make us feel special. To quote the British Prime Minister and novelist Benjamin Disraeli: "Talk to a man about himself and he will listen for hours." We 2791 also like the people who give us what we are missing in life. 2792 2793 "To get them to do business with me, I associate myself with powerfal friends and disassociate myself from losers. I also try to get introduced by someone of established credibility. " 2794 2795 People believe we have the same personality as those we associate with. Credibility leads to trust. 2796 2797 "We have a common enemy. By cooperating we both gain. " 2798 2799 We like people who cooperate with us. How do we get people to cooperate? Create an external common threat or an opportunity for mutual gain. 2800 2801 '1 believe she likes me, so I like her to. " 2802 2803 We reciprocate the way others see us. If we perceive others dislike us, we tend to dislike them. 2804 2805 "I won the respect and friendship of my opponent by asking him to do me a favor. " Asking a favor of someone is likely to increase that person's liking for us. Why? Because people want to be seen as 2806 consistent with their behavior. Benjamin Franklin tells us about an old maxim: "He that has once done you a kindness 2807 2808 82 2809 2810 will be more ready to do you another, than he whom you yourself have obliged." 2811 2812 "Since I want to be accepted, I always focus on the way I appear to others. " 2813 2814 We want to be socially accepted and not disliked or rejected. We have a strong desire for avoiding social disapproval, exclusion, humiliation, public shame and losing status. This contributes to conformity. 2815 William James says: ''A man's Social Self is the recognition which he gets from his mates... No more fiendish punishment could be devised... than that one should be turned loose in society and remain 2816 absolutely unnoticed by all the members thereo£" 2817 2818 The French 17th Century writer Francois Due de la Rochefoucauld wrote: "We only confess our little faults to persuade people that we have no big ones." We adapt what we say and do to suit our audience and 2819 create a desired impression. We behave like others do and don't speak the truth or openly question people for fear of the consequences. We don't want to be the person who stands out. This is one reason why 2820 people who are overly concerned about what others think about them prefer to be around like-minded people. It's more comfortable than standing out and risking social disapproval. 2821 2822 '1 don't like him because he is egoistic, defensive, always complains and has a bad temper." 2823 2824 We don't learn from people we don't like and we don't want to be associated with them. The people we don't like are the ones we perceive as dissimilar to us, people we are in competition with, those we 2825 perceive as threatening, or people that are self-absorbed, complaining, greedy, etc. We tend to dislike people who have been dehumanized - for example, people who have been described as evil or animals. 2826 2827 Keep in mind 2828 2829 • Concentrate on the issue and what you want to achieve. 2830 2831 • Don't depend on the encouragement or criticism of others. Marcus Aurelius Antoninus said: "How much time he gains who does not look to see what his neighbor says or does or thinks." 2832 2833 • Don't automatically mistake people's appearance for reality. It may be a social mask. 2834 2835 • Social approval is an effective way to make people behave correctly. Why do people avoid certain actions? Because they are afraid of the social punishment these actions may cause. 2836 2837 • Benjamin Franklin wrote: "Love your enemies, for they tell you your faults." 2838 2839 83 2840 2841 Francois Due de la Rochefoucauld adds: "Our enemies' opinion of us comes closer to the truth than our own." 2842 2843 SOCIAL PROOF 2844 2845 If 40 million people say a foolish thing, it does not become a wise one. 2846 2847 Somerset Maugham (British novelist, 1874-1965) 2848 2849 "But everybody else is doing it." 2850 2851 Do you rely on others for advice and actions? Most people do. In True Believer, American philosopher Eric Hoffer wrote, "When people are free to do as they please, they usually imitate each other." We are 2852 social animals, influenced by what we see other people doing and believing. We believe that others know more than we do. 2853 2854 We want what others want. Since everybody else wants it, we assume there has to be a reason. We avoid what others avoid. We imitate without thinking. Especially when many or similar people do it, when we are 2855 uncertain, in an unfamiliar environment, in a crowd, lack knowledge, or if we suffer from stress or low self esteem. 2856 2857 Sellers of fashion, books, movies, etc., know that if enough people like something, others will eventually follow. We trust testimonials from people that we see as similar to us. 2858 2859 Warren Buffett says: ''As happens in Wall Street all too often, what the wise do in 2860 2861 the beginning, fools do in the end." He tells an instructive story: 2862 2863 This friend, who ran a property-casualty insurer, was explaining to his directors why he wanted to acquire a certain life insurance company. After droning rather unpersuasively through the economics and 2864 strategic rationale for the acquisition, he abruptly abandoned the script. With an impish look, he simply said: "Aw, fellas, all the other kids have one." 2865 2866 '1 don't understand why they don't listen to me," said the CEO ofTransCorp. When we are uncertain, we are most likely to follow what people similar to us do. The CEO would therefore be more likely to have his 2867 message heard ifhe used a spokesperson who already supported the CEO's ideas and who the audience saw as similar to themselves, such as a colleague. 2868 2869 john's stockbroker recommends the same stock as other brokers. When john asked him why, he replied '1'd rather be wrong in a group than right by myself" 2870 2871 We feel more comfortable as part of a majority. It acts as a protection from criticism. If we are wrong and everybody else is too, we get less blame. To quote 2872 2873 84 2874 2875 J.M. Keynes: "Worldly wisdom teaches that it is better for reputation to fail conventionally than to succeed unconventionally." Warren Buffett adds: 2876 2877 Most managers have very little incentive to make the intelligent-but-with-some-chance of-looking-like-an-idiot decision. Their personal gain/loss ratio is all too obvious: if an unconventional decision works 2878 out well, they get a pat on the back and, if it works out poorly, they get a pink slip. (Failing conventionally is the route to go; as a group, lemmings may have a rotten image, but no individual lemming has 2879 ever received bad press.) 2880 2881 john invested in an exclusive oil project since a group of sophisticated, wealthy investors were involved. They promised that he would quadruple his money in one year. A year later, he'd lost it all. 2882 2883 Former chairman of the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, Arthur Levitt, Jr. says, "If you are dumb enough to invest based on a lavatory wall, you deserve to lose money." 2884 2885 In the early 1900s, Italian immigrant Charles Ponzi, took investors for $10 million by promising 40% returns on International Postal Reply Coupons. What he didn't tell newer investors was that their money was 2886 being used to pay off earlier investors. In the end, the house of cards collapsed. 2887 2888 In the Foundation for New Era Philanthropy, some of the U.S.'s leading charities and donors believed they could double their money in six months. New Era used contributions from one group to pay off another - 2889 until there was no money left. New Era was a $350 million Ponzi Scheme. Charles Munger says, "Grown-up people actually believed that there was a tooth fairy out there that would double their money in six 2890 months provided they agreed to give it to charity." 2891 2892 Blindly following the lead of others can have dangerous consequences. 2893 2894 "Oh my God, he stabbed me. Please help me!" 2895 2896 We have a tendency to not act in situations where we are uncertain if there is danger and when we don't feel individual responsibility. Also when we want to avoid embarrassment and when we're among strangers. 2897 The more people, the more reduced we see our own responsibility. 2898 2899 Just after 3 a.m., March 13, 1964 in New York City, Catherine Genovese, a 28-year old woman, was stabbed to death as she returned from her job. 38 people witnessed at least one of her killer's three attacks 2900 from the safety of their apartment windows for 25 minutes without calling the police.. 2901 2902 Why didn't the neighbors help? Were they indifferent? Frightened? Why should they be afraid of calling the police from the safety of their own homes? A 2903 2904 85 2905 2906 pair of psychology professors found the answer. No one had helped [3mjust [0mbecause thirty-eight witnesses were present. A bystander to an emergency is unlikely to help when there are other people around. Why? 2907 They saw two reasons for this. 2908 2909 First, we must interpret an event as an emergency. When we are uncertain, we have a tendency to look at people around us to see how they react. If others don't react, we interpret that as evidence that it is 2910 not an emergency, and we therefore don't react. We don't want to be the ones that stand out in a crowd and risk embarrassment for acting in a non-emergency situation. But here comes the problem. If each 2911 person reasons the same way, everyone draws the same conclusion. "Since nobody is concerned, nothing is wrong. It can't bean emergency." This is called pluralistic ignorance. 2912 2913 The second reason is called diffusion of responsibility. The more people there are, the less personal responsibility we feel. We often rationalize by saying, "Someone else probably called the police. "If we 2914 all think that way, no one will help. The more people we see around us, the less likely we are to help. We can't force people to help. If we punish people for not helping in an emergency, we will only create 2915 an incentive for people to avoid the punishment by not getting involved. 2916 2917 This will cause them to interpret a situation as a non-emergency. 2918 2919 So, how should we act if we are involved in an accident in a public place and need help? We should be specific. "You there, in the blue shirt. This is an emergency. Please help me!" 2920 2921 The board members ofTransCorp were asked if they had any questions. They looked around at the other members. All appeared confident. '/1m I the only one confased?" wondered John and kept quiet. 2922 2923 "Since no one disagrees, my idea seems to have everyone's support,"the CEO said. 2924 2925 If we believe that we are the only one who doesn't understand, we may keep quiet. Speaking up may lead to embarrassment. Group pressure may contribute to our silence. 2926 2927 Sometimes mutual friendship and loyalty override our motivation to seek alternative courses of action. This type of group thinking has been found to be a factor in many historical events including the Bay of 2928 Pigs invasion, the Vietnam War and Pearl Harbor. 2929 2930 In the late economist Peter F. Drucker's The Effective Executive, the former 2931 2932 chairman of General Motors, Alfred P. Sloan, Jr., is reported to have said at the dosing of a management meeting: "Gentlemen, I take it we are all in complete agreement on the decision here". Everyone around 2933 the table nodded assent. "Then," continued Mr. Sloan, "I propose we postpone further discussion of this 2934 2935 86 2936 2937 matter to give ourselves time to develop disagreement and perhaps gain some understanding of what the decision is all about." 2938 2939 John attended a meeting where an investment proposal promising a 200% return was presented All 30 people present at the meeting invested and all lost money. 2940 2941 How could 30 smart individuals be fooled? Some basic math would have told them that the project was doomed to fail. Each individual automatically assumed that the other 29 individuals present at the meeting 2942 had evaluated the proposal. If there was something bad, someone else would have said so. "And since they invest, I invest." It turned out that no one had taken the time to read through the proposal. 2943 2944 "I flattered them and made them feel special. I gave them purpose and hope, and they ate out of my hand " 2945 2946 In a group we are easily seduced because of our need for social acceptance. The French social psychologist Gustave Le Bon said in The Crowd, "The masses have never thirsted after truth. They turn aside from 2947 evidence that is not to their taste, preferring to deify error, if error seduce them. Whoever can supply them with illusions is easily their master; whoever attempts to destroy their illusions is always their 2948 victim." 2949 2950 German-Swiss philosopher Friedrich Nietzsche said: "Madness is a rare thing in individuals - but in groups, parties, peoples, and ages it is the rule." In a group, we feel anonymous, which reduces our 2951 feelings of responsibility. We can't be blamed. This can lead to overconfident, risky behavior. We may also become impulsive and destructive. Especially in situations of severe stress. Benjamin Franklin said: 2952 "A mob has heads enough but no brains." 2953 2954 Imitation, obedience to authority, and the fear of being different are forces that drive crowds. Groups don't encourage differences of opinion. If a member of the group disagrees, he may be seen as disloyal. 2955 Unanimity is better than independent thought. Individuals in the group reinforce each other into believing that they collectively are right. They focus on favorable consequences and ignore the downside. 2956 2957 Is the tendency for imitating the group so strong it can make people commit collective suicide? 2958 2959 In 1978, 913 followers of the cult leader Jim Jones and his People's Temple organization died during a mass suicide and murder in a place called Jonestown in Guyana, South America. Among the dead: more than 2960 270 children. Why? 2961 2962 The People's Temple started in San Francisco and moved to Guyana in 1977. 2963 2964 87 2965 2966 Armed guards surrounded the settlement in Jonestown, food was scarce, and the members of the cult were forced to work long hours and follow strict codes of behavior. Cult leader Jim Jones committed his 2967 followers one step at a time. He controlled the information, the rewards, and the punishment. In 1978, an American congressman and three others went on a fact-finding mission to Jonestown and were murdered. 2968 Jim Jones thought that he would be implicated in the killings and that the isolation ofJonestown would result in the end of the cult. So he gathered the community to participate in an act of mass suicide by 2969 drinking a fruit drink mixed with poison. 2970 2971 Psychology Professor Robert Cialdini writes: 2972 2973 His Uones] masterstroke was the decision to move the People's Temple community from its roots in urban San Francisco to the remoteness of equatorial South America, where the conditions of uncertainty and 2974 exclusive similarity would make the principle of social proof operate for him as perhaps nowhere else. 2975 2976 Cialdini continues: "In a country like Guyana, there were no similar others for a Jonestown resident but the people of Jonestown itself." 2977 2978 Keep in mind 2979 2980 The 19th Century American poet Ralph Waldo Emerson said: "It is easy in the world to live after the world's opinion; it is easy in solitude to live after our own; but the great man is he who in the midst of 2981 the crowd keeps with perfect sweetness the independence of solitude." What is popular is not always right. If you don't like what other people are doing, don't do it. Warren Buffett says: "We derive no 2982 comfort because important people, vocal people, or great numbers of people agree with us. Nor do we derive comfort if they don't." 2983 2984 Disregard what others are doing and think for yourself. Ask: Does this make sense? Remember the advice from Benjamin Graham, the dean of financial analysis: 2985 2986 Have the courage of your knowledge and experience. If you have formed a conclusion from the facts and if you know your judgment is sound, act on it - even though others may hesitate or differ. (You are 2987 neither right nor wrong because the crowd disagrees with you. You are right because your data and reasoning are right.) 2988 2989 A lot of our children's personality traits and habits are shaped outside the home. Children learn from their friends what is acceptable or not so make sure 2990 2991 88 2992 2993 the right "peer group" surrounds them. 2994 2995 When part of a group, remember that the participants may have different goals, information, and interpretations. Seek out alternative points ofview and encourage people to openly disagree. Appoint someone in 2996 the group to question things and point out risks and pitfalls. Use ballots to reduce the risk of social pressure. 2997 2998 Make people responsible for their actions. Remember though, when all are accountable, no one is accountable. 2999 3000 AUTHORITY 3001 3002 In questions of science, the authority ofa thousand is not worth the humble reasoning of a single individual 3003 3004 Galileo Galilei (Italian astronomer and physicist, 1564-1642) 3005 3006 After the break-in at john's office, he said: "Of course, I believed he was a security guard, since he had a uniform. " 3007 3008 We tend to obey an authority, especially when we are uncertain, supervised, or when people around us are doing the same. We are most easily influenced by credible authorities, those we see as both 3009 knowledgeable and trustworthy. 3010 3011 '1 read it in the New England journal of Medicine, so it must be correct. " 3012 3013 Names and reputation influence us. And symbols of power or status like titles, possessions, rank, uniforms, or a nice suit and tie. For example, in one study 22 hospital nurses got a telephone call from an 3014 unknown physician and were ordered to administer an obvious overdose of an unauthorized drug. All but one nurse obeyed. 3015 3016 Another example is when advertisers use famous people to endorse their products. But being famous doesn't give people special expertise. 3017 3018 "The more I didn't understand, the more I believed the expert. " 3019 3020 Experts are sometimes more convincing when we don't understand them. Sometimes we are too impressed by something that sounds clever. For example, some people buy into investments just because they don't 3021 understand them. They assume it must be something unique. As Warren Buffett says, "Techniques shrouded in mystery clearly have value to the purveyor of investment advice. After all, what witch doctor has ever 3022 achieved fame and fortune by simply advising 'Take two aspirins'?" 3023 3024 89 3025 3026 '1 was only following orders. " 3027 3028 Blind obedience is sometimes a way to rationalize dumb actions. 3029 3030 '1 believed he was making a mistake, but Ididn't dare tell him. After all, heis the expert. " A study involving airline pilots cited conflict avoidance as a contributing factor to crashes. Officers are 3031 reluctant to disagree with the authority of pilots. For example, in a crash of a DC-8 in 1978, the flight engineer told the captain that they were running out of fuel. The captain dismissed the warning and 3032 the plane crashed. 3033 3034 In 1997, a female police officer in Scotland was assigned to a murder investigation. Forensic investigators later found her thumbprint in the house where the murder victim was found. But the woman insisted, 3035 under oath, she had never been inside the house. Four experts from the Scottish Criminal Record Office said that the print was hers. She was suspended and accused of perjury. Subsequent events showed that the 3036 fingerprint was neither hers nor from a thumb, but from a forefinger. Thus, experts make mistakes. 3037 3038 Authority is so powerful that we may cause pain to other people to comply. The British novelist and scientist Charles Percy Snow said in The Two Cultures and the Scientific Revolution: "When you think of the 3039 long and gloomy history of man, you will find more hideous crimes have been committed in the name of obedience than have ever been committed in the name of rebellion." 3040 3041 In one experiment at Yale University, Psychology Professor Stanley Milgram tricked people by posing as an authority and caused normal people to impose what they had every reason to believe was intense pain to 3042 other people. The participants in the experiment were instructed to shock another person if they answered a question wrong. No real pain was delivered during the experiment. But it showed that when we are 3043 given orders from what we believe to be a legitimate authority, we obey even if the result is that we end up hurting others. In later studies Milgram showed that obedience was maximized by first observing 3044 peers obey but dramatically reduced when peers rebelled, or when the victim acted like a masochist asking to be shocked. Milgram said in Obedience to Authority: "It is psychologically easy to ignore 3045 responsibility when one is only an immediate link in a chain of evil action." 3046 3047 Keep in mind 3048 3049 Evaluate the truth of a statement on the basis of its underlying facts, without regard to the authority's personal qualities or social status. 3050 3051 Anyone can call themselves an expert. Separate between real and false experts. 3052 3053 An authority may have an interest in persuading you to believe something that 3054 3055 90 3056 3057 is in their interest. Always consider reliability, credibility, sensibility and bias. To insure their trustworthiness, authorities often mention weaknesses before strengths and provide information that seems 3058 contrary to their interests. This technique is often used by salesmen and negotiators. 3059 3060 SENSEMAKING 3061 3062 "We understand life backwards but live it forwards. " 3063 3064 Soren Aabye Kierkegaard (Danish philosopher and theologian, 1813-1855) 3065 3066 "There has to be a reason!" 3067 3068 The 19th Century playwright and poet Oscar Wilde said: "The public have an insatiable curiosity to know everything, except what is worth knowing." 3069 3070 We don't like uncertainty. We have a need to understand and make sense of events. We refuse to accept the unknown. We don't like unpredictability and meaninglessness. We therefore seek explanations for why 3071 things happen. Especially if they are novel, puzzling or frightening. By finding patterns and causal relationships we get comfort and learn for the future 3072 3073 TransCorp hired a team of people to find out why the new product failed. 3074 3075 What did we do wrong in this case? There is a difference between: "Why did it happen?" and "What can cause this to happen?" The team looked for the specific factors that caused their new product to fail. They 3076 may learn more from asking: Why do new products fail? What general reasons are there? What key factors influence product failures? 3077 3078 "It is easy to be wise after the event, "says Sherlock Holmes in The Problem of Thor Bridge. We read the present into the past. After an event, we know how things turned out. When trying to make sense of what 3079 has happened, we construct a plausible story or explanation that fits the outcome. But there are many ways an event or behavior can later be understood. There may be many contributing factors that fit the 3080 outcome, chance may be involved, or our guessed causes may also be consistent with other outcomes, including the opposite or prevention of the outcome. Ask: Could our explanation of the event help us predict 3081 future similar events? 3082 3083 This is the danger of relying on case-based stories. Stories may be selected to prove something and may give us a delusional sense of clarity. Knowledge about outcomes may also cast some doubt on 3084 reconstructions of historical events (given that the historian was not there). History is often composed of various events all coming together. 3085 3086 91 3087 3088 History is also explained by what has survived into the historian's present. Not all sources survive. Not everything gets recorded, memories are unreliable, evidence may be destroyed or deliberately ignored, 3089 and some things may be too embarrassing to mention. When Oliver Cromwell's portrait was painted, he told the artist. "Remark all these roughnesses, pimples, warts, and everything as you see me, otherwise I 3090 will never pay a farthing for it." 3091 3092 We also seem to have a tendency for romanticizing past achievements. John Waller, Lecturer in the History of Medicine at the University of Melbourne, says on scientific discoveries in Einstein's Luck: "Many 3093 biographies seem to have been written to glorify idols, ancestors, disciplines, or even the nations in which the scientists lived and worked." 3094 3095 "Why was he so stupid? How could hehavedone that? It was obvious it would happen. " The 19th Century Russian writer Fyodor Dostoevsky said: "Everything seems stupid when it fails." In hindsight, everything 3096 seems obvious. But we should look at earlier decisions in the context of their own time. Perhaps the actions made sense at the time. We don't know what uncertainties, conditions, or situational factors faced 3097 the decision-maker. Good decision-making can lead to bad outcomes and vice versa. If we believe that we predicted the past better than we did, we may also believe that we can predict the future better than we 3098 can. The Romanian dramatist Eugene Ionesco said: "You can only predict things after they've happened." 3099 3100 "The oil price will stabilize at $60." 3101 3102 How do they know that? In the Cato journal Distinguished Professor Deirdre McCloskey said: "If you desire a ride to Baghdad, here is a magic carpet; if you desire your enemy dead, here is a magic doll; if you 3103 desire unlimited riches, here is a forecast of interest rates." We like it when people tell us what the future will look like. It reduces uncertainty. It doesn't matter that no once can predict the future, we 3104 willingly pay for the existence of future-tellers. 3105 3106 Charles Munger says: ''Around here I would say that if our predictions have been a little better than other people's, it's because we've tried to make fewer of them." 3107 3108 '1t couldn't have happened by chance. There must be a reason. " 3109 3110 We see faces in inkblots and patterns in the movements of stocks. We find meaning in coincidences. We underestimate the influence of chance. We want to find reasons for all kind of events - random or not. And 3111 if we don't find any, we construct them. We then choose the things that fit an intended pattern and 3112 3113 92 3114 3115 ignore the rest. Studies show that we even try to figure out a pattern when we are told a process is random. 3116 3117 In one experiment, two lights were set up and flashed in a random sequence. Before each trial, research subjects tried to guess which of the two lights would appear. The studies showed that they tried to 3118 match the frequency of previous occurrences in their guesses. Similar studies showed that rats or pigeons instead chose 3119 3120 the alternative that came up most frequently. If we assume that a red light occurs 3121 3122 with a frequency of 80% and a green light with a frequency of 20%, we should bet on the most likely outcome every time: red. We then guess right 80% of the time. Trying to match the frequency only gave the 3123 right answer 68% of the time. 3124 3125 An example of our tendency to see patterns that aren't there is when we use unreliable tests for evaluating people. A test is reliable if it gives about the same result when repeated assuming the test 3126 measures a characteristic that is stable over time. A test is valid if it accurately measures what it claims to measure. Take the Rorschach inkblot test as an example. One problem is that the test classifies 3127 a large percentage of normal individuals as psychologically disordered. Can we evaluate personality by studying how an individual perceives a series of inkblots? Interviewers can read into it whatever they 3128 wish to see. This test is still used today although research has shown that it allows for countless interpretations and has no predictive value. 3129 3130 "Once upon a time in the land of .. " 3131 3132 We are quick to draw conclusions. Author and entrepreneur Seth Godin tells a true story in his bookAllMarketersAre Liars. In the 1980s, some businessmen bought some branded stereo speakers and packed them 3133 into a truck. They parked the truck behind a dorm at Harvard and started whispering "Pssst... Hey! You wanna buy some speakers?" They never said that the speakers were stolen but passersby assumed they were. 3134 They therefore had to be a bargain. The businessmen sold out in no time. Even if the speakers cost a little more than they did in the local store. 3135 3136 We love stories and story-telling. Good stories and drama get our attention. They give meaning to events. We rationalize decisions and justify choices by telling ourselves comforting stories. We use stories 3137 to understand, remember and make sense of events. But sometimes we have a hard time separating a true story from a false one. After an event a story is created so that the event makes sense. Remember that a 3138 story can have many possible beginnings (and endings). 3139 3140 Keep in mind 3141 3142 Look for alternative explanations and what normally happens. Think about general reasons. 3143 3144 93 3145 3146 Consider how other possible outcomes might have happened. Don't underestimate chance. 3147 3148 In hindsight, everything seems obvious. If we look forward, there are many 3149 3150 possible outcomes. 3151 3152 REASON-RESPECTING 3153 3154 "Please would you tell me," said Alice, a little timidly, "why your cat grins like that?" "It's a Cheshire Cat,"said the Duchess, "and that's why. " 3155 3156 Lewis Carroll (British mathematician and writer, 1832-1898, from Through the Looking Glass) 3157 3158 Our need for making sense makes us even believe in nonsense. 3159 3160 In one experiment a social psychologist asked people standing in line to use a copying machine if she could go in front of them, "Excuse me, I have 5 pages. May I use the Xerox machine because I have to make 3161 some copies?"Nearly all agreed. 3162 3163 When people ask us for a favor we are more likely to comply if they give us a reason - even if we don't understand the reason or it is wrong. Often it isn't the reason itself that is important, but the way 3164 the reason is phrased. Sometimes the word "because," without a sensible reason, is all that matters. We want explanations and the word "because" imply an explanation. 3165 3166 Carl Braun, the creator of CF Braun Engineering Company, understood the importance of telling people "why." Charles Munger tells us the story: 3167 3168 His rule for all the Braun Company's communications was called the five W's - you had to tell who was going to do what, where, when and why. And if you wrote a letter or directive in the Braun Company telling 3169 somebody to do something, and you didn't tell him why, you could get fired. In fact, you would get fired if you did it twice. 3170 3171 You might ask why that is so important? Well, again that's a rule of psychology. Just as you think better if you array knowledge on a bunch of models that are basically answers to the question, why, why, why, 3172 if you always tell people why, they'll understand it better, they'll consider it more important, and they'll be more likely to comply. Even if they don't understand your reason, they'll be more likely to 3173 comply. 3174 3175 So there's an iron rule that just as you want to start getting worldly wisdom by asking why, why, why in communicating with other people about everything, you want to include why, why, why. 3176 3177 "Why should we do this? Why should we do it this way?" ''Because this is how we always have done it. " 3178 3179 94 3180 3181 We should not only give people reasons for what to do but should also encourage flexibility. Ask them to question procedures and whether what appear to be self evident truths are really good for the business. 3182 Ask why, ask why, and ask why again. The third why often gets down to the real issue. 3183 3184 "How can I use what I don't understand?" 3185 3186 Understanding reasons is an important factor in learning. To learn, remember, organize, and use ideas, we must understand the "why" and "how." There's no use memorizing what we don't understand. If we don't 3187 understand the meaning of an idea, we don't use it. What we don't use, we forget. We also need to be motivated to learn. And we can't be motivated if we don't understand why we need to learn something. We 3188 need to see its practical use. 3189 3190 Understanding is about the ability of seeing patterns - how ideas and things relate and hang together. Knowledge that can be used in a variety of situations. 3191 3192 Our brains favor the concrete and practical over the abstract and theoretical. We are especially good at remembering images and spatial information. We therefore learn better if the use of ideas and patterns 3193 are illustrated through pictures and simple, clear and vivid real-life stories. Stories on what works and what doesn't work increase our ability to retain what we've learned. 3194 3195 Aristotle said: "For the things we have to learn before we can do them, we learn by doing them." This means we need to practice what we have learnt in various situations. 3196 3197 We also need an organizing framework in order to better retrieve and use knowledge. Charles Munger adds: "You can't really know anything if you just remember isolated facts and try and bang 'em back. If the 3198 facts don't hang together on a latticework of theory, you don't have them in a usable form." 3199 3200 Keep in mind 3201 3202 People can't be persuaded by what they don't understand. We underestimate the importance of giving people a reason. It is often easier to get people to change with a well-explained reason backed by solid 3203 evidence. Tell them so they understand why a specific action is needed, what the expected objective is, and why you think the action is right. 3204 3205 Of course, this doesn't work in every case. Sometimes you don't change people's opinions by showering them with logic. In Jonathan Swift's words: "You cannot reason a person out of a position he did not 3206 reason himself into in the first place." Aristotle adds: "For argument based on knowledge implies instruction, and there are people whom one cannot instruct." Sometimes it is 3207 3208 95 3209 3210 better to appeal to emotions than to reason since people are more moved by what they feel than by what they understand. 3211 3212 BELIEVE FIRST AND DOUBT LATER 3213 3214 "Our new product is very good for you for the following reasons. .. " 3215 3216 We start assuming that the product is good for us and look for evidence that confirms it. We believe people when they give us reasons. We believe that people are telling us the truth, even when they are not. 3217 3218 We are not natural skeptics. We find it easy to believe, but difficult to doubt. Doubting is active and takes effort. Bertrand Russell said: "Believing seems the most mental thing we do." Why? Because we have 3219 to believe in order to understand. 3220 3221 Studies show that in order to understand some information we must first accept it as true. The 17th Century philosopher Benedictus de Spinoza argued that understanding and believing are simply two different 3222 words for the same mental process. We first believe all information we understand and only afterwards and with effort do we evaluate, and if necessary, un-believe it. Studies show that Spinoza was right. We 3223 automatically and effortlessly believe what we see and hear and only afterwards (sometimes) with effort do we doubt and ask questions. Psychology Professor Daniel Gilbert says in his study How Mentals Systems 3224 Believe: "Having comprehended and accepted an idea, Spinoza considered persons entirely free either to unaccept or to certify it." 3225 3226 Studies also show that the more distracted or pressured we are (and therefore prevented from thinking things through), the more likely we believe in something we normally would find dubious. Whether we think 3227 things through or not depends on our motivation and ability. 3228 3229 Believing something that is false may sometimes come with a benefit. For example, studies show that if students are told they are above average on a subject, they will do better. 3230 3231 How successful are people at deceiving us? 3232 3233 Can we catch a liar? We don't seem to be good at telling a truth from a lie. Studies show that people - even professionals - are slightly better than chance at distinguishing truths from lies. We seem to be 3234 better at judging when people are telling the truth than when they are telling a lie. Michel de Montaigne said: "If falsehood, like truth, had only one face, we would be in better shape. For we would take as 3235 certain the opposite of what the liar said. But the reverse of truth has a hundred thousand shapes and a limitless field." 3236 3237 96 3238 3239 Keep in mind 3240 3241 When dealing with important issues think things through and avoid distraction. 3242 3243 MEMORY LIMITATIONS 3244 3245 Everyone complains of his memory, and no one complains of his judgment. 3246 3247 Francois Due de la Rochefoucauld 3248 3249 Our memory is selective. We remember certain things and distort or forget others. Every time we recall an event, we reconstruct our memories. We only remember fragments of our real past experiences. Fragments 3250 influenced by what we have learned, our experiences, beliefs, mood, expectations, stress, and biases. Certain experiences create strong feelings and are therefore more memorable than others. Dramatic or 3251 fearful experiences or events stick in our memories. Emotional events are better remembered than unemotional ones. That is why we learn better if information is tied to a vivid story. Learning is also tied to 3252 mood. 3253 3254 We learn better in a positive mood. That is why teaching should be performed in a way that creates powerful positive emotions among students. 3255 3256 Psychology Professor Daniel Schacter, proposes in The Seven Sins of Memory 3257 3258 that our memory's malfunctions can be divided into seven "sins." 3259 3260 (1) Our memory weakens and we lose memory over time. (2) We are preoccupied with distracting issues and don't focus attention on what we need to remember. (3) We search for information that we may be 3261 desperately trying to retrieve - something we know that we know - but are blocked. (4) We assign memory to the wrong source. (5) Memories are implanted as a result of leading questions, comments, or 3262 suggestions when we try to call up a past experience. (6) Our present knowledge influences how we remember our pasts. We often edit or entirely rewrite our previous experiences. (7) We recall disturbing 3263 events that we would prefer to eliminate from our minds altogether: remembering what we cannot forget, even though we wish that we could. 3264 3265 Individuals remember the same things differently. We remember events that never happened or assign what happened to the wrong place, time or person. Studies show that memories of emotional experiences are 3266 often different from what actually happened. We misinterpret what we saw. That is why there are variations in eyewitness accounts. Many cases show that eyewitness identification evidence has been a 3267 significant cause of wrongful convictions. Especially the accuracy of eyewitness identification of strangers. 3268 3269 97 3270 3271 "/ [3mnever forget a face. [0m" 3272 3273 Australian psychologist Donald Thomson appeared on a live TV debate about the unreliability of eyewitness testimony. He was later picked up by the police, placed in a lineup, and identified by a victim as the 3274 man who had raped her. But Thomson has an airtight alibi. The rape had occurred while he was on TY. It later turned out that the rapist had attacked the woman as she was watching the very show on which 3275 Thomson had appeared. 3276 3277 Studies show that we remember a face but wrongly remember the time and place we saw it. Leading and suggestive questions can cause misidentification, and influence by information obtained after the event. 3278 Studies show that it is easy get a witness to believe they saw something when they didn't. Merely let some time pass between their observation and the questioning. Then give them false or emotional 3279 information about the event. Psychology Professor Elisabeth Loftus' work has shown that people can be led to remember rather familiar and common experiences, even when they had not happened. For example, her 3280 studies show that people can believe that a childhood experience had happened when it never happened. 3281 3282 Studies show that jurors believe witnesses even when they are later shown to have made an incorrect identification. Eyewitnesses can be highly inaccurate but appear confident. The more confident people are 3283 when they appear as witnesses, the more believable the jurors will find them. The more detailed their memory of a situation is, the more the jurors trust them. Testimonial evidence is vivid and therefore more 3284 believable. 3285 3286 Is a child witness always to be trusted in a courtroom? 3287 3288 Can a psychologist who interviews a troubled child falsely implant the idea that a bad event happened to them? 3289 3290 Childhood memories are unreliable and influenced by fantasies and suggestions. Experiments have shown how normal children behave in response to suggestions. Implanted false stories can have a huge impact. 3291 Children can actually believe an event that never happened or produce false narratives for the event. Over time, their stories may become elaborate and filled with vivid details, making them more believable. 3292 3293 Keep in mind 3294 3295 Keep records of important events. 3296 3297 98 3298 3299 Do-SOMETHING SYNDROME 3300 3301 I have often said that the sole cause of man's unhappiness is that he does not know how to sit quietly in his room. 3302 3303 Blaise Pascal 3304 3305 When John asked why the company continued making acquisitions when so many of them turned sour, the CEO replied: "All my colleagues do deals like this. Plus how can I keep my job and all my perks if I don't 3306 keep busy?" 3307 3308 Blaise Pascal said: "Man finds nothing so intolerable as to be in a state of complete rest, without passions, without occupation, without diversion, without effort." We sometimes act because we can't sit 3309 still. We feel bored, impatient, threatened or pressured or we simply desire excitement and stimulation. We act without a sensible reason. It seems easier to explain doing something than actively doing 3310 nothing. 3311 3312 Warren Buffett tells why CEOs like acquisitions: 3313 3314 The sad fact is that most major acquisitions display an egregious imbalance: They are a bonanza for the shareholders of the acquiree; they increase the income and status of the acquirer's management; and they 3315 are a honey pot for the investment bankers and other professionals on both sides... often the CEO asks a strategic planning staff, consultants or investment bankers whether an acquisition or two might make 3316 sense. That's like asking your interior decorator whether you need a $50,000 rug. 3317 3318 The acquisition problem is often compounded by a biological bias: Many CEO's attain their positions in part because they possess an abundance of animal spirits and ego. If an executive is heavily endowed with 3319 these qualities - which, it should be acknowledged, sometimes have their advantages - they won't disappear when he reaches the top. When such a CEO is encouraged by his advisors to make deals, he responds 3320 much as would a teenage boy who is encouraged by his father to have a normal sex life. It's not a push he needs. 3321 3322 Warren Buffett also provides an example from the insurance world on why it is more important to do what is right than to simply do something: 3323 3324 We hear a great many insurance managers talk about being willing to reduce volume in order to underwrite profitably, but we find that very few actually do so. Phil Liesche [manager National Indemnity 3325 Company's insurance operation] is an exception: if business makes sense, he writes it; if it doesn't, he rejects it. It is our policy not to lay off people because of the large fluctuations in work load 3326 produced by such voluntary volume changes. We would rather have some slack in the organization from time to 3327 3328 99 3329 3330 time than keep everyone terribly busy writing business on which we are going to lose money. 3331 3332 Continuous reorganization may be dangerous. The Roman satirist Petronius Arbiter said in the 1st Century: "We trained hard, but it seemed that every time we were beginning to form into teams we would be 3333 reorganized. I was to learn later in life that we tend to meet any new situation by reorganizing, and what a wonderful method it can be for creating the illusion of progress while producing confusion, 3334 inefficiency, and demoralization." 3335 3336 Keep in mind 3337 3338 The 19th Century American writer Henry David Thoreau said: "It is not enough to be busy; so are the ants. The question is: What are we busy about?" Don't confuse activity with results. There is no reason to 3339 do a good job with something you shouldn't do in the first place. 3340 3341 Charles Munger says, "We've got great flexibility and a certain discipline in terms of not doing some foolish thing just to be active - discipline in avoiding just doing any damn thing just because you can't 3342 stand inactivity." 3343 3344 What do you want to accomplish? As Warren Buffett says, "There's no use running if you're on the wrong road." 3345 3346 SAY-SOMETHING SYNDROME 3347 3348 Wise men talk because they have something to say; fools, because they have to say something. 3349 3350 Plato 3351 3352 '1 am a big shot; people expect me to comment on all kind of things." 3353 3354 People tend to speak even if they have nothing to contribute. Mark Twain wrote: 3355 3356 "If you have nothing to say, say nothing." 3357 3358 Why do we always need to give an answer? Isn't it better to say, "I don't know?" Greek philosopher Socrates said that awareness of ignorance is the beginning of wisdom. 3359 3360 Keep in mind 3361 3362 Wisdom is a two-headed beast. Roman dramatist Publilius Syrus wrote in 1st Century BC: "I have often regretted my speech, never my silence." 3363 3364 Benjamin Franklin said: "He that would live in peace and at ease, must not speak all he knows, nor judge all he sees." 3365 3366 100 3367 3368 25. EMOTIONS 3369 3370 The heart has its reasons of which reason itself knows nothing. 3371 3372 - Blaise Pascal 3373 3374 '1 got married in the heat of passion. Sorry dad,"John's daughter said 3375 3376 Francis Bacon said: "The guilt of Senses is of two sorts, either it destitutes us, or else deceives us." Emotions come before reason. Often when we make a decision our feelings take over. We hear bad news 3377 first. Under the influence of intense emotions we sometimes make hasty judgments and choices we would normally never do. For example, we buy things we can't afford, we have unprotected sex, we overeat, and 3378 use drugs. Studies also show that when we are in a state of more rational calm, we underestimate how we will feel and act when we experience intense emotions. 3379 3380 '1 had a really bad day today,"said Mary, "So Tm going shopping now. " 3381 3382 One study tried to find out how disgust and sadness influenced economic decisions. All participants in the study watched a movie immediately before conducting financial transactions. Some watched a sad movie. 3383 Others a disgusting movie and a third group an emotionally neutral movie. Participants insisted that their feelings didn't affect what they were willing to pay for something or what price they were willing to 3384 accept. The study showed otherwise. Disgust reduced their selling and buying prices. Sadness cut their selling prices but raised their buying prices. 3385 3386 We saw under loss aversion and deprival that we put a higher value on things we already own than on the same things if we don't own them. Sadness reverses this effect, making us willing to accept less money 3387 to sell something that we would pay for the same thing. 3388 3389 This means, that when we feel sad, which often reflects helplessness and loss, we may want to change our circumstances so we feel better. This may cause us to overpay for something or buy things we don't 3390 need. That is why Mary went on a shopping spree. She needed some retail therapy. When we feel disgust we may be reluctant to buy anything new unless we find it is a real bargain. When we feel sadness or 3391 disgust we may want to get rid of things we have and sell them for less than what they are worth. 3392 3393 '1t doesn't matter how large the problem is. It doesn't feel good " 3394 3395 Risk is a feeling. We automatically judge how good or bad a stimulus is based on how we feel about it. When something produces strong emotions, we overweigh 3396 3397 101 3398 3399 its consequences and underweigh its chance of happening. We associate gains with great feelings. For example, studies show that our feelings toward winning the lottery are the same whether the chance of 3400 winning is one in 10 million or one in 10,000. 3401 3402 John is buying a new sports car. He is all excited. But how will he feel one year from now? 3403 3404 We expect that if good or bad things happen to us in the future, they will make us feel better or worse much longer and more intensively than they actually turn out to be. So John's new car will probably be 3405 less exciting than John expects. Neither will it excite John as long as he expected. Why? Because we tend to adapt to most good and bad things and circumstances and make them ordinary (adaptation is not 3406 inevitable - individual differences and conditions matter and some major life events produce long lasting or enduring changes in life satisfaction). Our feelings are also influenced by so many other things 3407 and people than the specific future event itself. Furthermore, the comparisons we make when we think about our future feelings are often not the comparisons we make when we experience the event. 3408 3409 What about if we instead use our past good experiences to decide what we want? Can we trust our memories to guide us? Memories can be deceptive. We also underestimate how our tastes and preferences will 3410 change. The Roman poet Titus Lucretius Cams said: "As long as we do not have it, the object of our desire seems greater than anything else; as soon as we enjoy it, we long for something different with an 3411 equal craving." 3412 3413 What could we do instead? When we make big decisions, we could compare our expected feelings with those of people who have similar experiences today. In that sense, we are not as unique as we think we are. 3414 3415 Keep in mind 3416 3417 • Understand your emotions and their influence on your behavior. Ask: Is there a rational reason behind my action? 3418 3419 • Remember the proverb: ''A wise man controls his temper. He knows that anger causes mistakes." 3420 3421 • When we have just gone through an emotional experience, we should hold off on important decisions. 3422 3423 • The benefits of cooling-off periods force us to think things through. 3424 3425 102 3426 3427 26.STRESS 3428 3429 You can't change the cards life has dealt you, but you can determine the way you'll play them. 3430 3431 - Ty Boyd (American motivational speaker) 3432 3433 Too much information, lack of predictability or control, too many choices, lack of sleep, social isolation, job status, crisis, catastrophes, fear, etc. cause stress. The less control we perceive we have over 3434 our lives, the easier we fall victim to stress. The more stress we experience, the more we tend to make decisions that are short term. 3435 3436 Everything our brain interprets as a threat influences our biology. Our ancestors didn't suffer less stress than we did. But their stress was different. They met dangers that demanded fast physical reactions. 3437 Our stress is more social and psychological in nature. 3438 3439 The fear of losing both her job and social position caused Mary to suffer constant headaches. 3440 3441 Stress affects concentration and memory. Long-term stress exposure upsets the brain's chemical balance. Stress may cause high blood pressure, heart disease, diabetes, back and stomach problems, headache, and 3442 depression. Studies show that when we feel stress the concentration of cortisol rises in the bloodstream. One effect of cortisol is to suppress the workings of our immune system. This makes us more vulnerable 3443 to diseases. Stress also counteracts the production of insulin (the hormone that processes blood sugar), causing the process of repair to slow down. Studies show that emotional stress creates longer recovery 3444 times in our bodies and may be more harmful to our health than non-emotional stress events like physical exercise. 3445 3446 What happens when people are exposed to physical and mental exhaustion, confasion, physical pain, emotional tension or fear? 3447 3448 Stress increases our suggestibility. Ivan Pavlov showed that animal behavior could be established or erased by exposing the animal to stress. For example, he could make a dog react aggressively to a caretaker 3449 with whom the dog was once very loyal. The same can happen to people. All people have a certain level of tolerance to stress. Once it is passed, people begin to break down and what they earlier believed and 3450 liked are easily changed. This can happen to prisoners of war. It has also been used to make religious and political conversions, and by police forces to elicit confessions. 3451 3452 103 3453 3454 '1 have lost control over the situation. " 3455 3456 The more we believe we are in control, the less vulnerable we are to the negative effects of stress. Studies show that people who perceive themselves to be in control over a stressful situation experience 3457 less stress on their hearts and circulatory system. 3458 3459 The status of our job matters. The Whitehall II study involving 17,000 civil servants showed that people with low perceived control over the work environment or people low in the organizational structure have 3460 an increased risk of cardiovascular disease. Our cortisol levels rise in response to the degree other people order us about. As we climb the social hierarchy health status improves. In Genome, science writer 3461 Dr. Matt Ridley comments on the Whitehall study: "Somebody in a low-grade job, such as a janitor, was nearly four times as likely to have a heart attack as a permanent secretary at the top of the heap." 3462 3463 In another study researchers tried to find out the differences between business executives who became sick from exposure to high stress and those who didn't. They found that executives who stayed healthy had 3464 a sense of commitment to work and families, felt in control, and had a positive attitude toward challenges. They saw challenges as part oflife and an opportunity for growth rather than as a threat. 3465 3466 Warren Buffett says, "I have no stress whatsoever - zero. I get to do what I love to do every day. I'm surrounded by people that are terrific." He continues, ''All the businesses I run don't take 5% of my 3467 time. We don't have regular staff meetings and the like. If you've got good businesses and the right managers, you don't need that sort of thing- and if you don't, they don't help." 3468 3469 Keep in mind 3470 3471 • Stress is neither good nor bad in itself. It depends on the situation and our interpretation. Stress can be controlled by our attitudes. The Austrian physician Dr. Hans Selye says in Stress without Distress 3472 that it is not stress that harms us but distress. We need challenges. He continues, "Without stress, there would no life... Complete freedom from stress is death." 3473 3474 • The 1st Century philosopher Epictetus said: "Happiness and freedom begin with a clear understanding of one principle: Some things are within our control, and some things are not. It is only after you have 3475 faced up to this fundamental rule and learned to distinguish between what you can and can't control that inner tranquility and outer effectiveness become possible." 3476 3477 If a problem can be solved, there is no need to worry. The thing to do is to correct it. If a situation can't be solved, we shouldn't worry about that either. We can't do anything about it. Mark Twain says: 3478 "I've suffered a great many 3479 3480 104 3481 3482 catastrophes in my life. Most of them never happened." Sometimes keeping ourselves busy with something else may cause us to stop worrying. 3483 3484 PAIN, CHEMICALS AND DISEASES 3485 3486 Pain upsets and destroys the nature of the person who feels it. 3487 3488 -Aristotle 3489 3490 '1can't think clearly because I am drunk. I don't care about the consequences if I act violent." 3491 3492 We become confused when we are in pain, under the influence of chemicals or have a physical or mental illness. Physical and mental pain may cause fear, anger and stress. Chemical changes magnify the pain and 3493 can cause depression. 3494 3495 Drugs, stimulants (like nicotine, alcohol or coffee), and depressants distort our senses. 3496 3497 MULTIPLE TENDENCIES 3498 3499 When you get two or three of these psychological principles operating together, then you really get irrationality on a tremendous scale. 3500 3501 - Charles Munger 3502 3503 Charles Munger gives an illuminating example on the issue of stealing: 3504 3505 A very significant fraction of the people in the world will steal if (A) it's very easy to do and, (B) there's practically no chance of being caught. And once they start stealing, the consistency principle 3506 will soon combine with operant conditioning to make stealing habitual. So if you run a business where it's easy to steal because of your methods, you're working a great moral injury on the people who work for 3507 you... 3508 3509 It's very, very important to create human systems that are hard to cheat. Otherwise you're ruining your civilization because these big incentives will create incentive-caused bias and people will rationalize 3510 that bad behavior is OK. 3511 3512 Then, if somebody else does it, now you've got at least two psychological principles: incentive-caused bias plus social proof. Not only that, but you get Serpico effects: If enough people are profiting in a 3513 general social climate of doing wrong, then they'll turn on you and become dangerous enemies if you try and blow the whistle. 3514 3515 Frank Serpico became known after exposing corruption at the New York Police Department in the 1970s. When Frank Serpico entered the New York Police force in 1960, payoffs and kickbacks were rampant in the 3516 department. 3517 3518 105 3519 3520 When he refused to take money, his fellow officers saw him as a potential danger. Then he blew the whistle on them, and became their enemy. In a 1971 testimony before the Knapp commission, Serpico said: "I 3521 hope that police officers in the future will not experience the same frustration and anxiety that I was subjected to for the past five years at the hands of my superiors because of my attempt to report 3522 corruption ... We create an atmosphere in which the honest officer fears the dishonest officer, and not the other way around." 3523 3524 john's acquisition experience caused him stress and cost TransCorp money. 3525 3526 John said, "I was dissatisfied having done so little for TransCorp last year. All of the other guys made acquisitions. If I could find a good acquisition, maybe I could move up the ranks. I needed a 3527 promotion. 3528 3529 I found a good-looking business, and saw the possibility of making TransCorp a lot of money. The CEO of the business was a nice guy and we always met in their relaxing conference room. The asking price was 3530 low in relation to past profits. I had experts telling me what a great company it was. I was presented entertaining information on new products. The investment banker did me a favor by bringing the deal and I 3531 wanted to reciprocate. 3532 3533 The banker told me that other people I admire would jump at the opportunity. I made a commitment to the financiers and told TransCorp's CEO about the deal. I committed myself publicly and felt a need to 3534 follow-through. I concentrated my search on evidence that confirmed the greatness of the deal. I denied reality and thought nothing bad could happen. I didn't say what I thought for fear of social 3535 disapproval. The CEO of the company I wanted to acquire continuously gave me good reasons to pursue the deal. The more effort I put into the deal, the more I felt I had to do it. I finally signed the papers. 3536 When reality kicked in and the deal turned sour, I was in deep trouble. And so was TransCorp." 3537 3538 '1 don't want to go against the CEO and risk losing my $250,000 directors fee." 3539 3540 Is the board of directors an effective corrector to deal with CEO mediocrity? Charles Munger says: "The psychological nature of the board of directors system makes it an ideal system for causing people to 3541 follow the lead of the CEO." 3542 3543 A board may be a legal creation, but it is a social animal. Warren Buffett says: 3544 3545 When people meet every couple of months and come from different parts of the country 3546 3547 - and they have the normal social instincts - they don't like to have rump meetings or sort of talk behind people's backs. So it's very difficult in a group - particularly if it's a group 3548 3549 106 3550 3551 like Charlie described where the directors' fees for a significant number of them are important to their well-being, and they'd love to be recommended for another board and add another $100,000 a year to 3552 their income- for someone to lead a charge all of a sudden at a regular meeting or to try to arrange a rump meeting of some sort to say, "We think the guy at the head of the table is no good." 3553 3554 So dealing with mediocrity- or, like I say, a notch above it - is a difficult problem if you're a board member. .. 3555 3556 I've been on 19 boards. And I've never seen a director on any of the 19, where the director's fees were important to them, object to an acquisition proposal or a CEO's compensation. 3557 3558 The CEO of TransCorp tells his board: "This is the decision, now let's start the discussion. " 3559 3560 Apart from incentive-caused bias, liking and social approval, what are some other tendencies chat operate here? Authority - the CEO is the authority figure who directors tend to trust and obey. He may also 3561 make it difficult for those who question him. Social proof - the CEO is doing dumb things but no one else is objecting so all directors collectively stay quiet - silence equals consent; illusions of the group 3562 as invulnerable and group pressure (loyalty) may also contribute. Reciprocation - unwelcoming information is withheld since the CEO is raising the directors fees, giving them perks, caking them on trips or 3563 letting chem use the corporate jet. Association and Persian Messenger Syndrome - a single director doesn't want to be the carrier of bad news. Self-serving tendencies and optimism 3564 3565 feelings of confidence and optimism: many boards also select new directors who 3566 3567 are much like themselves; chat share similar ideological viewpoints. Deprival - Directors don't want to lose income and status. Respecting reasons no matter how illogical - the CEO gives them reasons. 3568 Believing first and doubting later - believing what the CEO says even if not true, especially when distracted. Consistency- directors want to be consistent with earlier decisions - dumb or not. 3569 3570 Can we get rid of a bad CEO? Warren Buffett and Charles Munger says: 3571 3572 Buffett: When certain boards consisting of prominent people are embarrassed publicly by the media attention, I think that acts as kind of an early warning signal to some other boards because big shots - and 3573 they look for big shots frequently in terms of dressing up boards - do not like to look foolish, at least publicly... 3574 3575 Munger: ...in terms of the director's actually rebelling against the CEO, it tends to happen in one or two cases: One is when they reduce the directors' perks - which most CEOs are wise enough not to do. The 3576 ocher is when the situation gets so bad chat it threatens to 3577 3578 107 3579 3580 disgrace the directors. But you rarely see people taking action before they're threatened with disgrace. 3581 3582 Warren Buffett says that we need true independence from directors i.e. a: "willingness to challenge a forceful CEO when something is wrong or foolish." He continues: "In addition to being independent, 3583 directors should have business-savvy, a shareholder orientation and a genuine interest in the company." 3584 3585 Charles Munger adds: 3586 3587 The correct system is the Elihu Root System. Elihu Root, who had three different cabinet appointments, ifI remember right, said no man was fit to hold public office who wasn't perfectly willing to leave it at 3588 any time. And if Elihu Root didn't approve of something the government asked him to do, he could always go back and be the most sought-after lawyer in the world. He had an identity to go back to - so he 3589 didn't need the government's salary. 3590 3591 Well, I think that also ought to be more the test in corporate directorships. Is a director really fit to make tough calls who isn't perfectly willing to leave the office at any time? My answer 1s no. 3592 3593 CONTEXTUAL INFLUENCES 3594 3595 Most social acts have to be understood in their setting, and lose meaning if isolated. 3596 3597 No error in thinking about social facts is more serious than the failure to see their place and function. 3598 3599 - Solomon Asch (American social psychologist, 1907-1996) 3600 3601 Our behavior is influenced by social situational factors, conditions and circumstances, the structure or description of a problem or choice, and our desires, mood and expectations. 3602 3603 We tend to overestimate personal characteristics and motives when we explain the behavior of others. We underestimate situational factors like social pressure, roles or things over which there are no control. 3604 An example is, blaming an individual rather than a poorly designed system for failure. Chance also matters. Maybe we sometimes give too much blame to people who had bad luck, and too much credit to those who 3605 were simply lucky. 3606 3607 We expect people to be consistent in their behavior. But we behave differently in different situations. For example, we behave differently at home, in school, at work, and among friends; when alone and when 3608 in a group; when seen and when anonymous. 3609 3610 108 3611 3612 "I shouldn't have been so fast judging him as a bad person. Who knows, I may have done the same if put in the same situation." 3613 3614 Extreme circumstance and conditions can cause people to do things they would never do under normal circumstances. Put good people in a bad situation and their normal behavior changes. The Zimbardo prison 3615 experiment at Stanford studied the roles people play in prison situations. Students were randomly assigned to the roles of prisoners and guards for a two-week period. Tests showed that all students were 3616 normal people and physically and mentally healthy. A simulated prison environment was created to mimic real-life prison conditions, where they lived for several days. Students playing guards behaved 3617 aggressively and students playing prisoners behaved helplessly. Guards rapidly began to treat the prisoners as if they were non-humans. The prisoners began acting depressed and showed extreme stress. The more 3618 the prisoners acted like non-humans, the more the guards mistreated them. The experiment ended after six days. 3619 3620 In a statement prepared for the U.S. House of Representatives Committee on the Judiciary, the originator of the experiment, Philip Zimbardo, said: "We were horrified because we saw some boys treat other boys 3621 as if they were despicable animals, taking pleasure in cruelty, while other boys became servile, dehumanized robots who thought only of escape, of their own individual survival, and of their mounting hatred 3622 of the guards." 3623 3624 Often when we are in a role, we tend to act as others expect. Zimbardo said: "Even when they thought they didn't have to meet anyone's expectations, the role of prison guard determined their actions." 3625 3626 An American Indian proverb says: "Don't judge a man until you've walked two moons in his moccasins." How would we behave if we were anonymous, part of a group, tired and exhausted, and others had been labeled 3627 as enemies, evil or worthless? 3628 3629 "Why is John tense when people watch his golf swing?" 3630 3631 Are our actions observed or not? People may change their behavior merely because they are being observed. 3632 3633 "No one can see me. " 3634 3635 Anonymity can create destructive behavior. Studies show that peaceful students can become aggressive when they are made to feel anonymous by having their identity masked. 3636 3637 109 3638 3639 The less knowledgeable we are about an issue, the more influenced we are by how it is framed. 3640 3641 The answers we get depend on the questions we ask. The British philosopher 3642 3643 Herbert Spencer said: "How often misused words generate misleading thoughts." Consider how a statement, problem, consequence, or question is presented. How is it worded? What is its context? Are we 3644 considering certain features and ignoring others? Emotional, selective and appealing frames influence us. 3645 3646 How a choice is presented influences our preferences. For example, we prefer a product that is presented as "95% fat free" rather than "5% fat". We respond differently depending on whether something is 3647 presented in terms of gains or in terms oflosses. A surgical procedure that has a 40% chance of success seems more appealing than one that has a 60% chance of failure. 3648 3649 Frequencies appeal to our emotions. What is the chance that a mental patient commits an act of violence within 6 months after discharge? Studies show that experienced psychologists and psychiatrists judge the 3650 patient as more dangerous when the risk of violence were presented as relative frequencies (e.g., 20 criminals out of 100 similar to the patient are estimated to be violent to others...) than when the risk 3651 was presented as a probability (e.g., it is estimated that similar patients has a 20% chance of being violent to others ...). One study showed that a disease that kills 1,286 of 10,000 people (12.86%) was 3652 rated as riskier than one that kills 24.14 of 100 people (24.14%). 3653 3654 We are influenced by the order, first or last, in which a presentation happens. The key variable is the amount of time that separates the presentations, the time when we have to make a judgment, and which 3655 presentation is the most easily remembered. 3656 3657 Assume that two presidential candidates are speaking on an issue, one directly after the other. If some time passes before we have to make a judgment, we are likely to be more influenced by the first 3658 presentation. Assume now that some time passes between the first and last presentations, but we have to make a judgment immediately after the last presentation. Then we are more likely to be influenced by the 3659 last presentation. 3660 3661 '1 put my paycheck in the bank at 4% interest, and borrowed money for a car loan at 10% interest. " 3662 3663 We create our own frames by doing mental accounting. We treat assets of the same value differently depending on where they come from or their importance. We put different values on the same dollar, and are 3664 more willing to risk money we have won than money we have earned. A gain of $1,000 from playing roulette 3665 3666 110 3667 3668 has less value than $1,000 earned from hard work. '1 didn't gamble with my 3669 3670 $1,000, I only gambled with the $1,000 I won on the casino." But it is the same amount of money. 3671 3672 In one experiment psychologists found that people who lost a $10 theater ticket on the way to the theatre were reluctant to buy a second ticket. Those who instead lost a $10 bill on the way to buy a $10 3673 theatre ticket saw the loss of the money and the purchase of the ticket as unrelated, so they would buy the ticket. But, in both cases, the loss was the same. 3674 3675 We should view our assets in terms of their entirety. A dollar is a dollar independent of where it comes from. What counts is what we put in or take out of our pocket. 3676 3677 There is a difference in behavior whether we deal with someone we know and a stranger or under the eye of an experimenter. 3678 3679 "[ expect you to understand what Tm saying. I know you can do this. " 3680 3681 "Things are not always what they seem," said the 1st Century Roman philosopher Phaedrus. Our behavior can be influenced by the expectations of others- teachers, coaches, bosses, etc. For example, to please 3682 the observer, a research subject may read in a desired result. A patient may wish to respond to a treatment in what they see as the correct way. We live up to what is expected of us. 3683 3684 Studies show that patients can have faster heartbeats and higher blood pressure when examined by a doctor compared to a nurse. 3685 3686 We often see what we want or expect to see. A doctor may see an effect in a patient because he expects to see it. We often don't see what we don't expect to see. 3687 3688 Do we treat people according to our expectations? 3689 3690 Assume Mary is on her way to meet someone for the first time. Does it matter if this person has been described as friendly or emotionally cold? Yes, it produces a change in Mary's expectations of that 3691 individual and a change in her behavior. Mary will expect friendliness or hostility and behave according to her expectations. The person may react to Mary in a way that confirms her expectations. We treat 3692 people like we expect them to be. If we expect people to be bad, we treat them in a certain way, which may cause them to behave badly. 3693 3694 Assume that a new teacher is told that half of the class has high IQs and half has low IQs. The teacher is given the names of the supposed intelligent kids and the supposed not so intelligent ones. In 3695 reality, someone has randomly selected the two groups. By the end of the year, the experimental premise will become a 3696 3697 111 3698 3699 self-fulfilling prophecy. The kids the teacher thought had high IQs will be doing better than the kids with supposedly low IQs. This has been demonstrated in studies of elementary school students. Teachers 3700 taught much better when they expected a lot from their students. 3701 3702 Irrational behavior in one context may cause good results in another. 3703 3704 We aren't stupid - judgments are often a function of context. The judgments of others can be informative, obedience to an authority is important for order, being careful in getting involved in a dangerous 3705 situation may save our life. 3706 3707 What about all the evidence from lab experiments? 3708 3709 Lab experiments can't resemble reality. 3710 3711 There is a difference between real life and the controlled and somewhat artificial context of the lab. What is happening in some lab experiments may not happen in a natural situation. For example, many 3712 experiments are often played anonymously without repetition. What is the structure of the problem? The environment? Assumptions? Importance? Cost of being wrong? Often there exists more than one right answer. 3713 The context of the task matters. In a more realistic, concrete, and social context, many tasks are often solved correctly. 3714 3715 Studies show that we are overconfident. Does this mean we are always overconfident? No, the studies only show that some people are overconfident in some tasks in a certain context. 3716 3717 SOME FINAL ADVICE FROM CHARLES MUNGER 3718 3719 Follow these three pieces of advice from Charles Munger: 3720 3721 I don't want you to think we have any way oflearning or behaving so you won't make a lot of mistakes. I'm just saying that you can learn to make fewer mistakes than other people - and how to fix your mistakes 3722 fosterwhen you do make them. But there's no way that you can live an adequate life without [making] many mistakes. In fact, one trick in life is to get so you can handle mistakes. Failure to handle 3723 psychological denial is a common way for people to go broke: You've made an enormous commitment to something. You've poured effort and money in. And the more you put in, the more that the whole consistency 3724 principle makes you think, "Now it has to work. If I put in just a little more, then it'll work." 3725 3726 And deprival super-reaction syndrome also comes in: You're going to lose the whole thing if you don't put in a little more. People go broke that way - because they can't stop, rethink and say, "I can afford 3727 to write this one off and live to fight 3728 3729 112 3730 3731 again. I don't have to pursue this thing as an obsession - in a way that will break me." Part of what you must learn is how to handle mistakes and new facts that change the odds. Life, in part, is like a 3732 poker game, wherein you have to learn to quit sometimes when holding a much-loved hand. 3733 3734 I've gotten so that I now use a kind of two-track analysis. First, what are the factors that really govern the interests involved, rationally considered? And second, what are the subconscious influences where 3735 the brain at a subconscious level is automatically doing these things - which by and large are useful, but which often misfunction. One approach is rationality - the way you'd work out a bridge problem: by 3736 evaluating the real interests, the real probabilities and so forth. And the other is to evaluate the psychological factors that cause subconscious conclusions - many of which are wrong. 3737 3738 Take all the main models from psychology and use them as a checklist in reviewing outcomes in complex systems. No pilot takes off without going through his checklist: A, B, C, D ... And no bridge player who 3739 needs two extra tricks plays a hand without going down his checklist and figuring out how to do it... And, to repeat for emphasis, you have to pay special attention to combinatorial effects that create 3740 lollapalooza consequences. 3741 3742 Don't our feelings, instincts or our intuition help us avoid misjudgments? 3743 3744 Natural selection equipped us with traits adapted for the environment in which humans spent most of their time. Feelings like love, compassion, anger, fear, jealousy, and embarrassment can be explained 3745 biologically. They exist for a reason 3746 3747 to help us survive and reproduce. Somerset Maugham said: "Love is only a dirty trick played on us to achieve a continuation of the species." Why does sex feel good? Because it makes us reproduce. If sex felt 3748 painful, we wouldn't be here today. Our emotions are also part of the human whole. Our "good" emotions wouldn't be good without our "bad" emotions. 3749 3750 Feelings and instincts helped our ancestors navigate in the world. The ancestral environment rewarded actions before thought, emotion before reason. Fast intuitions and quick reactions are vital responses for 3751 organisms. Spending time pondering may be dangerous. 3752 3753 The problem is that feelings can be twisted. Intuition is inconsistent and feelings can sometimes get out of control. Especially when we feel uncertain, distracted or stressed. 3754 3755 Remember Chinese philosopher Lao-Tsu (604-531 BC): "He who knows men is clever; He who knows himself has insight; He who conquers men has force; He who conquers himself is truly strong." 3756 3757 113 3758 3759 In Part Three we will study other reasons why we make misjudgments. These are partly rooted in our psychological make-up; our tendency to use crude rules of thumb, and make hasty judgments and other 3760 psychological tendencies discussed in Part Two. They also have their roots in a lack of considering some basic ideas from physics and mathematics. 3761 3762 Charles Munger gives us some introductory remarks on the value of knowing the methods of physics: 3763 3764 One of the things that influenced me greatly was studying physics.. .IfIwere running the world, people who are qualified to do physics would not be allowed to elect out of taking it. I think that even people 3765 who aren't [expecting to] go near physics and engineering [in their planned profession] learn a thinking system in physics that is not learned so well anywhere else. Physics was a total eye-opener. 3766 3767 The tradition of always looking for the answer in the most fundamental way available 3768 3769 - that is a great tradition and it saves a lot of time in this world. And, of course, the problems are hard enough that you have to learn to have what some people call assiduity. Well, I've always liked that 3770 word - because to me it means that you sit down on your ass until you've done it. 3771 3772 114 3773 3774 - PART THREE - 3775 3776 [1mTHE PHYSICS AND MATHEMATICS OF MISJUDGMENTS [0m 3777 3778 There will come a time when mathematical ignorance, like public smoking, will become socially unacceptable. 3779 3780 - Jerry King (Professor of Mathematics, from The Art of Mathematics) 3781 3782 115 3783 3784 This part illustrates reasons for misjudgments and mistakes that can be reduced by considering some basic principles from physics and mathematics. The big ideas are explained using examples from business, 3785 investing, law, medicine, etc. As in Part Two, we begin with a list of the causes of misjudgments and mistakes. Each item on the list will be explained over the next chapters. 3786 3787 Systems thinking 3788 3789 Failing to consider that actions have both intended and unintended consequences. Includes failing to consider secondary and higher order consequences and inevitable implications. 3790 3791 Failing to consider the whole system in which actions and reactions take place, the important factors that make up the system, their relationships and effects of changes on system outcome. 3792 3793 Failing to consider the likely reactions of others - what is best to do may depend on what others do. 3794 3795 Failing to consider the implications of winning a bid - overestimating value and paying too much. 3796 3797 Overestimating predictive ability or usmg unknowable factors m making predictions. 3798 3799 Scale and limits 3800 3801 Failing to consider that changes in size or time influence form, function and behavior. 3802 3803 Failing to consider breakpoints, critical thresholds or limits 3804 3805 Failing to consider constraints - that a system's performance is constrained by its weakest link. 3806 3807 Causes 3808 3809 Not understanding what causes desired results. 3810 3811 Believing cause resembles its effect - that a big effect must have a big or complicated cause. 3812 3813 Underestimating the influence of randomness in bad or good outcomes. 3814 3815 Mistaking an effect for its cause. Includes failing to consider that many effects may originate from one common root cause. 3816 3817 Attributing outcome to a single cause when there are multiple causes. 3818 3819 Mistaking correlation for cause. 3820 3821 Failing to consider that an outcome may be consistent with alternative explanations. 3822 3823 117 3824 3825 Drawing conclusions about causes from selective data. Includes identifying the wrong cause because it seems the obvious one based on a single observed effect. Also failing to consider information or evidence 3826 that is missing. 3827 3828 Not comparing the difference in conditions, behavior and factors between negative and positive outcomes in similar situations when explaining an outcome. 3829 3830 Numbers and their meaning 3831 3832 Looking at isolated numbers -failing to consider relationships and magnitudes. Includes not using basic math to count and quantify. Also not differentiating between relative and absolute risk. 3833 3834 Underestimating the effect of exponential growth. 3835 3836 Underestimating the time value of money. 3837 3838 Probabilities and number of possible outcomes 3839 3840 Underestimating risk exposure in situations where relative frequency (or comparable data) and/or magnitude of consequences is unknown or changing over time. 3841 3842 Underestimating the number of possible outcomes for unwanted events. Includes underestimating the probability and severity of rare or extreme events. 3843 3844 Overestimating the chance of rare but widely publicized and highly emotional events and underestimating the chance of common but less publicized events. 3845 3846 Failing to consider both probabilities and consequences (expected value). 3847 3848 Believing events where chance plays a role are self-correcting - that previous outcomes of independent events have predictive value in determining future outcomes. 3849 3850 Believing one can control the outcome of events where chance is involved. 3851 3852 Judging financial decisions by evaluating gains and losses instead of final state of wealth and personal value. 3853 3854 Failing to consider the consequences of being wrong. 3855 3856 Scenarios 3857 3858 Overestimating the probability of scenarios where all of a series of steps must be achieved for a wanted outcome. Also underestimating opportunities for failure and what normally happens in similar 3859 situations. 3860 3861 Underestimating the probability of systems failure - scenarios composed of many parts where system failure can happen one way or another. Includes 3862 3863 118 3864 3865 failing to consider that time horizon changes probabilities. Also assuming independence when it is not present and/or assuming events are equally likely when they are not. 3866 3867 Not adding a factor of safety for known and unknown risks. Size of factor depends on the consequences of failure, how well the risks are understood, systems characteristics and degree of control. 3868 3869 Coincidences and miracles 3870 3871 Underestimating that surprises and improbable events happen, somewhere, sometime, to someone, if they have enough opportunities (large enough size or time) to happen. 3872 3873 Looking for meaning, searching for causes and making up patterns for chance events, especially events that have emotional implications. 3874 3875 Failing to consider cases involving the absence of a cause or effect. 3876 3877 Reliability of case evidence 3878 3879 Overweighing individual case evidence and under-weighing the prior probability (probability estimate of an event before considering new evidence that might change it) considering for example, the base rate 3880 (relative frequency of an attribute or event in a representative comparison group), or evidence from many similar cases. Includes failing to consider the probability of a random match, and the probability of 3881 a false positive and false negative. Also failing to consider a relevant comparison population that bears the characteristic we are seeking. 3882 3883 Misrepresentative evidence 3884 3885 Failing to consider changes in factors, context or conditions when using past evidence to predict likely future outcomes. Includes not searching for explanations to why past outcome happened, what is required 3886 to make past record continue, and what forces can change it. 3887 3888 Overestimatingevidence from a single case or small or unrepresentativesamples. 3889 3890 Underestimating the influence of chance in performance (success and failure). 3891 3892 Only seeing positive outcomes - paying little or no attention to negative outcomes and prior probabilities. 3893 3894 Failing to consider variability of outcomes and their frequency. 3895 3896 Failing to consider regression - in any series of events where chance is involved unique outcomes tends to regress back to the average outcome. 3897 3898 119 3899 3900 - ONE - 3901 3902 SYSTEMS THINKING 3903 3904 Wanted and unwanted consequences 3905 3906 In one of Aesop's fables the following story is told: 3907 3908 A poor widow living alone in the country kept a faithful hen. Each morning the hen laid a big, brown egg for the woman's breakfast. One day the widow thought to herself: "Now ifI were to double my hen's 3909 allowance of barley, she would lay me two eggs a day instead of one." So she started feeding her biddy a double measure of grain, and soon the hen began to grow fat and sleek and lazy. It wasn't long before 3910 she stopped laying altogether. 3911 3912 Every action has consequences. Both intended and unintended. No matter how carefully we plan, we can't anticipate everything. Often we fail to consider what other events are likely to occur as a result of 3913 some action. Politics, medicine, welfare programs, technology, military actions and laws generate unintended consequences. Whatever we do (or don't do), there are multiple consequences. They might not be what 3914 we expect. In one study, traffic engineers found that adding new routes (like a more direct road) could make traffic go slower. During merging, cars drive closer to each other and therefore slow down. 3915 Furthermore, studies of car safety show that wearing seat belt makes drivers feel more secure, making them drive faster or more recklessly. 3916 3917 By solving one problem, we generate another one and sometimes create an even worse one. 3918 3919 There was a problem with mice on campus. The solution for exterminating the mice was to pay students $1 for every dead mouse they delivered. It worked! Until the students began breeding the mice in order to 3920 make more money. 3921 3922 Actions have consequences and consequences have further effects. Charles Munger gives an example regarding Medicare: 3923 3924 They had all these actuarial studies that showed the cost would be X. And the cost turned out to be more than 1OX... They didn't factor in the fact that effects have effects... they didn't think through the 3925 incentive effects of the way they were changing the rules. They 3926 3927 120 3928 3929 created a system wherein they were reimbursing both doctors and hospitals, in effect, on a cost plus percentage of cost basis. The minute they did that, the hospitals and doctors found wonderful ways to talk 3930 the patients into buying all kinds of care that got reimbursed ... good for the hospital and good for the doctor, but bad for the patient and bad for the taxpayers. 3931 3932 Should good intentions eliminate bad consequences? No. Outcomes don't follow from intentions and intentions by definition apply only to intended consequences. But as Samuel Johnson said, "The road to hell is 3933 paved with good intentions." Isn't it more important to find out if the consequences are good rather than if the reasons are good? Ask: What are we trying to improve? What can reasonably be expected to 3934 happen? Are the net effects positive or negative? 3935 3936 Good thinking is better than good intentions. In the 18th Century, Pierre S. du Pont, a deputy to the French National Assembly said: "Bad logicians have committed more involuntary crimes than bad men have 3937 done intentionally." 3938 3939 But even good thinking can have undesired consequences. Charles Munger gives an example: 3940 3941 An excess of what seems like professionalism will often wind up hurting you horribly precisely because those careful procedures themselves often lead to overconfidence in their outcome... Long Term Capital 3942 Management, the well-known hedge fund recently collapsed as a result of its principals' overconfidence in their highly leveraged methods. And it collapsed despite those principals having IQ's that must have 3943 averaged 160 or more...Smart, hard-working people aren't exempt from professional disasters resulting from overconfidence. Often they just go aground in the more difficult voyages on which they choose to 3944 embark based on self appraisals in which they conclude that they have superior talents and methods. It is, of course, irritating that extra care in thinking isn't all good- that it also introduces extra 3945 error. But most good things have undesired "side effects." And thinking is no exception. 3946 3947 One way to reduce unintended consequences is to stop focusing on isolated factors and instead consider how our actions affect the whole system. 3948 3949 The whole system 3950 3951 Sales volume dropped and John suggested· "Why don't we reduce price? It's a sure-fire way to win back customers and boost sales. We make up on volume what we lose on price and as a result we increase our 3952 market share. Profits will surely rise. " 3953 3954 "Where did we go wrong? We lost market share. Profits and stock price declined. " 3955 3956 121 3957 3958 Why didn't TransCorp's profit increase? They forgot to think about all the factors that influenced the outcome. They didn't anticipate the consequences of cutting prices. They didn't consider other factors 3959 and conditions that influenced the value of the business. Some were changed as a consequence of TransCorp's decision to reduce prices in anticipation of higher volumes. Volume increases affect costs and 3960 behavior and need for investments in operating assets. There may also have been production problems due to technical constraints or the price decrease wasn't enough to make customers switch from the 3961 competition. 3962 3963 How a system behaves is a function of all the factors (human and non-human) that make up and influence the system. 3964 3965 A system is a collection of parts working together as a whole. Take a business as an example. It is a collection of parts but works as a complete system. There are variables like suppliers, employees, 3966 customers, demand, competition, etc. There are activities like purchasing, manufacturing, warehousing, logistics, and distribution. There are technological systems and equipment needed to conduct the 3967 business. All these parts work together. 3968 3969 TransCorp fired 200 people to cut costs. 3970 3971 We optimize one component at a time instead of optimizing the whole (what we finally want to accomplish). TransCorp forgot to consider how a change influences the whole system. Cost cutting doesn't 3972 automatically translate into higher value. TransCorp's decision to foe people caused manufacturing and delivery problems, which in turn caused delays in customer production. This created a loss of customers 3973 and reputation. The end result was lower profits. 3974 3975 Why reduce prices? What is the purpose? What does TransCorp ultimately want to achieve? 3976 3977 Systems adjust in response to feedback. A positive feedback amplifies an effect, while a negative dampens it. Take the stock market as an example of a positive feedback. The stock market falls causing a 3978 sell-off. This creates a ripple effect of further sell-off and price declines. The opposite occurs in a stock market bubble. A thermostat is an example of negative feedback. 3979 3980 Try to optimize the whole and not asystem's individual parts. Think through what other variables may change when we alter a factor in a system. Trace out the short and long-term consequences in numbers and 3981 effects of a proposed action to see if the net result agrees with our ultimate goal. 3982 3983 Ask: What key factors influence the outcome of the system and how do these factors interact? What other things may change as a consequence of some action? Given these conditions, what likely consequences 3984 (wanted and unwanted) will the 3985 3986 122 3987 3988 proposed action have on the system, considering all the relevant factors that influence or are part of the system? Will the net result be what we want? A manager can for example ask: How is the value of the 3989 business likely to change considering important factors that influence business value? 3990 3991 Considering the whole includes anticipating the reactions of others. 3992 3993 The reaction of others 3994 3995 Game theory is a study of conflict between thoughtful and potential deceitful opponents. 3996 3997 William Poundstone (from Prisoner's Dilemma) 3998 3999 TransCorp cut the price and lost volume. 4000 4001 What happened? TransCorp's competitors matched the price cut. Competitors can match price cuts or even go below it to regain, keep or increase market share. When thinking through consequences, consider what 4002 other people are likely to do. Since our interests may conflict with others, the final outcome of our decision often depends on what others will do. What other people do may 4003 4004 depend on what they think we will do, their available choices, interests, and how they are thinking- including their misjudgments. As we have learned, humans don't always act rationally. 4005 4006 Game theory deals with what happens when individuals or groups of people interact with one another to achieve their goals. We saw an example of game theory in Part One (Prisoner's Dilemma). It also applies to 4007 negotiations. Factors that decide the final outcome of a negotiation are: 1) the number of participants, 2) if we meet the participants again in the future, 3) the time lapse in between, 4) the degree of 4008 anonymity and communication, and 5) our relative position of strength which includes our other options, back-up alternatives and need to reach an agreement. 4009 4010 The winner's curse 4011 4012 I sent the club a wire stating, "Please accept my resignation. 4013 4014 I don't care to belong to any club that will have me as a member. " 4015 4016 Groucho Marx 4017 4018 Several mining firms including MineCorp, one of TransCorps subsidiaries, are bidding on the right to mine silver. 4019 4020 No firm knows for certain how much silver there is and hence what the true value is.They each hire an expert to make an educated guess. By definition, these expert guesses will range from too low to too high. 4021 Some firm's expert will probably be 4022 4023 123 4024 4025 dose. But they won't win. The winning firm was MineCorp since their expert had the most optimistic estimate of the value (the seller accepts the highest bid). But there was less silver in the mine than their 4026 expert guessed and less value than what MineCorp paid for the rights. This means that the winning bidder was cursed since the bid was higher than the value. Later it was shown that MineCorp also 4027 underestimated its costs of production. 4028 4029 Three Atlantic Richfield engineers, Capen, Clapp and Campbell, introduced the idea behind the Winner's Curse when they did a study of companies bidding for oil fields. Their basic idea was Uournal of 4030 Petroleum Technology, June 1971), that "a lease winner tends to be the bidder who most overestimates reserve potential." 4031 4032 Let's say TransCorp has 10 projects from 10 divisions to choose from. They only have time and money to invest in one project. Which one are they most likely to pick? Of course, the one that looks most 4033 attractive. But all division managers have an incentive to make their own project the most attractive one. The risk is therefore that TransCorp chooses the project with the most optimistic forecast and 4034 therefore more likely to disappoint. 4035 4036 "Hurray, I won the auction!,"said John. "What you 'won' was the right to pay more for something than everyone else thought it was worth,"said Mary. 4037 4038 Winning is an informative event, telling us whose estimate was most optimistic. When we place a bid on a house, company, project, or negotiate to buy something, we don't realize what is implied by an 4039 acceptance of our offer. That we may have overestimated its value and therefore paid too much. 4040 4041 Research shows that the more bidders there are competing for a limited object, each having the same information, and the more uncertain its value is, the more likely we are to overpay. Instead, if our 4042 objective is to create value, the more bidders there are, the more conservative our bidding should be. This also implies that the less information we have compared to other bidders or the more uncertain we 4043 are about the underlying value, the lower we should bid. If we participate in auctions, we must ascertain the true value of what's being sold or its value to us. 4044 4045 When we negotiate with one party and want an acceptance for an offer, the other party may have an informational advantage. The other party is most likely to accept our offer when it is least favorable to us, 4046 especially if it is a one-time relationship or if the other party is anonymous. 4047 4048 Consider the seller's perspective. Ask: Why are they selling? How would I reason ifl think it through from the viewpoint of the other person? Why would I make a better decision than someone who has all the 4049 information? 4050 4051 124 4052 4053 Predictions 4054 4055 Do not, therefore, expect any prophecy from me: had I known what one will discover tomorrow, I would have published it long ago, to secure priority. 4056 4057 - Henri Poincare (French mathematician and scientist, 1854-1912) 4058 4059 When asked about corporate responsibility for social problems, Charles Munger answered: 4060 4061 I'm all for fixing social problems. I'm all for being generous to the less fortunate. And I'm all for doing things where, based on a slight preponderance of the evidence, you [3mguess [0mthat it's likely to do more 4062 good than harm... 4063 4064 What I'm [3magainst [0mis being very confident and feeling that you know, for sure, that your particular intervention will do more good than harm given that you're dealing with highly complex systems wherein 4065 everything is interacting with everything [3melse. [0mGreek philosopher Heraclitus wrote: "Nothing endures but change." The world is too complicated to predict all the effects of some action. Maybe a business can 4066 predict scenarios like reduction in demand and intensified competition, but some events, their timing, magnitude or consequence, are impossible to anticipate. 4067 4068 Mark Twain said: "The art of prophecy is very difficult, especially with respect to the future." It is hard to predict something when we don't (or can't) foresee or understand how an entire system works, what 4069 key variables are involved, their attributes, how they influence one another and their impact. Even if we know the key variables, their values may be impossible to estimate. They may also change over time and 4070 be dependent on context. It may also be impossible to estimate how they will interact as a whole. 4071 4072 The more parts involved and the more they interact, the more can happen, and the harder it is to determine consequences of individual actions. 4073 4074 According to Dr. Gerald Edelman, the brain is an example of a complex system: 4075 4076 A complex system is one in which smaller parts form a heterogeneous set of components which are more or less independent. But as these parts connect with each other in larger and larger aggregates, their 4077 functions tend to become integrated, yielding new functions that depend on such high order integration. This is, in fact, just what happens in the brain. 4078 4079 As the number of variables grows, the number of possible interactions grows even faster. Assume that two subsystems, A and B, cause the behavior of a system. 4080 4081 125 4082 4083 Each subsystem consists of 5 parts. If we only consider two-way interactions among parts, there are 10 interactions between A-parts, 10 between B-parts, and 25 interactions between A and B parts. This means 4084 that the behavior of the system is composed of 55 determinants (SA-parts + 5B-parts + 10 interactions between A parts + 10 interactions between B-parts + 25 interactions between A and B parts). 18% (10 of 55) 4085 of all determinants derive from individual effects of parts in A and B while about 82% (45 of 55) derive from interactions. Now imagine a system where A and B each consists of 100 parts. There are now 20,100 4086 determinants (100+100+4,950+4,950+10,000) and 19,900 interactions meaning that 99% (19,900 of20,100) of system determinants derive from interactions. 4087 4088 We often take too little notice of how variables interact. Take the economy as an example. There are many factors to consider. They include interest rates, currency exchange rates, balance of trade figures, 4089 unemployment rates, consumer confidence, political factors, the stock market, business cycles, biases, etc. These factors are interconnected, and it is hard to tell which is most important. Add to this that 4090 people's behavior isn't fixed. We are emotional creatures, our preferences change, and we react to each other's actual or expected decisions. A prediction may also make us change our expectations and 4091 behavior, making the prediction more or less likely to come true. 4092 4093 Charles Munger says: "We try and predict what individual investments will swim well in relation to the tide. And then we tend to accept the effects of the tide as those effects fall." 4094 4095 "Ifsomeone could forecast the stock market, why are they selling advice through $100 newsletters?" 4096 4097 Fidelity's former manager Peter Lynch said in One Up on Wall Street: "There are 60,000 economists in the U.S., many of them employed full-time trying to forecast recessions and interest rates, and if they 4098 could do it successfully twice in a row, they'd all be millionaires by now... As far as I know, most of them are still gainfully employed, which ought to tell us something." 4099 4100 Predictions about the future are often just projections of past curves and present trends. This is natural since our predictions about the future are made in the present. We therefore assume the future will 4101 be much like the present. But the future can't be known until it arrives. It is contingent on events we can't see. For example, who in the year 1900, could foresee events like World War I and II, the 1929 4102 stock market crash, Chernobyl or technologies like the television, laser, computer, internet or the DVD? Many key inventions happened by accident and sagacity. For example, in 1867 Alfred Nobel accidentally 4103 discovered that when 4104 4105 126 4106 4107 nitroglycerin dripped on kieselguhr (a mineral made of small, fossilized remains of sea animals), it formed a stable paste that was safer to use than liquid nitroglycerin alone. He called it dynamite. 4108 4109 Don't believe people that say they can forecast unforeseeable variables. Nobody can forecast interest or currency rates, the GDP, turning points in the economy, the stock market, etc. Massive amounts of 4110 information, advanced computers or fancy mathematical formulas don't help. Warren Buffett says that we tend to put too much comfort in computer models and the precision they project: "We believe the precision 4111 they project is a chimera. In fact, such models can lull decision-makers into a false sense of security and thereby increase their chances of making a really huge mistake." 4112 4113 Economics isn't like physics. There are no reliable or precise formulas where we easily can fill in the values of various economic factors, and then have the work done. Charles Munger says: "Economics 4114 involves too complex a system... economics should emulate physics' basic ethos, but its search for precision in physics-like formulas is almost always wrong in economics." J.M. Keynes adds: "To convert a 4115 model into a quantitative formula is to destroy its usefulness as an instrument of thought." 4116 4117 Financial writer Roger Lowenstein writes in When Genius Failed: "The next time a Merton [Robert Merton, 1997 Nobel Laureate for developing mathematical risk management formulas] proposes an elegant model to 4118 manage risks and foretell odds, the next time a computer with a perfect memory of the past is said to quantify risks in the future, investors should run - and quickly- the other way." 4119 4120 That an event has happened many times before, doesn't mean that it will continue to happen. And just because an event has never happened before, doesn't mean it can't happen in the future. Take catastrophic 4121 events as an example. Who could have predicted the September 11, 2001 terrorist attack on the World Trade Center? Hijacking four planes simultaneously and using them to attack the 4122 4123 U.S. was improbable. Yet it happened. 4124 4125 Modern History Professor Richard Evans wrote in In Defence of History: "Time and again, history has proved a very bad predictor of future events. This is because history never repeats itself; nothing in human 4126 society... ever happens twice under exactly the same conditions or in exactly the same way." 4127 4128 Sometimes we can guess that certain things are bound to happen, but we can't predict when they will happen. 4129 4130 Will it rain two weeks from now? 4131 4132 Some things are possible to predict short-term but impossible to predict long- 4133 4134 127 4135 4136 term. Small changes make a big difference over time. Long-term weather forecasts are an example. Many factors determine the weather. Factors that can't be reliably measured ahead of time. Small changes in the 4137 temperature and pressure over the ocean can lead to large variations in the future development of storm systems. Weather predictions become more inexact the further out they are. 4138 4139 The difficulty lies in initial condition uncertainties and model error. For example, small errors in the initial values ofvariables can grow and produce errors in the forecast. There may also be gaps in the 4140 initial data. But even if we know the initial conditions perfectly, the models are not perfect. Small model errors either in physics or numerics can also grow and produce different states. For example, not 4141 all atmospheric processes are understood. Furthermore, all weather models operate on a finite grid or limited area, typically in the order of 10 to 100 kilometers, depending on the study area. This means that 4142 the numerical resolution and representation is finite. But many physical processes and features that influence the weather occur on smaller scales than those resolved by the grid. For example, energy 4143 transfers at the surface, small atmospheric processes (such as isolated thunderstorms), topography, lakes, and vegetation. The model must treat or "parameterize" the effects of these "sub-grid" features' 4144 effects on the resolved scale. These parameterizations are simplifications and approximations and may also account for many of the model errors. So even if we know all the principles behind the weather and 4145 what governs the atmosphere, fundamental limitations make it hard to make accurate predictions. 4146 4147 Many meteorologists know they can't make a perfect forecast and have 4148 4149 therefore given up on predicting whether it will or will not rain beyond a few days into the future. Instead, they have altered their approach and try to quantify the uncertainty in the prediction ("The 4150 probability of precipitation is 20% this Saturday''). This uncertainty is small at short lead times and greater at longer lead times. It also varies with the weather situation, the location and the size of 4151 the area the prediction covers. When meteorologists make forecasts two weeks out, they look at the climatological frequency of precipitation, determined from a history of what has happened in the past. 4152 4153 All prediction is inherently uncertain, and we have a duty to tell people about the uncertainties of our predictions and our past error rates. Albert Einstein wrote in a March 14, 1954, letter: "The right to 4154 search for truth... implies also a duty; one must not conceal any part of what one has recognized to be true." 4155 4156 128 4157 4158 - Two - 4159 4160 SCALE AND LIMITS 4161 4162 Scale of size and time 4163 4164 Changes in size or time influences form, function and behavior. If something of a certain size is made bigger or smaller, it may not work the same way. Some things get better and others get worse. For 4165 example, changes in the size of an organism affect its strength, surface area, complexity, metabolism, longevity, and speed of movement. 4166 4167 How do weight, strength and surface area change when we change size? 4168 4169 If we double the length of a similarly shaped object, surface area increases 4 times and volume 8 times. Surface area increases at the square of length and volume at the cube oflength (to get areas we 4170 multiply two lengths together, and to get volumes we multiply three lengths). 4171 4172 Volume always grows faster than surface area as we increase size, independent of an object's shape. This places limitations on the size of things. 4173 4174 Does it make any difference in melting time if we use one ice cube (volume 8) or 8 smaller ones (total volume 8}? 4175 4176 If we increase size, volume grows faster than surface area. What does this mean? The relationship between surface area and volume decreases when we increase the size. It also means that the relationship 4177 increases when we decrease the size. Take ice cubes as an example. Let's assume the larger one has a side length of 2 and the smaller ones a side length of 1. 4178 4179 Small ice cube 4180 4181 Large ice cube 4182 4183 Side length 4184 4185 1 4186 4187 2 4188 4189 Cross-section surface area (side length) 2 4190 4191 1 4192 4193 4 4194 4195 Total surface area (6 sides) 4196 4197 6 4198 4199 24 4200 4201 Volume (side length) 1 4202 4203 1 4204 4205 8 (weight) 4206 4207 Ratio of total surface area to volume 4208 4209 6 4210 4211 3 4212 4213 As we can see, the large ice cube has less surface area per unit volume than 8 small ice cubes. Total surface area is the total area of all 6 surfaces of the ice cube. 4214 4215 129 4216 4217 This means that 8 ice cubes have a surface area of 48 (8 x 6) versus 24 for the larger ice cube. This also means that 8 small ice cubes melt faster than one large ice cube, since the amount of heat an ice 4218 cube can absorb depend on its surface area (the melting process occurs at the surface). Whenever we make objects smaller, we get more surface area per unit volume. For example, since iron rusts when exposed 4219 to air and rusting occur at the surface, a steel knife rusts more slowly than steel wool. 4220 4221 Why did the dinosaurs have such small heads in relation to their bodies? 4222 4223 Living things are shaped and constrained by basic mathematical principles. Weight depends on volume and strength or load-bearing ability on area. The strength of a muscle or a bone is a function of 4224 cross-section area. Strength does not increase at the same rate as weight and volume. When we increase size, weight increases faster than strength. Scale up an organism and sooner or later it will be too weak 4225 to support its own weight. Double the size of a small dinosaur - twice as long, wide and high - and it weighs 8 times as much as before. We now need a neck that is 8 times stronger than before since it must 4226 hold 8 times the weight. But since the strength of the neck is proportional to its cross-section area, the neck is only 4 times stronger. There comes a point where the neck breaks. 4227 4228 What about the giants we see in the movies? 4229 4230 Assume we make a human 10 times larger than normal. This means he is now 10 times longer, 10 times wider, and 10 times higher. He now weighs 1,000 times more but he is only 100 times stronger (as muscular 4231 strength is proportional to the cross section area of a muscle). Since the load-bearing capacity of bones scales in the same manner his bones would be subject to ten times more stress than normal. He needs 4232 thicker bones to support more weight. Otherwise his legs will crush. This is why elephants have such thick stumpy legs to support their weight. The giant has 1,000 times more meat on the body but only 100 4233 times the skin to hold it together meaning ten times the pressure on its skin (since pressure is proportional to area). This also means that his skin surface area is too small to remove the heat emitted from 4234 his huge body. He would suffer from overheating since the amount of heat his body produces is proportional to the cube of his length (1,000), while the amount of heat he dissipates through the skin is 4235 proportional to the square of his length (100). 4236 4237 The British biologist Sir D'Arcy Wentworth Thompson said in On Growth and Form: "Everywhere nature works true to scale, and everything has its proper size accordingly. Men and trees, birds and fishes, stars 4238 and star-systems, have their 4239 4240 130 4241 4242 appropriate dimensions, and their more or less narrow range of absolute magnitudes." 4243 4244 Some things in nature have about the same shape or pattern regardless of the scale we view them. Asmall part of a cauliflower looks much the same as the entire flower. Other examples include clouds, ferns, 4245 snowflakes, river networks, systems of blood vessels and the structure of coastlines. 4246 4247 'John needs to hire a new assistant and ask his boss: 'Do I have your OK? Adding 4248 4249 $20,000 to the payroll should be inconsequential "' 4250 4251 The concept of scale also applies to time - how things change over time or when something is repeated. What would Warren Buffett have told John? "The proposal should be evaluated as a $3 million decision, 4252 given that an additional person would probably cost at least that amount over his lifetime, factoring in rises, benefits and other expenses." 4253 4254 Small, slow changes operating over long periods can have great consequences. For example, we have seen how small genetic changes can have major anatomical effects over time. 4255 4256 Breakpoints, critical thresholds and limits 4257 4258 At a certain scale, a system reaches a critical mass or a limit where the behavior of the system may change dramatically. It may work better, worse, cease to work or change properties. 4259 4260 Small interactions over time slowly accumulate into a critical state -where the degree of instability increases. A small event may then trigger a dramatic change like an earthquake. 4261 4262 A small change may have no effect on a system until a critical threshold is reached. For example, a drug may be ineffective up until a certain threshold and then become effective, or it may become more and 4263 more effective, but then become harmful. 4264 4265 Another example is from chemistry. When a system of chemicals reaches a certain level of interaction, the system undergoes a dramatic change. A small change in a factor may have an unnoticeable effect but a 4266 further change may cause a system to reach a critical threshold making the system work better or worse. 4267 4268 A system may also reach a threshold when its properties suddenly change from one type of order to another. For example, when a ferromagnet is heated to a critical temperature it loses its magnetization. As it 4269 is cooled back below that temperature, magnetism returns. 4270 4271 A company may reach a certain critical size and get advantages of scale in 4272 4273 131 4274 4275 This means that 8 ice cubes have a surface area of 48 (8 x 6) versus 24 for the larger ice cube. This also means that 8 small ice cubes melt faster than one large ice cube, since the amount of heat an ice 4276 cube can absorb depend on its surface area (the melting process occurs at the surface). Whenever we make objects smaller, we get more surface area per unit volume. For example, since iron rusts when exposed 4277 to air and rusting occur at the surface, a steel knife rusts more slowly than steel wool. 4278 4279 Why did the dinosaurs have such small heads in relation to their bodies? 4280 4281 Living things are shaped and constrained by basic mathematical principles. Weight depends on volume and strength or load-bearing ability on area. The strength of a muscle or a bone is a function of 4282 cross-section area. Strength does not increase at the same rate as weight and volume. When we increase size, weight increases faster than strength. Scale up an organism and sooner or later it will be too weak 4283 to support its own weight. Double the size of a small dinosaur - twice as long, wide and high - and it weighs 8 times as much as before. We now need a neck that is 8 times stronger than before since it must 4284 hold 8 times the weight. But since the strength of the neck is proportional to its cross-section area, the neck is only 4 times stronger. There comes a point where the neck breaks. 4285 4286 What about the giants we see in the movies? 4287 4288 Assume we make a human 10 times larger than normal. This means he is now 10 times longer, 10 times wider, and 10 times higher. He now weighs 1,000 times more but he is only 100 times stronger (as muscular 4289 strength is proportional to the cross section area of a muscle). Since the load-bearing capacity of bones scales in the same manner his bones would be subject to ten times more stress than normal. He needs 4290 thicker bones to support more weight. Otherwise his legs will crush. This is why elephants have such thick stumpy legs to support their weight. The giant has 1,000 times more meat on the body but only 100 4291 times the skin to hold it together meaning ten times the pressure on its skin (since pressure is proportional to area). This also means that his skin surface area is too small to remove the heat emitted from 4292 his huge body. He would suffer from overheating since the amount of heat his body produces is proportional to the cube of his length (1,000), while the amount of heat he dissipates through the skin is 4293 proportional to the square of his length (100). 4294 4295 The British biologist Sir D'Arcy Wentworth Thompson said in On Growth and Form: "Everywhere nature works true to scale, and everything has its proper size accordingly. Men and trees, birds and fishes, stars 4296 and star-systems, have their 4297 4298 130 4299 4300 appropriate dimensions, and their more or less narrow range of absolute magnitudes." 4301 4302 Some things in nature have about the same shape or pattern regardless of the scale we view them. Asmall part of a cauliflower looks much the same as the entire flower. Other examples include clouds, ferns, 4303 snowflakes, river networks, systems of blood vessels and the structure of coastlines. 4304 4305 'John needs to hire a new assistant and ask his boss: 'Do I have your OK? Adding 4306 4307 $20,000 to the payroll should be inconsequential."' 4308 4309 The concept of scale also applies to time - how things change over time or when something is repeated. What would Warren Buffett have told John? "The proposal should be evaluated as a $3 million decision, 4310 given that an additional person would probably cost at least that amount over his lifetime, factoring in rises, benefits and other expenses." 4311 4312 Small, slow changes operating over long periods can have great consequences. For example, we have seen how small genetic changes can have major anatomical effects over time. 4313 4314 Breakpoints, critical thresholds and limits 4315 4316 At a certain scale, a system reaches a critical mass or a limit where the behavior of the system may change dramatically. It may work better, worse, cease to work or change properties. 4317 4318 Small interactions over time slowly accumulate into a critical state -where the degree of instability increases. A small event may then trigger a dramatic change like an earthquake. 4319 4320 A small change may have no effect on a system until a critical threshold is reached. For example, a drug may be ineffective up until a certain threshold and then become effective, or it may become more and 4321 more effective, but then become harmful. 4322 4323 Another example is from chemistry. When a system of chemicals reaches a certain level of interaction, the system undergoes a dramatic change. A small change in a factor may have an unnoticeable effect but a 4324 further change may cause a system to reach a critical threshold making the system work better or worse. 4325 4326 A system may also reach a threshold when its properties suddenly change from one type of order to another. For example, when a ferromagnet is heated to a critical temperature it loses its magnetization. As it 4327 is cooled back below that temperature, magnetism returns. 4328 4329 A company may reach a certain critical size and get advantages of scale in 4330 4331 131 4332 4333 experience, purchasing, marketing, manufacturing, administration, research, logistics, distribution, etc. For example, expenses can be spread out over larger amounts of volume, lowering average costs. These 4334 advantages often permit greater specialization, making people better at what they do. 4335 4336 Scale matters, says Warren Buffett discussing the private jet company NetJets®: 4337 4338 Both we and our customers derive significant operational benefits from our being the runaway leader in the fractional ownership business. We have more than 300 planes constantly on the go in the U.S. and can 4339 therefore be wherever a customer needs us on very short notice. The ubiquity of our fleet also reduces our "positioning" costs below those incurred by operators with smaller fleets. These advantages of scale, 4340 and others we have, give NetJets a significant economic edge over competition. 4341 4342 Charles Munger tells us about another kind of advantage of scale: 4343 4344 In some businesses, the very nature of things is to sort of cascade toward the overwhelming dominance of one firm. The most obvious one is daily newspapers. There's practically no city lefr in the U.S., aside 4345 from a few very big ones, where there's more than one daily newspaper ... Once I get most of the circulation, I get most of the advertising. And once I get most of the advertising and circulation, why would 4346 anyone want the thinner paper with less information in it? So it tends to cascade to a winner-take-all situation. 4347 4348 "We increased production volume but employee focus, service, and motivation went down." 4349 4350 At some point the disadvantages of business size may eat into the advantages. For example, increased costs and investments, per-unit cost increases, systems become too complicated, bureaucratic and 4351 inefficient, etc. 4352 4353 People's behavior may change when we change the scale of a group. What works well in a group of one size may not work at all in a group of another size. Garrett Hardin illustrates this as he examines the 4354 religious Hutterite communities in the northwestern U.S.: 4355 4356 As a colony grows in size, the propensity of the individual to claim a share of production "according to his needs" increases, while his eagerness to work "according to his ability" diminishes. The 4357 effectiveness of the overseers (preachers or bosses) also diminishes. Then, as shrinking increases, those less inclined to "goof off" begin to envy the brotherhood of drones, whom they presently join. 4358 4359 132 4360 4361 The Hutterites learned that scale or the number of people in each decision unit is important. Up to 150 people per colony, the system can be managed by the force of shame. Above this size an appeal to 4362 conscience loses its effectiveness and individuals begin to need more than they contribute. Studies show that groups of about 150 individuals are common in clans of hunter-gatherers, and military units. The 4363 spread of behavior and ideas depends on scale. A certain proportion or minimum number of people (a threshold) must make a choice before we follow their lead. Some examples are whether to join a strike or 4364 riot, adopt an idea, buy a product or stock, speak out on an issue, or leave a boring party. A critical 4365 4366 threshold may cause massive social imitation. 4367 4368 Consider technological, physical, human, biological and mathematical constraints and limits. We can't send signals faster than the speed of light. There are limits to how small or large something can be. 4369 Gordon Moore, one of the founders oflntel, predicted in 1965 that the number of transistors that could be economically produced and placed on a silicon chip would double every 18 months. In 1995 he updated 4370 his prediction to once every two years. Eventually though, physical, engineering or economic limits may stop this from happening. 4371 4372 Size and frequency 4373 4374 Small earthquakes are common while big ones are rare. 4375 4376 Statistics show that the frequency of some events and attributes are inversely proportional to their size. Big or small things can happen but the bigger or more extreme they get, the less frequent they are. 4377 For example, there are a few large earthquakes, fires, avalanches, or cities, but many small ones. There are a few billionaires but many millionaires. 4378 4379 The size and frequency of these events and attributes has a statistical pattern - a scaling relationship that is about the same independent of size (we saw earlier that there is a scaling relationship between 4380 the length of the ice cube's sides and its volume). For example there is a scaling relationship between earthquake magnitude and frequency. Based on observations from 1990, U.S. Geological Survey estimates 4381 the average annually frequency of magnitude 8 and higher earthquakes to 1, magnitude 7-7.9 to 17, magnitude 6-6.9 to 134, and magnitude 5-5.9 to 1319 earthquakes. Still, the patterns are based on past 4382 statistics and estimates. They don't help us to precisely predict future events. For example, catastrophes occur randomly. We don't know when the next big one will occur. 4383 4384 85% of the profits ftom the division came ftom 25% of the products. 4385 4386 The Italian economist and sociologist Vilfredo Pareto noted that 80% of his peas 4387 4388 133 4389 4390 were produced by only 20% of the peapods. He also observed that 20% of the people owned 80% of Italy's land. Often a few things cause much of an effect. For example, a few defects produce most of the problem, 4391 or a few individuals cause most of the problems. A few criminals commit most of the crime. It is estimated that about 5% of movies earn about 80 to 90% of profits in the movie industry. This unevenness is 4392 also common in many other situations like healthcare spending, accidents, or book sales. 4393 4394 Warren Buffett says: "It is not necessary to do extraordinary things to get extraordinary results." A few products or a few customers produce most of the profit or a few in the sales staff produce most of the 4395 sales. In many business activities a few things can produce much of the value. Ask: How do we allocate our time, work, attention and money? Can we identify the few things that really matter? 4396 4397 Constraints 4398 4399 ''Increase production!" 4400 4401 Optimization of one variable may cause the whole system to work less efficiently. Why? The performance of most systems is constrained by the performance of its weakest link. A variable that limits the system 4402 from achieving its goal or optimum performance. An increase in production may for example be physically constrained by the production capacity on one of the machines. If one machine in a production line of 4403 two machines can produce 100 items and the second 90, the output is physically constrained by the second machine. 4404 4405 What do we want to achieve? What will prevent this from happening? Why? 4406 4407 When trying to improve the performance of a system, first find out the system's key contraint(s) - which may be physical (capacity, material, the market) or non physical (policies, rules, measurements) - and 4408 its cause and effect relationship with the system. Maybe the constraint is based on faulty assumptions that can be corrected. Then try to "strengthen" or change the weakest link. Watch out for other effects - 4409 wanted or unwanted - that pop up as a consequence. Always consider the effects on the whole system. 4410 4411 134 4412 4413 - THREE - 4414 4415 CAUSES 4416 4417 "We measure and reward performance by the quantiry of steel produced. " 4418 4419 What do we want to accomplish? It's hard to achieve a result if we don't understand what causes the result to happen. In order to solve problems or achieve goals, we must first understand what causes the 4420 result we want to accomplish. Start with examining what factors make up the system and how they connect. Then, define the key factors that determine outcome. 4421 4422 If a business measures performance by the amount of steel produced, they will 4423 4424 get a lot of steel produced. But the amount of produced kilo steel is only one part of the equation. It's better to ask: What is the equation that achieves what we want to accomplish? What factors cause what 4425 we want to achieve? Under what circumstances? What causes business value? Do we have the factors needed? What must be changed in the equation to achieve what we want? Have we thought through what other 4426 effects our actions may have? 4427 4428 Large effects 4429 4430 A bird flies into the engine of an aircraft and disaster strikes. 4431 4432 We believe that cause resembles its effect - for example, that large or important effects must have large causes or that complicated outcomes have complicated underlying reasons. But the size of an effect may 4433 not be proportional to its cause. Small things may break a large system. In 1988, 35 people died and 113 were injured when a London-bound commuter train crashed into the back of a stationary train. The 4434 accident was caused by faulty wiring work. A mechanic worked more than 12 hours with only a 5-minute break and forgot to remove a small wire from an old switch when installing a new rail signaling system. 4435 4436 On September 23, 1999, the Mars Climate Orbiter spacecraft disappeared 4437 4438 What happened? The core cause was the failed conversion of English units (pounds) to metric units (newton). The manufacturer measured the force of small control thrusters in pounds but the space officials 4439 expected newtons. A misunderstanding that sent the spacecraft about 56 miles too close to Mars, making it disappear into the Martian atmosphere. A simple mistake caused the loss of a $125 million spacecraft. 4440 4441 135 4442 4443 Washing hands save lives. 4444 4445 Dirty hands can cause major health problems. Among bacteria that reproduce by dividing themselves every half hour, a single one can generate about 17 million offspring within 12 hours. Records at the Center 4446 for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC) show that every year close to 2 million people (out of 35 million admissions annually) in the U.S. pick up an infection in the hospital. Of those people, about 90,000 4447 die as a result of their infection. And the major reason is bad hygiene like unsanitary conditions, germ-laden instruments and unwashed hands. CDC and the U.S. Department and Health and Human Services 4448 estimate that strict adherence to clean-hand policies alone could save the lives of 20,000 patients. That washing hands saved lives was discovered in 1847 by the Hungarian gynecologist Ignaz Philipp 4449 Semmelweis. When working at the Maternity Department of the Vienna Hospital, he observed that women delivered by medical students had high mortality rates while those delivered by midwife trainees had low 4450 rates of childbed fever. The difference? The medical students had made pathological dissections, or had come into contact with dead bodies before the examination of the women. Semmelweis introduced the 4451 practice of washing hands in a solution of chlorinated lime before every examination and mortality 4452 4453 rates plummeted. 4454 4455 Random events 4456 4457 '.11. fire in our supplier's factory caused delivery problems of components. We lost market share to competition, which resulted in huge losses. This outcome was unforeseeable since we couldn't have predicted 4458 the fire in advance. " 4459 4460 When bad things happen, we try to find causal explanations or something to blame. The more unexpected or negative we find an event, the more likely we are to look for explanations. We underestimate the 4461 influence of randomness. 4462 4463 Here we define a random event as an event that can't be predicted because of a lack of knowledge. An event is random when we don't have enough information to determine its outcome in advance. 4464 4465 Acting on symptoms 4466 4467 Take away the cause, and the effect ceases. 4468 4469 - Miguel De Cervantes (from Don Quixote) 4470 4471 Sometimes we mistake an effect for its cause. There is a story about a man that was walking by a river when suddenly a screaming girl floated by. The man jumped in the river and saved her. After five minutes, 4472 another screaming girl 4473 4474 136 4475 4476 floated by. He jumped in again and saved the girl. The same thing happened over and over again. The problem was a little further up the river. There was a man throwing girls from a bridge. Our hero solved the 4477 symptoms but not the cause of the problem. 4478 4479 "We have tons of problems. We are losing customers, we can't deliver on time, our inventory system doesn't work. " 4480 4481 What is the core cause of these problems? Many times when we have a lot of problems, there may be one common reason for them all. When dealing with problems we must focus on what we want to achieve and make 4482 sure that we address the underlying cause and not act on symptoms that may look like causes. Maybe the symptoms were due to wrong policies or measuring instruments or goals, etc. 4483 4484 Multiple causes 4485 4486 We attribute an outcome to a single cause when there are multiple causes. We assume that A causes B but A may not be the only thing that causes B. There may be many causes for a given effect. 4487 4488 For example, behavior is determined by a multitude of psychological and non psychological factors, individual characteristics and the given situation. Sometimes these factors interact and reinforce each 4489 other. When explaining behavior, think in terms of multiple causes. For example, Charles Munger says on the Milgram experiment discussed in Part Two (where a group of research subjects delivered electric 4490 shocks simply because they were told to do so by an authoritative figure): 4491 4492 For years it was in the psychology books as a demonstration of authority- how authority could be used to persuade people to do awful things. Of course, that's mere first conclusion bias. That's not the 4493 complete and correct explanation. Authority is part of it. However, there was also quite a few other psychological principles [consistency, contrast, reason-respecting], all operating in the same direction, 4494 which achieved that lollapalooza effect precisely because they acted in combination toward the same end. 4495 4496 Mistaking correlation for cause 4497 4498 Correlation means a relationship or association between two or more variables. We tend to assume that when two things happen together, that one causes the other. That a change in one variable is strongly 4499 correlated or followed by a change in another doesn't automatically mean that one causes the other. Some third factor may cause them both. Assume we detect a high correlation between money 4500 4501 137 4502 4503 and happiness. But that doesn't tell us if money causes happiness, if happiness causes money, or if some third factor causes them both. 4504 4505 An example of statistical misuse is from 1992 when it was reported that 28 teenagers who frequently played the game of "Dungeons and Dragons" (D&D) committed suicide. What conclusion should be drawn? Is there 4506 a link between teenage suicide and the game? 4507 4508 The American mathematician John Allen Paulos tells us in Innumeracy to put this statement into the right perspective by considering two more facts. The game sold millions of copies and about 3 million 4509 teenagers played it. In that age group the annual suicide rate is about 12 people per 100,000. This means chat we can expect 360 D&D playing teenagers (12/100,000 x 3 million players) to commit suicide. 4510 4511 Alternative explanations 4512 4513 ''Mary has a fever and therefore she has a cold. " 4514 4515 There may be many explanations for a given outcome. But we often jump to conclusions and fail to consider alternative explanations. A given effect may be consistent with a range of causes and don't help us 4516 find the core cause of a problem. 4517 4518 That Mary has a fever tells us that she is not well but it doesn't tell us why she is ill. Fever can occur from a range of diseases. Ask: What else can explain this outcome? 4519 4520 Selective data and appropriate comparisons 4521 4522 There is nothing more deceptive than an obvious fact. 4523 4524 Sherlock Holmes (Arthur Conan Doyle, The Boscombe Valley Mystery) 4525 4526 We identify the wrong cause because it seems the obvious one based on a single observed effect. As Bertrand Russell says: "Obviousness is always the enemy to correctness." 4527 4528 When someone remarked to the French writer Voltaire, "Life is hard," he retorted, "Compared to what?" We tend to ignore alternatives, and therefore we fail to make appropriate comparisons. Often we only 4529 consider information or evidence that is presented or available and don't consider that information may be missing. 4530 4531 "By studying successful businesses, I have found that their secret to success is focus," said the CEO ofTransCorp. 4532 4533 But many failed businesses also had focus. Is success, then, due to strong culture, visionary leaders, or something else? Maybe failed enterprises also had strong 4534 4535 138 4536 4537 cultures and visionary leaders. To understand what qualities cause success, we need to compare business successes with failures. We must include companies that started with the same quality but failed. The 4538 problem though, is that the data for failures often disappears. Furthermore, what works in one situation may fail in another. 4539 4540 By interviewing survivors of fatal airline accidents, a 1986 Discover article presented some tips on how we could improve our chances of surviving plane crashes. But as noted by Psychology Professor Robyn 4541 Dawes, there was no evaluation of what percent of all passengers did what the survivors did. Maybe those who died also had done the same. Of course, we can't interview the passengers who didn't survive. 4542 4543 Often the same attributes are used to explain both success and failure. For example, when a company is successful, the media say that it is because of its focus and great leadership. When performance goes 4544 down, they report that the company became less focused and its leadership deteriorated. While there may be evidence that the company is less focused or has worse leadership than before, it could just as well 4545 be that the competition has gotten better. Business performance is relative, not absolute. The performance of a business is always influenced by what its competitors do. Even if a company gets better in many 4546 areas, market share and profits may decline if the competition does things even better. And even if a company gets worse in many areas, market share and profits may increase if competition does things even 4547 worse. 4548 4549 "Look at where the bullet holes are and put extra armor every place else. " 4550 4551 During World War II, the statistician Abraham Wald tried to determine where one should add extra armor to airplanes. Based on the patterns of bullet holes in returning airplanes, he suggested that the parts 4552 not hit should be protected with extra armor. How could he reach that conclusion? Because he also considered planes that didn't return. Assume that all planes had been hit more or less uniformly. Some planes 4553 hit in marked areas were still able to return. This means that planes that didn't return were most likely hit somewhere else - in unmarked places. These were the areas that needed more armor. 4554 4555 "The drug obviously worked since I used it and got better. " 4556 4557 But the same outcome could have happened without taking the drug. We need to consider both confirming and disconfirming evidence. Ask: What is the frequency of supporting cases compared to disconfirming 4558 cases? What is the relative frequency of this condition or disease in the population? 4559 4560 For example, when studying the effectiveness of a new treatment, people often 4561 4562 139 4563 4564 ignore the outcome of a non-treatment, and focus only on a large number of successful treatments, and therefore conclude that the treatment is effective. But we also have to look at the number of people who 4565 a) use the treatment and don't improve, b) don't use the treatment and improve, and c) don't use the treatment and don't improve. 4566 4567 In one study people were asked to judge the effectiveness of a treatment based on the following data from an experiment: 4568 4569 Treatment No treatment 4570 4571 Improvement 200 people 4572 4573 50 4574 4575 No improvement 75 4576 4577 15 4578 4579 Most subjects believed the treatment was effective. But it is rather ineffective. Why? We need to compare the outcome for the no treatment group with the outcome for the treatment group. 50 of 65 people 4580 (50+15) or about 77%, improved without any treatment versus 200 of 275 (200+75) people or about 73% who improved with the treatment. 4581 4582 Psychology Professor Thomas Gilovich says in How We Know What Isn't So: "With the body so effective in healing itself, many who seek medical assistance will experience a positive outcome even if the doctor 4583 does nothing beneficial. Thus, even a worthless treatment can appear effective when the base-rate of success is so high." 4584 4585 What caused customer complaints at TransCorp? 4586 4587 We look for obvious causes and look at the conditions and behavior that were present in the particular situation after we know what happened. But we should observe what is normally happening. Most outcomes 4588 are context-dependent. 4589 4590 Instead of concentrating on conditions, and behavior preceding the customer complaint, TransCorp should examine both sales without complaints and with complaints and ask: What were the underlying conditions 4591 and behavior when customers didn't complain? Are there differences that can explain the complaints? For similar situations, ask: Compared with what? Compare negative outcomes with positive. What factors 4592 differ? What were the underlying conditions and behavior where something bad happened compared to the conditions and behavior when things worked? What differentiates the situations? Don't draw 4593 4594 conclusions from what may have been a unique or random event. 4595 4596 140 4597 4598 - FOUR - 4599 4600 NUMBERS AND THEIR MEANING 4601 4602 Use basic math to count, quantify, and understand relationships 4603 4604 john bought all the stock he could since it was priced at only $1. 4605 4606 Something is only cheap or expensive in relation to something else. If an investor refers to a stock as "cheap," what is it cheap in relation to? 100,000 shares of stock priced at $1 have the same market 4607 valuation as 1,000 shares priced at $100. The relevant question is: What is the company worth in relation to its price? 4608 4609 TransCorp made a "huge" $1 billion in profits. 4610 4611 Words like "big" or "small" have no meaning in themselves. A number has only a size in relation to another number. $1 billion says nothing about economic performance unless we compare it with how much capital 4612 was needed to generate it. What ifTransCorp needed $100 billion in equity and debt to run the business? That's only a 1% return. 4613 4614 "Research shows that the new drug reduces the risk ofgetting the disease by 25%." What benefits can be expected by taking the new drug? Assume statistics show the following: Without the drug 20 people in 4615 1,000 get the disease. By taking the drug, the figure drops to 15 people in 1,000. How efficient is the drug if we look at the absolute number of people saved from the disease? The reduction in absolute risk 4616 is 5 people in 1,000 (20-15) or 0.5%. The reduction in relative risk or the relative number of people saved from the disease is 25% (5/20). A 25% reduction only means something if many people are saved. 4617 4618 How many people need to take the drug in order to save one individual from the disease? Since 5 people in 1,000 (or 1 in 200) are saved from the disease by taking the drug, only one person out of 200 that 4619 take the drug will be saved. For the other 199 people the drug does not have any positive effect. 4620 4621 How do we know that research findings are true? Surveys of epidemiological studies (studies of factors affecting health and illness) show that many researchers' claims don't replicate in medical trials 4622 because of bias and random error. For example, two refuted claims are that aspirin is highly protective against heart disease in both men and women and that vitamin E reduces the 4623 4624 141 4625 4626 chance of cardiovascular mortality. Studies by Hygiene and Epidemiology Professor John Ioannidis show that the smaller the studies; the smaller the effect sizes; the hotter the field; the greater the 4627 interest; the larger the databases; and the greater the flexibility in analyses, the higher the chance that a research claim is false. True replication is the cornerstone of science, and assuming that biases 4628 are weeded out, the more researchers reproduce a finding, the better chance it has of being true. 4629 4630 What does it mean that our sun is 93 million miles away? 4631 4632 Often we need to translate a number to something more understandable. Light travels at an average speed of 186,281 miles per second. This means that it takes sunbeams about 8 minutes to reach the earth. The 4633 star Alpha Centauri is 4.35 light-years away. A light-year is the distance light travels in one year. Even iflight year measures distance, it implies time. If we were to ride on a beam of light, it would take 4634 us 4.35 years to reach our closest star. When we look up in the sky we see the past - the star as it appeared 4.35 years ago. 4635 4636 Always look at what numbers mean. For example, ask: Does the magnitude make sense? In relation to what? Also, think about what counts - not how it is counted. There was a sign hanging in the physicist Albert 4637 Einstein's office at Princeton that said: "Not everything that counts can be counted, and not everything that can be counted counts." 4638 4639 The effect of exponential growth 4640 4641 john's son David made a proposal '1 take out the garbage every day for a month, and you only have to pay me a penny today and then every day afterward I want double as much as I got the day before. " 4642 4643 The sequence of numbers 2, 4, 8, 16 grows exponentially. Day 2 his son would have 2 cents, day 3, 4 cents. After 27 days, he would have $1.3 million dollars. The individual growth is constant - 100% a day- 4644 but the sum gets higher faster and faster. This is the power of doubling. 4645 4646 As we have seen there are limits to prolonged growth. Take bacteria as an example. Assume that a certain strain of bacteria divide in one minute. We put the bacteria in a bottle at 11 am and the bottle is 4647 full at noon. When was the bottle half full? - 11 :59 am. Just one minute earlier. 4648 4649 Even a small number of steady growth leads eventually to doubling and redoubling. For example, a country whose population grows by 2% a year, double in size in 35 years and redoubles in 70 years. A simple 4650 formula for doubling time is found by dividing 70 by the percent growth per year. 4651 4652 142 4653 4654 Compounding refers to "interest on interest." If we invest $1,000 with a return of 6% a year, we receive $60 in the first year. If we reinvest that $60, next year we get another $60 from our original $1,000 4655 investment, plus $3.6 from the $60 we reinvested. If we reinvest all our returns, the total value of our original $1,000 investment after 5 years is: $1,000 x 1.06 x 1.06 x 1.06 x 1.06 X 1.06 = $1,338. 4656 4657 Time is the key to compound interest. Over short periods, compounding produces a little extra return. Over long periods, it has an enormous effect. Invest 4658 4659 $2,500 each year for 40 years at 10% return and you will be a millionaire. 4660 4661 The time value of money 4662 4663 A bird in the hand is worth two in the bush. 4664 4665 -Aesop 4666 4667 Why must we reduce the value of money we receive in the future? 4668 4669 Money paid in the future is worth less than money paid today. A dollar received today is worth more than a dollar received tomorrow. If we have a dollar today, we can invest it and earn interest making that 4670 dollar worth more than a dollar in the future. This means that money has a price and that price is interest. 4671 4672 How much should we pay today for the right of receiving $1,000 a year from now? Or, how much do we need to invest today in order to have $1,000 a year from now? It's the same question. The answer depends on 4673 the interest rate. If the rate is 6%, then the answer is $943. If we invest $943 today at 6%, we have $1,000 one year from now. $943 is the present value of $1,000 a year from now. We have discounted or 4674 reduced $1,000 to its value today. The further out in time we receive the $1,000 or the higher the interest rate is, the less the present value is. 4675 4676 143 4677 4678 - FIVE - 4679 4680 PROBABILITIES AND NUMBER OF POSSIBLE OUTCOMES 4681 4682 Probability is the very guide of life. 4683 4684 Marcus Tullius Cicero 4685 4686 How likely do we believe it is that some event will occur? Probabilities are like guesses. But as Richard Feynman said in his Caltech Lectures on Physics: "There are good guesses and there are bad guesses. 4687 The theory of probability is a system for making better guesses." 4688 4689 We can either estimate the probability based on its relative frequency (proportion of times the event happened in similar situations in the past) or we can make an educated guess using past experiences or 4690 whatever important and relevant information and evidence that is available. 4691 4692 We can also count possible outcomes. The only time we can calculate the exact probability of an event in advance (over a large number of trials) is in cases where we know all possible outcomes and where all 4693 outcomes are equally likely. This is applicable for games of chance such as tossing a coin or rolling a die. However we use the notion of probability, we need to follow its basic rules. 4694 4695 How like/,y is it that a hurricane strikes Texas? 4696 4697 According to the National Hurricane Center, there have been 36 hurricane strikes in Texas from 1900 to 1996. Based on past experience and barring no change in conditions, we can estimate that there is about a 4698 37% (36/97) chance that a hurricane will strike Texas in any given year. This figure - 36/97 - is also called the base rate frequency of outcomes (hurricanes in Texas). 4699 4700 We must make sure that the conditions that produced the relative frequency can be expected to be pretty much the same before we can use it as a guide for the future. We must also look at variations of outcome 4701 and severity (how much damage an event may cause). Take tornadoes as an example. According to the National Climatic Data Center, between 1950 to 1999 there has been an average of 810 tornadoes yearly in the 4702 U.S. But in 1950 there was 201 tornadoes (causing 70 deaths), in 1975, 919 (causing 60 deaths), and in 1999, 1,342 tornadoes (causing 4703 4704 94 deaths). 4705 4706 144 4707 4708 A doctor says, "This is the first time I've seen this disease. I estimate there is a 50-50 chance that the patient will survive. " 4709 4710 This statement has only two possible outcomes. Either the patient dies or not. Does it really make any sense to say "a 50-50 chance" if there are no past data or other evidence to base the probability on? 4711 Does it really tell us something? If there are no historical, comparable or representative data or other evidence to base an estimate on, the probability figure only measures the doctor's belief in the 4712 outcome of the event. 4713 4714 Another doctor says, "According to medical records of similar cases, under the same conditions, 50% of the patients survived five years or longer." 4715 4716 The more representative background data or evidence we have the better our estimate of the probability. 4717 4718 To narrow down the probability figure even more, we need a relevant comparison group, i.e., a group to which a frequency refers. In the hurricane example, we defined the probability for a specific comparison 4719 group, referring to the relative frequency with which hurricanes have occurred (37 times in Texas during the 97 years for which we have data). 4720 4721 Events may happen with great frequency or rarely. Some events are not repeatable and some events have never happened before. For certain events, past experience may not be representative. Others are 4722 characterized by low past frequency and high severity. Unforeseen events occur where our actual exposure (measures vulnerability and potential cost or loss) is unknown. Sometimes people react to an event by 4723 avoiding or preventing it in the future causing a change of the events future probability. Other times one bad event may increase the chance of another. For example, an earthquake may cause landslides, 4724 floods, or power blackouts. The more uncertainty there is, the harder it is to find a meaningful probability number. Instead our estimate must be constrained to a range of possible outcomes and their 4725 probabilities. 4726 4727 Uncertainty increases the difficulty for insurers to appropriately pnce catastrophes, such as hurricanes or earthquakes. Warren Buffett says: 4728 4729 Catastrophe insurers can't simply extrapolate past experience. If there is truly "global warming," for example, the odds would shift, since tiny changes in atmospheric conditions can produce momentous changes 4730 in weather patterns. Furthermore, in recent years there has been a mushrooming of population and insured values in U.S. coastal areas that are particularly vulnerable to hurricanes, the number one creator of 4731 super-cats. A hurricane that caused x dollars of damage 20 years ago could easily cost 1Ox now. 4732 4733 145 4734 4735 Occasionally, also, the unthinkable happens. Who would have guessed for example, that a major earthquake could occur in Charleston, S.C.? (It struck in 1886, registered an estimated 6.6 on the Richter scale, 4736 and caused 60 deaths.) 4737 4738 But it may still be possible to price sensibly. Warren Buffett says: 4739 4740 Even if perfection in assessing risks is unattainable, insurers can underwrite sensibly. After all, you need not know a man's precise age to know that he is old enough to vote nor know his exact weight to 4741 recognize his need to diet. 4742 4743 Warren Buffett also considers a worst case scenario: 4744 4745 Given the risks we accept, Ajit [Ajit Jain; manager of Berkshire's reinsurance operations] and I constantly focus on our "worst case," knowing, of course, that it is difficult to judge what this is, since you 4746 could conceivably have a Long Island hurricane, a California earthquake, and Super Cat X all in the same year. Additionally, insurance losses could be accompanied by non-insurance troubles. For example, were 4747 we to have super-cat losses from a large Southern California earthquake, they might well be accompanied by a major drop in the value of our holdings in See's, Wells Fargo and Freddie Mac... 4748 4749 We do, though, monitor our aggregate exposure in order to keep our "worst case" at a level that leaves us comfortable. 4750 4751 How reliable is past experience for predicting the future? In Against the Gods, Peter Bernstein refers to a 1703 letter written by German mathematician Gottfried Wilhelm von Leibniz to the Swiss scientist and 4752 mathematician Jacob Bernoulli referring to mortality rates: "New illnesses flood the human race, so that no matter how many experiments you have done on corpses, you have not thereby imposed a limit on the 4753 nature of events so that in the future they could not vary." Even with the best empirical evidence, nobody knows precisely what will happen in the future. 4754 4755 After the September 11, 2001, catastrophe, Warren Buffett wrote on the importance on focusing on actual exposure and how using past experience sometimes may be dangerous: 4756 4757 In setting prices and also in evaluating aggregation risk, we had either overlooked or dismissed the possibility oflarge-scale terrorism losses... In pricing property coverages, for example, we had looked to 4758 the past and taken into account only costs we might expect to incur from windstorm, fire, explosion and earthquake. But what will be the largest insured 4759 4760 146 4761 4762 property loss in history (after adding related business interruption claims) originated from none of these forces. In short, all of us in the industry made a fundamental underwriting mistake by focusing on 4763 experience, rather than exposure, thereby assuming a huge terrorism risk for which we received no premium. 4764 4765 Experience, of course, is a highly useful starting point in underwriting most coverages. For example, it's important for insurers writing California earthquake policies to know how many quakes in the state 4766 during the past century have registered 6.0 or greater on the Richter scale. This information will not tell you the exact probability of a big quake next year, or where in the state it might happen. But the 4767 statistic has utility, particularly if you are writing a huge statewide policy... 4768 4769 At certain times, however, using experience as a guide to pricing is not only useless, but actually dangerous. Late in a bull market, for example, large losses from directors and officers liability insurance 4770 ("D&O") are likely to be relatively rare. When stocks are rising, there are a scarcity of targets to sue, and both questionable accounting and management chicanery often go undetected. At that juncture, 4771 experience on high-limit D&O may look great. 4772 4773 But that's just when [3mexposure [0mis likely to be exploding, by way of ridiculous public offerings, earnings manipulation, chain-letter-like stock promotions and a potpourri of other unsavory activities. When 4774 stocks fall, these sins surface, hammering investors with losses that can run into the hundreds of billions. 4775 4776 Even if we for some events can't estimate their probability, there may be some evidence telling us if their probabilities are increasing or decreasing. Ask: Do I understand the forces that can cause the 4777 event? What are the key factors? Are there more opportunities for the event to happen? 4778 4779 Warren Buffett says on terrorism: 4780 4781 No one knows the probability of a nuclear detonation in a major metropolis area this year... Nor can anyone, with assurance, assess the probability in this year, or another, of deadly biological or chemical 4782 agents being introduced simultaneously... into multiple office buildings and manufacturing plants... 4783 4784 Here's what we do know: a. The probability of such mind-boggling disasters, though 4785 4786 likely very low at present, is not zero. b. The probabilities are increasing, in an irregular and immeasurable manner, as knowledge and materials become available to those who wish us ill. 4787 4788 The more opportunities (possible wanted or unwanted outcomes) an event has to happen in relation to what can happen (all possible outcomes), the more likely it is to occur. 4789 4790 147 4791 4792 Number of possible outcomes 4793 4794 Toss a coin once. What can happen? There are 2 possible outcomes. Roll a die once. There are 6 possible outcomes. All equally likely. Roll a die twice. What can happen? There are 6 possible outcomes on each 4795 roll and therefore 36 possible combinations or outcomes when rolling a die twice. Roll a die 3 times. There are 216 possible outcomes. 4796 4797 This is a simplified way of saying that the more possible outcomes an event has (in number or time), the less likely a specific outcome is (for example only one outcome satisfies the wanted event: "roll a die 4798 once and observe a six") and the more likely some outcome is (there are 6 possible outcomes to choose from). The more possible outcomes a specific event has, and the more they are unwanted, and the more 4799 independent events that are needed to achieve a scenario, the less likely it is that the wanted scenario happens. Some outcomes 4800 4801 may be less likely than others (for example, due to constraints or limits). 4802 4803 Treat rolling a die 3 times as 3 separate events where each event is "observe a six". What we see from the above is that the more events that must happen to achieve some scenario or wanted outcome ("3 sixes 4804 in a row"), the less likely the scenario is to happen. Observing "anything but 3 sixes in a row" is an unwanted event. There are 215 outcomes or ways for this unwanted event to happen out of 4805 4806 216. This means that it is very likely that the unwanted event happens. 4807 4808 We talk about what is likely to happen in the long run. We might be lucky and roll 3 sixes in a row. We must also consider the consequences of an unwanted outcome. 4809 4810 What does this mean? If there are more ways of reaching a bad outcome than 4811 4812 a good outcome, the probability of a bad outcome is higher. It is easier to destroy a system than to create one merely because there are more opportunities for destruction than creation. 4813 4814 It means that surprises, coincidences, rare events and accidents happen, somewhere, sometime, and to someone if they have opportunities to happen. 4815 4816 It also means that eliminating risk is preferable to finding out where the risk lies (since there are so many opportunities for an unwanted outcome). For example, we can reduce risk by increasing the number 4817 of wanted possible outcomes, reducing the number of unwanted possible outcomes, reducing the magnitude of consequences or avoiding certain situations. 4818 4819 Ask some relevant questions: 4820 4821 Event: Type of event? Frequent? Unique? 4822 4823 Causes: What can initiate and cause the event? What factors contribute? What conditions and circumstances must be present? Have the causes changed over time? 4824 4825 148 4826 4827 Exposure: Known? Measurable? Possible consequences? Magnitude of consequences/loss? What's the worst that can happen? 4828 4829 Probability: Distribution of possible outcomes over time? Stable? Relative frequency or relevant past experience? Number of observations? Relative likelihood of different size of losses? How is average 4830 frequency produced? Variability in outcome and severity? Dependence on human factors? 4831 4832 Representative: Past data representative or change in conditions? Evidence of changes in causes or frequency of event? Temporary or permanent change? Small sample or too short observation time? Changing 4833 exposure as time proceeds? 4834 4835 Backups: Backup failure rate? 4836 4837 Let's observe some effects of what we've described in this chapter. More focus is put on the underlying ideas than the math. The theory of probability and its definitions, rules and calculations are found in 4838 Appendix Three. 4839 4840 Low frequency events 4841 4842 The chance of gain is by every man more or less overvalued, and the chance of loss is by most men undervalued 4843 4844 - Adam Smith (Scottish philosopher and economist, 1723-1790) 4845 4846 Supreme Court Justice Oliver Wendell Holmes, Jr. said: "Most people think dramatically, not quantitatively." We overestimate the frequency of deaths from publicized events like tornadoes, floods and homicides 4847 and underestimate the frequency of deaths from less publicized ones like diabetes, stroke and stomach cancer. Why? As we learned in Part Two, we tend to overestimate how often rare but recent, vivid or highly 4848 publicized events happen. The media has an interest in translating the improbable to the believable. There is a difference between the real risk and the risk that sells papers. A catastrophe like a plane 4849 crash makes a compelling news story. Highly emotional events make headlines but are not an indicator of frequency. Consider instead all the times that nothing happens. Most flights are accident-free. Ask: How 4850 likely is the event? How serious are the consequences? 4851 4852 john is boarding the day flight from Los Angeles to Washington and wonders, "How likely am I to die on this trip?" 4853 4854 What is the risk of a disaster? First we need to know the available record of previous flights that can be compared to John's. Assume, we find that in 1 out of 10,000 flights there was an accident. The record 4855 also shows that when an accident happens, on average 8 out of 10 are killed, 1 injured and one safe. This means that 4856 4857 149 4858 4859 the chance that a passenger will be involved in an accident is 1 in 10,000; being killed, 1 in 12,500 (10,000/0.8); and being injured, 1 in 100,000 (10.000/0.1) 4860 4861 According to the Federal Aviation Administration, Dr. Arnold Barnett of Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT), a widely recognized expert on air traffic safety, measured a passenger's odds of surviving 4862 the next flight. It related the probability of not being in a fatal air carrier accident and the probability of not surviving if a fatal accident happens. In the year 2000 the odds were 5.8 million to 1. 4863 4864 According to the National Transportation Safety Board the number of passengers killed in air accidents in the U.S. during 1992 through 2001 was 433 (including the 232 aboard the four hijacked flights on 4865 September 11, 2001). For reference, in 2001, the annual number oflives lost in road traffic accidents in the 4866 4867 U.S. was 42,119. 4868 4869 That people feel safer driving than flying makes sense since we are oriented towards survival. As Antonio Damasio says in Descartes' Error, "Planes do crash now and then, and fewer people survive plane 4870 crashes than survive car crashes." Studies also show that we fear harm from what's unfamiliar much more than mundane hazards and by things we feel we control. We don't feel in control when we fly. 4871 4872 Why do we lose money gambling? Why do we invest in exotic long shot ventures? We often overestimate the chance of low probability but high-payoff bets. For example, how likely is it that anyone guesses a 4873 number between 1 and 14 million? What is Mary's chance of winning "Lotto 6/49" if there are 14 million outcomes? What must happen? She must pick 6 numbers out of 49 and if they all match she wins. What can 4874 happen? How many numbers can she choose from? The possible number of ways she can choose 6 numbers out of 49 is 13,983,816. The probability that someone chooses the winning combination is therefore one in 4875 about 14 million. Merely slightly better than throwing heads on 24 successive tosses of a coin. 4876 4877 Imagine the time it takes to put together 14 million combinations. If we assume every combination on average takes 1 minute to put down on paper, and Mary pick numbers for 24 hours a day, it will take her 27 4878 years to write them all down. 4879 4880 Even if Mary invests $14 million to buy 14 million tickets in the hopes of winning a $20 million jackpot, she may have to share the jackpot with others that picked the winning number. If just one other person 4881 picked the winning combination, she would lose $4 million (20/2- 14). 4882 4883 150 4884 4885 Why do people play a game when the likelihood of losing is so high? Even if we exclude the amusement factor and the reinforcement from an occasional pay off, it is understandable since they perceive the 4886 benefit of being right as huge and the cost of being wrong as low - merely the cost of the ticket or a dollar. Remember the advice of Benjamin Franklin: "He that waits upon fortune, is never sure of a 4887 dinner." 4888 4889 Mathematical expectation 4890 4891 A lottery has JOO tickets. Each ticket costs $10. The cash price is $500. Is it worthwhile for Mary to buy a lottery ticket? 4892 4893 The expected value of this game is the probability of winning (1 in 100) multiplied with the price ($500) less the probability of losing (99 out of 100) multiplied with the cost of playing ($10). For each 4894 outcome we take the probability and multiply the consequence (a reward or a cost) and then add the figures. This means that Mary's expected value of buying a lottery ticket is a loss of about $5 (0.01 x $500 4895 - 0.99 x $10). 4896 4897 We need to separate between few games and many games. Since probability means the number of times an event is likely to happen during a large number of trials, the expected value is the amount Mary should 4898 expect to win or lose per game if she made the same bet many times. Expected value tells Mary that she on average should expect to lose $5 every time she plays if she plays the same lottery over and over. Not 4899 what she can expect from a single game. Mary has a 1 4900 4901 % chance of winning the lottery and if she wins, her gain is $490. She has a 99 4902 4903 % chance oflosing $10. 4904 4905 Most of our decisions in every-day life are one-time bets. Choices we face only once. Still, this is not the last decision we make. There are a large number of uncertain decisions we make over a lifetime. We 4906 make bets every day. So if we view life's decisions as a series of gambles, we should use expected value as a guide whenever appropriate. Over time, we will come out better. 4907 4908 John placed $38 dollar on the roulette tabk. 4909 4910 Mathematics and human nature make it impossible for us to beat the roulette wheel for any considerable length of time. If we play at a casino once we may be lucky and in the short run win some money, but we 4911 should expect to lose in the long run. The casino has the advantage. 4912 4913 There are 38 different numbers (including double zero) on the roulette wheel. When the croupier spins the wheel there is an equal chance of the ball landing in any one of the 38 slots. John puts $1 on a 4914 single number. If his number comes 4915 4916 151 4917 4918 up, he wins $35. On average his expected value of a one dollar bet is a loss of 5.26 cents (1/38x$35 - 37/38x$1). Over the long run John loses an average of 5.26 cents for every dollar he places on the table. 4919 The odds are set so they average out in the casino's favor. 4920 4921 ''If I just stay at the table long enough, the odds turn in my favor and I will win back everything I lost. " 4922 4923 But this is what the casino wants us to believe. The casino can't predict the outcome of any particular bet but as soon as there are a large number of individual players making bets, the casino will make 4924 money. As a casino operator said: "What I love is the risk. Some nights we make money, and other nights we make more money." 4925 4926 Even if we win in the short run, human nature turns us into losers. Nearly all of those who win big continue to play until they have lost their gains, and perhaps more. This is well illustrated by Henry 4927 Howard Harper in his book, The Psychology of Speculation: 4928 4929 It is said to be a proven fact that the chances are so much against the player, that a roulette wheel can be run at a profit, even if the percentage in favor of the house is entirely eliminated. This is due 4930 to the fact that the excitement of play causes a certain confusion of mind, and players are prone to do the wrong thing; for instance, double their bets when in an adverse run of luck and "pinch" them when 4931 luck is running favorably. Or, on the other hand, players who have pressed their advantage and doubled in a run of favorable luck will continue stubbornly to plunge long after their luck has changed. 4932 Precisely the same psychology applies to trading in stocks. 4933 4934 Chance has no memory 4935 4936 "My luck is about to change. The trend will reverse. " 4937 4938 We tend to believe that the probability of an independent event is lowered when it has happened recently or that the probability is increased when it hasn't happened recently. For example, after a run of bad 4939 outcomes in independent events that appear randomly, we sometimes believe a good outcome is due. But previous outcomes neither influence nor have any predictive value of future outcomes. There is neither 4940 memory nor a sense of justice. 4941 4942 Mary flipped a coin and got 5 heads in a row. Is a tail due? It must be, since in the long run heads and tails balance out. 4943 4944 When we say that the probability of tossing tails is 50%, we mean that over a long 4945 4946 152 4947 4948 run of tosses, tails come up half the time. The probability that Mary flips a head on her fifth toss is 50%. The coin has no sense of fairness. As the 19th Century French mathematician Joseph Bertrand said: 4949 "The coin has neither memory or consciousness." Mary committed the gambler's fallacy. This happens when we believe that when something has continued for a certain period of time, it goes back to its long-term 4950 average. This is the same as the roulette player when he bets on red merely because black has come up four times in a row. But black has the same chance as red to come up on the next spin. Each spin, each 4951 outcome is independent of the one before. Only in the long run will the ratio of red to black become equal. 4952 4953 Every single time Mary plays, the probability it lands on heads is 50% and lands on tails 50%. Even if we know that the probability is 50%, we can't predict if a given flip results in a head or tail. We may 4954 flip heads ten times in a row or none. The laws of probability don't count out luck. 4955 4956 "J got a speeding ticket yesterday, so now I can cross the speed limit again,"said john. Even criminals suffer the gambler's fallacy. Studies show that repeat criminals expect their chance of getting caught 4957 to be reduced after being caught and punished unless they are extremely unlucky. 4958 4959 Mary finds it comforting knowing it will take another 99 years until the next giant storm happen. 4960 4961 What is a" 100-year storm?" To predict storms we look at past statistics i.e., how often in the recorded past a storm of a certain magnitude has occurred. We also assume that the same magnitude of storm will 4962 occur with the same frequency in the future. A 100-year storm doesn't mean it happens only once every 100 years. It could happen any year. If we get a once in 100-year storm this year, another big one could 4963 happen next year. A 100-year event only means that there is a 1% chance that the event will happen in any given year. So even if large storms are rare, they occur at random. The same reasoning is true for 4964 floods, tsunamis, or airplane crashes. In all independent events that have random components in them, there is no memory of the past. 4965 4966 Controlling chance events 4967 4968 The craps table was filled with people tossing their die soft and asking for a low number. 4969 4970 We believe in lucky numbers and we believe we can control the outcome of chance events. But skill or effort doesn't change the probability of chance events. 4971 4972 153 4973 4974 "Change tickets! Are you crazy! I would feel awfol if my number comes up and I'd traded it away. " 4975 4976 In one experiment a social psychologist found that people were more reluctant to give up a lottery ticket they had chosen themselves, than one selected at random for them. They wanted four times as much money 4977 for selling the chosen ones compared to what they wanted for the randomly selected ticket. But in random drawings it doesn't make any difference if we choose a ticket or are assigned one. The probability of 4978 winning is the same. The lesson is, if you want to sell lottery tickets, let people choose their own numbers instead of randomly drawing them. 4979 4980 Gains, losses and utility 4981 4982 The 18th Century Swiss mathematician Daniel Bernoulli said: ''A gain of one thousand ducats is more significant to a pauper than to a rich man though both gain the same amount." This means that the utility or 4983 personal value of an outcome differs for different people and at different stages in life. For example, our preferences change as our state of wealth changes. 4984 4985 Often when we make financial decisions we don't consider our total wealth. Instead we judge a decision by evaluating changes measured in terms of short term gains and losses. 4986 4987 "Should I invest?" 4988 4989 "There is a 50% probability that I gain $10,000. There is a 50% probability that I lose $4,000. " 4990 4991 "Since I get pleasure from gains and the expected value ($3,000} is positive, I decide to invest." 4992 4993 Instead we should take a more long-term view and think in terms of wealth. We should add our current wealth to all possible financial outcomes and choose the alternative that has a higher expected utility 4994 (considering our own psychological nature, talent and goals). 4995 4996 ''My present wealth is $1,000,000. Do I choose $1,000,000 for sure or $996,000 or 4997 4998 $1,010,000 with equal probabilities?" 4999 5000 "Since the expected utility resulting from integrating the favorable investment with my wealth is lower than the expected utility of my current wealth, I don't invest. " Remember that the concept of utility 5001 is about the personal value of potential consequences and is therefore different for different individuals. An individual who finds that the expected utility resulting from integrating the mentioned 5002 5003 154 5004 5005 investment with his wealth are higher or about the same as the expected utility of his current wealth, will choose the favorable investment. 5006 5007 Ask: What do I end up with? How much will I have ifl succeed and how much will I have ifl fail? How certain am I? What is the expected utility? 5008 5009 The consequences of low frequency events 5010 5011 Imagine the following scenario: 5012 5013 Outcome A OutcomeB 5014 5015 Probability Cost of consequence 5016 5017 10% -90 5018 5019 90% -10 5020 5021 Expected value 5022 5023 -9 5024 5025 -9 5026 5027 Both outcomes have the same expected value but differ hugely in their cost of consequences. We can't only look at how likely an unwanted event is to happen. We must also rate the magnitude of its 5028 consequences. Before taking an action, ask: What are the benefits and costs? What might go wrong? How can it go wrong? How much can I lose? What is the probability and consequence of failure over time? How 5029 can the probability and consequence of failure be reduced? 5030 5031 What if the probability of success is high but the consequence of failure is terrible? 5032 5033 The consequences of being wrong 5034 5035 Take no chance whatsoever with food poisoning, and stay away from places where others have been recently killed, regardless 5036 5037 of what the mathematical laws of probability tell you. 5038 5039 - Edward Wilson (Professor Emeritus, from Consilience) 5040 5041 "Pascal's Wager" is Blaise Pascal's argument for believing in God. Pascal reasoned as follows: If we believe in God, and God exists, we would gain in afterlife. If we don't believe in God, and God exists, we 5042 will lose in afterlife. Independent of the probabilities of a God, the consequences of not believing are so awful, we should hedge our bet and believe. 5043 5044 Pascal suggests that we are playing a game with 2 choices, believe and not believe, with the following consequences: 5045 5046 155 5047 5048 Probability (p) Believe 5049 5050 Don't believe 5051 5052 God does exist 5053 5054 p 5055 5056 Saved (good) Damned (bad) 5057 5058 God does not exist (1 - p) 5059 5060 Inconvenience Normal life 5061 5062 If God exists, and we believe God exists, we are saved. This is good. If we don't believe, and God is unforgiving, we are damned. If we believe but God doesn't exist, we miss out on some worldly pleasures. If 5063 God doesn't exist and we don't believe that God exists, we live a normal life. 5064 5065 Expected value of believing= p (the value of being saved) + (1-p)(the cost of inconvenience) 5066 5067 Expected value of not believing = p(the cost of being damned) + (1-p)(the value ofliving a normal life) 5068 5069 Pascal said: "If I lost, I would have lost little. If I won I would have gained eternal life." Our choice depends on the probabilities, but Pascal assumed that the consequences of being damned is infinite, 5070 meaning the expected value of believing is least negative and therefore he reasoned that believing in God is best no matter how low we set the probability that God exists. 5071 5072 john wants to make extra money and is offered to play Russian Roulette. 5073 5074 If John wins he gets $10 million. Should he play? There are 6 equally likely possible outcomes when he pulls the trigger - empty, empty, empty, empty, empty, bullet. This makes the probability 5/6 or 83%. 5075 This is the same as saying that John is playing a lottery with only 6 tickets where one ticket is lethal. 5076 5077 Should he play this game once? The probability is 83% that he gets $10 million. The probability is only 17% that he loses. 5078 5079 Let's look at the consequences: If John doesn't play and there was a bullet he is glad he didn't play. If he plays and there is a bullet, he dies. If he doesn't play and there was no bullet he loses the 5080 pleasure which the extra money could have bought him. If he plays and there is no bullet he gains $10 million which would buy him extra pleasure. To play is to risk death in exchange for extra pleasure. There 5081 is an 83% probability that John is right but the consequence of being wrong is fatal. Even if the probabilities favor him, the downside is unbearable. Why should John risk his life? The value of survival is 5082 infinite, so the strategy of not playing is best no matter what probability we assign for the existence of "no bullet" or what money is being offered. But there may be exceptions. Someone that is poor, in 5083 need of supporting a family who knows he will die of a lethal disease within 3 months might pull the trigger. He could lose 3 months of life, 5084 5085 156 5086 5087 but if he wins, his family will be taken care of after his death. 5088 5089 We should never risk something we have and need for something we don't need. But some people pull the trigger anyway. This is what Warren Buffett said about the Long-Term Capital Management affair: 5090 5091 Here were 16 extremely bright - and I do mean [3mextremely [0mbright - people at the top of LTCM. The average IQ among their top 16 people would probably be as high or higher than at any other organization you 5092 could find. And individually, they had decades of experience - collectively, [3mcenturies [0mof experience - in the sort of securities in which LTCM was invested. 5093 5094 Moreover, they had a [3mhuge [0mamount of their [3mown [0mmoney up - and probably a very high percentage of their net worth in almost every case. So here were super-bright, extremely experienced people, operating with 5095 their own money. And yet, in effect, on that day in September, they were broke. To me, that's absolutely fascinating. 5096 5097 In fact, there's a book with a great title - [3mYou Only Have to Get Rich Once. [0mIt's a great title, but not a very good book. (Walter Guttman wrote it many years ago.) But the tide is right: You only have to get 5098 rich [3monce. [0mWhy do very bright people risk losing something that's very important to them to gain something that's totally unimportant? The added money has no utility whatsoever - and the money that was lost 5099 had enormous utility. And on top of that, their reputation gets tarnished and all of that sort of thing. So the gain/loss ratio in any real sense is just [3mincredible... [0mWhenever a really bright person who has 5100 a lot of money goes broke, it's because of leverage... It's [3malmost [0mimpossible to go broke without borrowed money being in the equation. 5101 5102 157 5103 5104 - SIX - 5105 5106 SCENARIOS 5107 5108 Systems construction and planning processes 5109 5110 He that builds before he counts the cost, acts foolishly; 5111 5112 And he that counts before he builds, finds he did not count wisely. 5113 5114 - Benjamin Franklin 5115 5116 just as john started to renovate his house, TransCorp initiated a billion-dollar project. Why do house construction projects, start-ups or product development ventures take more time, money and effort than we 5117 expect? For example, one study found that of 3,500 projects executed, the project budget was often exceeded by 40 - 200%. Studies by Planning Professor Bent Flyvbjerg found that about 9 out of 10 5118 transportation infrastructure projects had cost overruns. His studies also found large deviations between forecast and actual traffic demand volumes. He gives us several examples: Boston's Central Artery 5119 Tunnel was 275% or $11 billion over budget in constant dollars. Costs for Denver's $5 billion International Airport were dose to 200% higher than estimated and passenger traffic in the opening year was half 5120 of that projected. Denmark's Great Belt underwater rail tunnel had cost over-runs by 110%. Other examples on projects with cost overruns and benefit shortfalls are Bangkok's Skytrain, Los Angeles' convention 5121 center, Quebec's Olympic stadium, the Eurofighter military jet, the Channel Tunnel, the Pentagon Spy Satellite Program, and Athens' 2004 Olympics. 5122 5123 A project is composed of a series of steps where all must be achieved for success. Each individual step has some probability of failure. We often underestimate the large number of things that may happen in 5124 the future or all opportunities for failure that may cause a project to go wrong. Humans make mistakes, equipment fails, technologies don't work as planned, unrealistic expectations, biases including sunk 5125 cost-syndrome, inexperience, wrong incentives, contractor failure, untested technology, delays, wrong deliveries, changing requirements, random events, ignoring early warning signals are reasons for delays, 5126 cost overruns and mistakes. Often we focus too much on the specific project case and ignore what normally happens in similar situations (base rate frequency of outcomes-personal and others). Why should some 5127 project be any different from 5128 5129 158 5130 5131 the long-term record of similar ones? George Bernard Shaw said: "We learn from history that man can never learn anything from history." 5132 5133 The more independent steps that are involved in achieving a scenario, the more opportunities for failure and the less likely it is that the scenario will happen. We often underestimate the number of steps, 5134 people and decisions involved. 5135 5136 Add to this that we often forget that the reliability of a system is a function of the whole system. The weakest link sets the upper limit for the whole chain. 5137 5138 TransCorp wants to develop a new product. 5139 5140 To predict the probability of developing the new product we need to know all the steps in the product development chain and the probability of each one. The project is composed of 6 steps and each step is 5141 independent of the others. Each step has an 80% probability of success. Based on similar development programs performed under the same conditions, TransCorp estimates that 8 out of 10 times each step is 5142 successful. In 2 times out of 10 something happens that prevents each step from succeeding. But since each step is independent, the probabilities must be multiplied together. The probability the company 5143 finally succeeds in developing the product is 26% - meaning that TransCorp should expect success one time out of four. So even if each step had an 80% probability of success, when combined, the probability of 5144 product success decreases to 26%. 5145 5146 Every time we add another step to some system, the probability that the system works is reduced. 5147 5148 John is thinking of investing in a biotech start-up. 5149 5150 Professor and startup coach John Nesheim, who has been involved in some 300 plus startups, tells us in High Tech Startup, that only six out of one million high tech ideas turn into a public company. This base 5151 rate frequency tells us there is a low prior probability of turning into a public company. 5152 5153 Take a biotech venture as an example. Studies show that of every 10,000 to 30,000 drug candidate molecule entering discovery, only 250 make it to pre clinical evaluation; only 5 to 10 to clinical; and only 5154 one gets approved. There are so many things that must go right before it becomes a business that generates money. Factors like technological virtue, product safety, cost-effectiveness, manufacturing, patent 5155 issues, product stability, regulatory matters, market assessment, competitive position, financial need (and availability), etc. How can we put a probability number on all these factors? And even if we can, 5156 these factors must all work to achieve the desired scenario. Ask: What is the prior probability of success for this type of venture before I consider this specific case? 5157 5158 159 5159 5160 Warren Buffett says on biotech: 5161 5162 How many of these companies are making a couple of hundred million dollars a year? It just doesn't happen. It's not that easy to make lots of money in a business in a capitalistic society. There are people 5163 that are looking at what you're doing every day and trying to figure out a way to do it better, underprice you, bring out a better product or whatever it may be. 5164 5165 The compensation we need for taking a risk is really a function of the wanted outcome in relation to all possible outcomes. Take rolling a die as an example. How likely is it that we get a six four times in a 5166 row? If we have to invest $1 to play this game once, we need to get back $1,296 to go even. There are 1,296 outcomes and only one of them is favorable (6,6,6,6). 5167 5168 The more negative things that can happen - or positive things that must happen - the better compensated we must be for taking on the risk. Ask: What can happen and what are the consequences? Anticipate 5169 unforeseen obstacles. 5170 5171 If you do venture investments, follow the advice of Warren Buffett: 5172 5173 You may consciously purchase a risky investment - one that indeed has a significant possibility of causing loss or injury - if you believe that your gain, weighted for probabilities, considerably exceeds your 5174 loss, comparably weighted, and if you can commit to a number of similar, but unrelated opportunities. Most venture capitalists employ this strategy. Should you choose to pursue this course, you should adopt 5175 the outlook of the casino that owns a roulette wheel, which will want to see lots of action because it is favored by probabilities, but will refuse to accept a single, huge bet. 5176 5177 We can demonstrate Buffett's advice mathematically. Suppose a start-up has a 40% probability of succeeding. The probability that 10 mutually independent start-ups (with the same probability of success) all 5178 succeed is 0.01% but the probability that at least one succeeds is 99.4%. Here we assumed that the fate of each venture is independent of the fate of the other. That one start-up fails make it no more likely 5179 that another start-up fails. 5180 5181 "How can we fond this venture if we don't present a great fature?" 5182 5183 Consider bias from incentives. To sell in a venture, expected returns are often overestimated. Warren Buffett says, "We expect all of our businesses to now and then have ups and downs. (Only in the sales 5184 presentations of investment banks do earnings move forever upward.)" 5185 5186 160 5187 5188 Systems failure and accidents 5189 5190 On July 25th, 2000, a Concorde bound ftom Paris to New York crashed shortly after take off All I 09 people on board were killed, along with 4 on the ground. 5191 5192 A stray metal strip on the runway lost by another aircraft caused the event. As a result a tire burst. Its explosion sent pieces of rubber into the fuel tank, causing a fuel leak and fire. 5193 5194 We underestimate how likely it is that an event happens when it may happen one way or another. Accidents happen if they have opportunities to happen. 5195 5196 Astronomy Professor Carl Sagan said in Carl Sagan: a life in the cosmos: "The Chernobyl and Challenger disasters remind us that highly visible technological systems in which enormous national prestige had 5197 been invested can nevertheless experience catastrophic failures." 5198 5199 System safety doesn't reside in one component but in the interactions of all the components. If one key component fails, the system may fail. Assume a space shuttle is composed of 2,000 independent parts or 5200 smaller systems, each with a workingprobabilityof99.9%. All parts need to work for the shuttle to work. The probability that at least one of the parts doesn't work causing the shuttle to malfunction is 86% 5201 (many parts means many opportunities for failure). 5202 5203 The blackout began at 10:30 p.m. in the Omaha area and the domino effect caused a cascade of electricity cuts throughout U.S. 5204 5205 Some systems are more prone to accidents than others because of the number of components, their connections and interactions. The more variables we add to a system, and the more they interact, the more 5206 complicated we make it and the more opportunity the system has to fail. Improving certain parts in highly interconnected systems may do little to eliminate future problems. There is always the possibility of 5207 multiple simultaneous failures and the more complicated the system, the harder it is to predict all possible failures. The exception to this is systems that serve as a substitute if the present system breaks 5208 down. We must ensure that backup systems don't cause unwanted effects or that some parts share the same defects. 5209 5210 Separate between independent and dependent events. The probability that an airplane navigation system works is 99% and the probability that the backup navigation system works is 90%. The probability that the 5211 backup system fails is not influenced by whether the primary system fails or not. The probability that neither navigation system works is one tenth of a percent (0.0lx0.1). Navigation system reliability is 5212 therefore 99.9% (at least one navigation system will work). 5213 5214 But if the systems are dependent - the probability of the backup failing rises 5215 5216 161 5217 5218 if the primary system fails - the overall probability of a system failure increases. We can't assume that events are independent of each other. What happens next in a chain of events may not be independent of 5219 the previous outcome. Subsystems may share something in common. For example, aircraft engines draw fuel from a common supply and a common pump. Dependence can also be caused by the fact that parts are of the 5220 same design, manufactured by the same company. 5221 5222 Unlikely things happen if enough time passes. An event that has one chance in 20 of happening in any given year (assume that the probability stay the same over time) is nearly certain to happen over 50 years 5223 (92.3%). If we reduce the probability to one chance in 40, the probability of the event happening at least once over 50 years is decreased to 71.8%. 5224 5225 Suppose there are 40 independent ways for a nuclear accident to happen in any given year, each with a probability of 1 in 1000. The probability that an accident happens in any given year is 3.9%. The 5226 probability that at least one nuclear accident happens during the next 10 years is 33%. 5227 5228 We might reduce the probability of accidents, but not eliminate them. 5229 5230 At 3:42pm, San Francisco was shaken by a major earthquake. 5231 5232 Based on frequency and scientific data, scientists estimated in 2003 that there is a 62% probability (the error range could be anywhere from 38 to 87%) of at least one magnitude 6.7 or greater earthquake, 5233 striking somewhere in the Bay region before 2032. The probability of a major earthquake happening in any given year is therefore 3.2% (assuming the probability of a major earthquake happening in any given 5234 year stays the same). The probability that a major earthquake will happen at least once during the next 5 years is 15%. 5235 5236 Regardless of the factors that are considered in predicting earthquakes, chance plays a role in whether a large earthquake happens. 5237 5238 Can we predict the time, location and magnitude of a future earthquake? Berkeley Statistics Professors David Freedman and Philip Stark say in their report What is the chance of an earthquake that a larger 5239 earthquake in the Bay Area is inevitable, and imminent in geologic time: "Probabilities are a distraction. Instead of making forecasts, the USGS [U.S. Geological Survey] could help to improve building codes 5240 and to plan the government's response to the next large earthquake. Bay Area residents should take reasonable precautions, including bracing and bolting their homes as well a securing water heaters, 5241 bookcases, and other heavy objects. They should keep first aid supplies, water, and food at hand. They should largely ignore the USGS probability forecast." 5242 5243 162 5244 5245 "Our technology was foolproof How could this happen?" 5246 5247 Many systems fail because they focus on the machines, not the people that use them. For example, a study of anesthesiologists found that human error was involved in 82% of preventable accidents. The remainder 5248 was due to equipment failure. 5249 5250 Even if the probability that some technology works is 99.99%, human fallibility makes the system less reliable than technological reliability alone. Humans are involved in designing, execution and follow-up. 5251 Excluding ignorance and insufficient knowledge, given the complexity of human and non-human factors interacting, there is a multitude of ways in which things can go wrong. 5252 5253 In 1983 Korean airlines Flight 007 was shot down for into Russian territory for violating Russian air space. All 269 people on board were killed. 5254 5255 The plane had deviated close to 360 miles from its predetermined track. It was later shown that a chain of accidental events led the plane off track. It started when the plane left Anchorage, Alaska. The 5256 captain and crew were tired when the plane took off. A series of small events, each trivial, combined to cause a catastrophe. 5257 5258 "Sorry, I left a metal instrument in your abdomen. " 5259 5260 Doctors sometimes make mistakes - both in diagnosing and treating patients. For example, a surgeon leaving a metal instrument in a patient's abdomen, a patient having the wrong leg amputated, a cardiac 5261 surgeon bypassing the wrong artery, a doctor prescribing the wrong drug, a missed diagnosis of complete heart block, a missed colon cancer, a wrong diagnosis of pulmonary embolism, or a blood product being 5262 mislabeled. 5263 5264 In the Harvard Medical Practice Study (1991), a random sample of 30,000 5265 5266 patients from 51 hospitals in the state of New York was selected. Medical records were examined to detect evidence of injuries caused by medical mismanagement. The study showed that 3.7% of patients 5267 (negligence accounting for 1%) had complications that either prolonged their hospital stay or resulted in disability. Later studies have shown that medical errors account for between 44,000 to 98,000 deaths 5268 in the U.S. every year and that medication errors are the leading eighth cause of death. 5269 5270 A study of 100 cases of diagnostic errors in internal medicine showed that system-related factors contributed in 65% of the cases and cognitive factors in 74%. Cognitive and system-related factors often 5271 co-occurred. The single most common cause of cognitive-based errors was the tendency to stop considering other possible explanations after reaching a diagnosis. 5272 5273 Studies of autopsies show that a U.S. institution with an autopsy rate of 5%, 5274 5275 163 5276 5277 can expect to misdiagnose a principal underlying disease, or the primary cause of death, about 24% of the time. Even a hospital that does autopsies on everyone should expect an error rate of about 8%. 5278 5279 Henry Ford said: "Don't find fault, find a remedy." Don't assign blame. Look for causes and preventive methods. Often it is better to prevent future errors by designing safety into systems than punishing 5280 individuals for past error. Blame does little to improve safety or prevent others from making the same mistake. For example, aviation assumes that errors of judgment happen and that it is better to seek out 5281 causes than assign blame. That is why the Federal Aviation Administration (FM) has an Aviation Safety Reporting System (ASRS) for analyzing and reporting aviation incidents. FM utilizes NASA as a third party 5282 to receive aviation safety reports. This cooperation invites pilots to report to NASA actual or potential deficiencies involving aviation safety. That NASA is the receiver ensures confidentiality and 5283 anonymity of the reporter and all parties involved in an incident. There has been no breach of confidentiality in more than 20 years of the ASRS under NASA management. Pilots who report an incident within ten 5284 days have automatic immunity from punishment. 5285 5286 Safety factor 5287 5288 "We always consider variability and unpredictability when setting safety factors. We act as if we were building a bridge. We are very conservative. " 5289 5290 Ancient Rome used incentives in the design and construction of safe bridges. The designer of the bridge had to stand under it after completion while chariots drove over the top. This put both the designer's 5291 life and those who used the bridge at risk. This increased the probability that designers made sure the bridge held up. Engineers and architects add a safety factor to accommodate uncertainty. This factor 5292 depends on the consequences of failure, how well the risks are understood, 5293 5294 systems characteristics and degree of control. 5295 5296 Assume that accidents will happen and prepare for when people and technology don't work as planned. Systems should be designed to eliminate the probability of bad events or limit their consequences if they 5297 happen. We can borrow an idea from aviation where incidents are thoroughly investigated to learn what went wrong and how to do better next time - critical incident analysis. Ask: How do specific accidents 5298 evolve? What major factors contribute? Are there any common patterns? We need to add a factor of safety for known and unknown risks. We have to consider break points, build in defense systems and contingency 5299 plans. We must also simplify and standardize equipment and processes and use checklists to 5300 5301 decrease the likelihood of operator errors. 5302 5303 164 5304 5305 - SEVEN - 5306 5307 COINCIDENCES AND MIRACLES 5308 5309 Coincidences 5310 5311 The most astonishingly incredible coincidence imaginable would be the complete absence of all coincidences. 5312 5313 - John Allen Paulos (from Beyond Numeracy) 5314 5315 We notice certain things and ignore others. We select and talk about the amazing event, not the ordinary ones. We see coincidences after they happen. We don't see them before they happen. 5316 5317 We underestimate how many opportunities there are for "unlikely" events to happen. Surprises and improbable events happen if they have enough opportunities to happen. There are many ways in which events may 5318 be linked together. 5319 5320 Getting 5 tails in a row is certain to happen somewhere, sometime to someone. The chances may be small that an event happens at a particular place, time or to a particular person. But with many places, over 5321 long periods of time or with many individuals, the seemingly improbable will happen. As Aristotle says: "It is likely that unlikely things should happen." 5322 5323 Someone flips tails 20 times in a row. 5324 5325 Amazing, isn't it? Seen as an isolated event it may seem unlikely. But with a large enough group to choose from, it is likely that it happens to someone. In a group of 1,048,576 people it happens to someone. 5326 In fact, in the U.S. a country with about 280 million people, one in a million chance events happen 280 times a day. 5327 5328 How likely is it that two people share the same birthday? 5329 5330 There are many opportunities for coincidences. For example, in a group of 23 people, the probability is 50.7% that two people share the same birthday. It is rather likely that events like this one happen 5331 since there are many ways that 2 people can share an unspecified birthday. Observe that the question is not how likely it is that 2 people share any particular birthday. The question is whether it is likely 5332 that 2 people share an unspecified birthday. 5333 5334 How many people have to be present at Mary's birthday dinner so there is more 5335 5336 165 5337 5338 than a 50% chance that one of the other guests has the same birthday as Mary? 183, since we now work with the restriction "two people must share a particular birthday." 5339 5340 Scale matters. When the numbers are large enough, improbable things happen. The more available opportunities or the longer the time, unlikely events happen. Ask: What are all possible outcomes and their 5341 likelihood? What else could have happened? 5342 5343 Making up causes for chance events 5344 5345 Humans are pattern seeking, storytelling animals. We look for and find patterns in our world and in our lives, then weave narratives around those patterns to bring them to life and give them meaning. 5346 5347 - Michael Shermer (Publisher of Skeptic) 5348 5349 john tosses a single die six times and the result is either (A) 623514 or (B) 666111. 5350 5351 Which alternative showed the correct outcome? Even if (A) looks random and 5352 5353 looks like it has a pattern, in independent chance events, both A and Bare equally likely or unlikely to appear. Random events may not look random. Independent sequences often show order or streaks. For 5354 example, during the Second World War, people saw a pattern in the German bomb hits of London, expecting some areas more dangerous than others. But they were randomly distributed over London. 5355 5356 We want to find reasons for all kind of events - random or not. We search for patterns even where none exist. For example, there must be something important that is happening if a particular number comes up 5357 again and again. But it is always possible to find patterns and meaning in an event if we actively search for them and selectively pick anything that fits the pattern and ignore everything that doesn't. But 5358 we can't predict the pattern in advance. 5359 5360 John rolls five dice and gets five sixes. 5361 5362 The probability that some roll contains any five specified numbers is very small or one in 7,776 (for example, 6x6x6x6x6). When we toss five dice there are precisely 7,776 different combinations of numbers 5363 that can appear. Every combination is equally likely and one of them is certain to happen every time we roll five dice. Even if one particular combination (five sixes) is improbable, no single combination is 5364 impossible. Any combination that happens is simply one out of a number of equally likely outcomes. It may have been improbable that John rolled five sixes, but not impossible. 5365 5366 166 5367 5368 Anything can happen if the number of possibilities is large. People have seen a human face on Mars, faces in rocks, clouds or even in a grilled cheese sandwich. But that is no mystery. Given the large numbers 5369 of rocks, clouds, and sandwiches, sooner or later we will find one that looks like a face, even a particular face. 5370 5371 Believing in miracles 5372 5373 Impector Gregory: '1s there any point to which you would wish to draw my attention?" Sherlock Holmes: "To the curious incident of the dog in the night-time. " 5374 5375 Inspector Gregoty: "The dog did nothing in the night-time. " 5376 5377 "That was the curious incident,"remarked Sherlock Holmes. 5378 5379 - Arthur Conan Doyle (from Silver Blaze) 5380 5381 Mary thinks about calling her friend Jill. Suddenly the phone rings and it is Jill. 5382 5383 Is something paranormal going on? No, Mary forgot about all the times Jill didn't call when Mary was thinking about her, or the times someone else called, or the times Jill called but Mary wasn't thinking of 5384 her, or the times Jill didn't call when Mary wasn't thinking of her. When Mary thinks about Jill and the phone rings, it registers as an event and something we remember. When Jill doesn't call, it is a 5385 non-event. Nothing happened. Nothing is registered and therefore nothing is remembered. 5386 5387 We often pay little or no attention to times when nothing happens. We shouldn't look at past events and find significance in the amazing ones. We need to make comparisons among cases involving no cause or no 5388 effect and look at all the other things that might have happened instead. 5389 5390 "The psychic predicted the tornado" 5391 5392 Amazing. It sounds too good to be by chance. What we didn't know was that the psychic predicts a tornado every week. As Marcus Tullius Cicero said: "For who can shoot all day without striking the target 5393 occasionally." Often we don't notice the incorrect predictions, only the rare moments when something happens. We forget when they are wrong and only remember when they were right. And many times we want them 5394 to be right, so we hear what we want to hear and fill in the blanks. 5395 5396 "The art of prophecy is very difficult, especially with respect to the future", wrote Mark Twain. This is why it's important to remain skeptical of "future tellers." Their right guesses are highly publicized 5397 but not all their wrong guesses. Like Harvard Professor Theodore Levitt said: "It's easy to be a prophet. You make twenty-five predictions and the ones that come true are the ones you talk about." Michel de 5398 Montaigne adds: "Besides, nobody keeps a record of their erroneous prophecies since they are infinite and everyday." 5399 5400 167 5401 5402 The future-tellers predictions are always far enough in the future that they never have to face the consequences when they're wrong. Or they make their forecasts so general they can apply to anyone or to any 5403 outcome so they can't be proved wrong. 5404 5405 "There is no evidence that ghosts don't exist. " 5406 5407 Some things can't be proven false. The fact that there is no evidence against ghosts isn't the same as confirming evidence that there are ghosts. What is true depends on the amount of evidence supporting it, 5408 not by the lack of evidence against it. 5409 5410 Mary comes home after school and tells John: "My friend Alice witnessed a miracle. " The 18th Century Scottish Philosopher David Hume suggested a test to analyze claims of miraculous events: "No testimony is 5411 sufficient to establish a miracle, unless the testimony be of such a kind, that its falsehood would be more miraculous than the fact which it endeavors to establish." 5412 5413 Hume suggests the following test: If the opposite of a given statement is more 5414 5415 likely, the statement is probably false. Thus, isn't it more likely that the opposite, "Alice didn't witness a miracle" is true? Not because miracles are impossible but because the alternative explanation of 5416 illusion is more probable. How many things that are impossible must happen for a miracle to be true? 5417 5418 The German poet Johann Wolfgang von Goethe said: "Mysteries are not necessarily miracles." That an event can't be explained doesn't mean it is a miracle. No theory can explain everything. As Michael Shermer 5419 says, "My analogy is that the L.A.P.D. [Los Angeles Police Department] can solve, say, 90 percent of annual homicides. Are we to assume that the other 10 percent have supernatural or paranormal causes? No, of 5420 course not, because we all understand that the police cannot solve all murder mysteries." 5421 5422 Bertrand Russell said in A History of Western Philosophy: "Uncertainty, in the presence of vivid hopes and fears, is painful, but must be endured if we wish to live without the support of comforting fairy 5423 tales." 5424 5425 168 5426 5427 - EIGHT - 5428 5429 RELIABILITY OF CASE EVIDENCE 5430 5431 Prior probabilities 5432 5433 At the dinner table john tells Mary: "One of our employees got caught today for stealing, but she said she never did it before and will never do it again. " 5434 5435 How likely is it that she never did it before? Look at the prior probability of stealing, considering for example, the base rate or how typical or representative an event or attribute is. 5436 5437 Charles Munger tells us how John should think: 5438 5439 If you're going to catch 10 embezzlements a year, what are the chances that any one of them - applying what Tversky and Kahneman called base rate information - will be somebody who only did it this once? And 5440 the people who have done it before and are going to do it again, what are they all going to say? Well in the history of the ... Company they always say, "I never did it before, and I'm never going to do it 5441 again." And we cashier them. It would be evil not to, because terrible behavior spreads. 5442 5443 Does eyewitness identification or DNA evidence mean that a person is guilty? Does a positive medical test mean that a person has a disease? 5444 5445 In the eighteenth century, the English mathematician and minister Thomas Bayes laid a foundation for a method of evaluating evidence. The French mathematician Pierre Simon de Laplace brought the method to its 5446 modern form. Bayes' Theorem makes it possible to update the prior probability of an outcome in light of new evidence. It is easier to use if we change probability formats into frequency formats. Let's use 5447 Bayes's Theorem with a modified version of the classic cab problem, 5448 5449 originally developed by the Psychologists Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky. 5450 5451 john testifies in court: '1 witnessed the accident and the cab involved was green. " John's vision has been reliably tested and the tests establish that he can identify the color green correctly 8 out of 10 5452 times. John said "green" in 8 out of 10 cases when something was green and said "green" 2 times out of 10 when something was blue. This means that John misidentified the color 2 out of 10 times. 5453 5454 How trustworthy is John as an eyewitness? A witness testimony always 5455 5456 169 5457 5458 contains a degree of uncertainty. Also remember that the reliability of any observation not only depends on the reliability of the observer - even if John has good eyes - but also on how likely his 5459 observation is true given prior probabilities. First we ask: What is the prior probability ofoutcome- how probable is an event prior to considering the new evidence? How probable is it that a green cab was 5460 involved in an accident before we consider John's evidence? Assume that the relative frequency (the proportion of cabs of a certain color in a particular population at a specific point in time) of blue and 5461 green cabs gives us information about the prior probability of involvement in the accident. What was the proportion of blue and green cabs out of all cabs at the time of the accident? Assume there were a 5462 total of 100 cabs in town. 90 blue and 10 green. This means that the prior probability the 5463 5464 cab involved was green is 10% (10 green cabs out of 100). 5465 5466 What is the (posterior - after considering case evidence) probability the cab was green given that John said it was green? 5467 5468 John says "green" 5469 5470 Given green 5471 5472 8 cabs (IO x 0.8) 5473 5474 Given blue 18 (90 X 0.2) 5475 5476 Total 26 5477 5478 If 10 out of 100 cabs are green and John is right 8 out of 10 times, then he identifies 8 cabs as green. IfJohn says green cab and it is not a green cab then he is likely to identify 18 of the 80 blue cabs as 5479 green. Out of a total of 26 cabs John has identified as green, only 8 are green. This means that the likelihood that the cab was green given John's testimony that "the cab was green" is 31 % (8/26). It seems 5480 the cab involved is more likely to have been blue. 5481 5482 Before John testified the prior probability was only 10% that the cab involved was green. When he testified "green" the probability rose to 31%. 5483 5484 "Based on 50 years of accidents involving cabs, given the same proportion of color, 3 out of 4 times the cab involved was green. " 5485 5486 Independent of the frequency of blue and green cabs, the appropriate prior probability may have been past evidence of accidents. What we want is the correct evidence that is representative for what was likely 5487 to happen before we considered the new evidence. 5488 5489 When we get new representative evidence, we must update the prior probability. Ask: What has happened in similar cases in the past? Are there any reasons this probability should be revised? Have the 5490 circumstances or the environment changed? The more uncertainty that surrounds a specific case, the more emphasis we must put on the prior probability. 5491 5492 170 5493 5494 How strong is the evidence? 5495 5496 One factor when evaluating evidence is the coincidental or random match probability. It answers the question: What is the probability that a person other than the suspect, randomly selected, will match a 5497 certain profile? For example, when evaluating DNA evidence a random match happens when two different people share the same DNA profile. 5498 5499 After five days of searching, the police found the missing woman strangled to death. john's brother, Bill, is on trial for her murder. 5500 5501 There is a DNA profile match. The forensic evidence against Bill is blood and tissue samples taken from the crime scene, which match Bill's. Either Bill left the evidence or someone else did. 5502 5503 What is the probability of a coincidental match? How likely is it that a match occurs between the DNA profile found at the scene of the murder and a randomly chosen person? How likely is it that Bill's 5504 profile matches the profile of the person who did leave the evidence at the crime scene? How rare is this profile? The rarer the profile, the lower the probability that Bill's matches only by chance. The 5505 prosecution's medical expert witness estimates (estimation of the frequency of the profile in the most appropriate comparison population) the probability that there would be such a match if Bill was innocent 5506 and the match was just a coincidence as only 1 in 20,000. This means that out of every 20,000 individuals, only one will have the same DNA profile as the one found at the murder scene. The prosecutor argues: 5507 "There is only a one in 20,000 chance that someone other than Bill would by chance have the same profile as the one found on the murder scene. The probability is therefore only 1 in 20,000 that someone other 5508 than Bill left the evidence. "The figure had a dramatic impact on the media and 5509 5510 the jury. Bill was found guilty and given a life sentence. 5511 5512 Where did justice go wrong? The prosecutor confused two probabilities. The probability that Bill is innocent given a match is not the same as the probability of a match given Bill is innocent. The prosecutor 5513 should have said: "The probability is one in 20,000 that some person other than Bill would leave the same blood and tissue as that found on the crime scene. " 5514 5515 The jury also needs to consider prior (before the evaluation of the forensic evidence is considered) probabilities of guilt. The probability that Bill is the murderer can't only be calculated from the 5516 forensic evidence alone. Other evidence needs to be considered. The significance of forensic evidence always depends on other evidence. What other data do the police have? What else is known about Bill? Does 5517 he have an alibi? Was he near the crime scene? Each piece 5518 5519 171 5520 5521 of evidence must be considered together, and not in isolation. There may also have been a non-criminal explanation of why Bill left the blood and tissue samples. 5522 5523 Based on evidence prior to considering the forensic evidence the jury estimates there is a 10% probability that Bill is the source of the forensic evidence (90% that he is not and thus innocent). The 5524 probability of a match given Bill is guilty is 1 (sensitivity 100% i.e. no false negatives) because if Bill is the source of the forensic evidence and the laboratory test is accurate, his DNA profile will 5525 match. Combining this with the random match probability of one chance in 20,000 (that his DNA profile showed up at the crime scene just by chance) gives a posterior probability that Bill is the source of the 5526 forensic evidence of 99.96% (0.1/0.100045). 5527 5528 Match 5529 5530 Given guilty Given innocent 5531 5532 0.1 (10% X 100%) 0.000045 (90% X 1/20,000) 5533 5534 Total 0.100045 5535 5536 One way of determining the prior probability is by asking: What is the population from which the murderer could have come? We need to know the appropriate comparison population to estimate this number. The 5537 murder has taken place in a city of 500,000 men. Assume any man in the city could have committed the crime. One of them is the murderer. Of the 499,999 people innocent, we can expect about 25 coincidental DNA 5538 matches. This means there are 26 men (25 + the murderer) who could have committed the crime. Since Bill is one of these 26, the probability that he is guilty given the forensic evidence, is only 3.8% (1/26). 5539 5540 But is this really true? It is only true if all men are equally likely to have committed the crime. For example, that they all had the same access to the crime scene. 5541 5542 The choice of appropriate comparison population also matters. How did the expert witness estimate the random match probability? What is the real prevalence of this profile? And does the random match 5543 probability mean that this profile would occur only once in 20,000 individuals? No, the calculated frequency is only an estimate that may be wrong in either direction. 5544 5545 DNA evidence is also easier to plant at a crime scene than for example fingerprints (DNA evidence is easier to manufacture or distort). In Scientific Conversations by Claudia Dreifus, forensic mathematician 5546 Charles Brenner says about the O.J. Simpson case and DNA evidence: "The defense did something very clever from the DNA point of view: They said the evidence was planted. Their basic strategy was even if it 5547 matches, it was a plant. They gave up on the 5548 5549 172 5550 5551 strategy of disproving the DNA evidence. There obviously was a match in the blood. They never denied it." 5552 5553 In the O.J. Simpson trial, the defense argued that fewer than one out of 1,000 wife abusers kill their wives. Therefore evidence of abuse is irrelevant and should not be admissible in a murder trial. But the 5554 appropriate probability is not the probability that a man who abuses his wife kills her. The relevant comparison population to consider is wives who have been abused by their husbands and thereafter been 5555 murdered by someone. The relevant question is therefore: What is the probability that a man killed his wife given that he abused her and given that she was actually killed by someone? And Nicole Brown Simpson 5556 was killed, not just abused. 5557 5558 John Allen Paulos says in Innumeracy that given reasonable facts about murder and abuse, it has been shown that if a man abuses his wife or girlfriend and she is later killed, the abuser is the killer more 5559 than 80 percent of the time. But this doesn't mean that the probability that the husband or boyfriend is guilty of murder is 80%. It is just one piece of evidence among many that needs to be considered. 5560 5561 Do errors happen in testing? 5562 5563 Yes, one type of error is a false positive and another is a false negative. A false positive is akin to a false alarm. A false negative is the missing of a real effect. For example, some factors that can 5564 influence the reliability of medical test results and cause false positives are: the clinical accuracy of the test method (compared with some "gold standard"), patient preparation, medical conditions, 5565 medications and laboratory errors. People may also make errors when collecting and handling samples, in their interpretation of test results or in reporting test results correctly. 5566 5567 john tested positive for a rare disease with a mortality rate of BO%. How scared should he be? 5568 5569 What is the chance that anyone (a person chosen randomly and belonging to the same risk group as John) actually has the disease given that they tested positive? The predictive value of the test depends both 5570 on the clinical accuracy of the test and prior probabilities or the proportion of individuals with the disease in the population we are testing at agiven time (prevalence). Clinical accuracy is composed of 5571 sensitivity (the frequency of positive test that results in positive samples) and 5572 5573 specificity (the frequency of negative test that results in negative samples). 5574 5575 Assume a population of 100,000 people. 5576 5577 The frequency of people with the disease in the population is 0.1 % i.e. one person in 1,000 has the disease. Before the test John had a 0.1% chance of having 5578 5579 173 5580 5581 the disease and a 99.9 % chance of not having the disease. If the test was 100% accurate, 100 people should test positive and 99,900 should test negative. These are the prior probabilities. 5582 5583 The test has a 97% sensitivity or true positive rate. This means that 97 out of 100 people with the disease correctly test positive. It also means that 3 people out of 100 with the disease wrongly test 5584 negative (false negatives). 5585 5586 The test has a 95% specificity or true negative rate. This means that 95 out of 100 people without the disease correctly test negative. 5% of the time the test is incorrect. 5% of the people without the 5587 disease or 4,995 people wrongly test positive (false positives). 5588 5589 Since John is told he tested positive, the information he needs is the frequency of people that test positive and have the disease (true positives) and the frequency of people that test positive but don't 5590 have the disease (false positives). 5591 5592 Test positive 5593 5594 Given disease 97 (100 X 0.97) 5595 5596 Given not disease 4,995 (99,900 X 0.05) 5597 5598 Total 5,092 5599 5600 Out of every 1,000 people belonging to the same risk group as John, we can expect that 19 people have the deadly disease given they test positive (97/5,092). The probability that John has the deadly disease 5601 given he tested positive is about 1.9% or very low. Out of 5,092 tests, most are false positives indicating the disease when there is no disease. 5602 5603 What if a randomly tested person tests negative? There are 3 false negatives and 94,905 true negatives, meaning that there is more than a 99.9% chance that the person doesn't have the disease. 5604 5605 The label "tested positive" can be scary but remember that the test is not the disease. A test could fall in the group of false positives. But which is worst? To belong to the group of false positives - 5606 diagnosed as having the disease without having it, or false negatives - diagnosed as not having the disease but having it? The higher the prior probability or the more common a disease, the more reliable the 5607 outcome of the test. Conversely, the lower the prior probability or the more rare the disease, the less reliable the outcome of the test. Even a highly accurate test can yield an unreliable result if it tests 5608 for a rather uncommon disease. This assumes that the individual tested does not belong to a group of 5609 5610 people at higher risk of having the disease. 5611 5612 Ask: What is the frequency of people with the disease in the relevant comparison population before I consider specific case evidence? How accurate is the medical test? 5613 5614 174 5615 5616 The above reasoning can be used to help evaluate the reliability of diagnostic tests or screening procedures. Some examples are screening for or diagnosis of breast cancer, prostate cancer, colorectal cancer, 5617 HIV or drug use. 5618 5619 Estimating the frequency of false positives and false negatives are also important when evaluating the reliability of polygraph tests (used in criminal investigations or for screening employees) and 5620 identification systems. 5621 5622 In polygraph tests, false positives occur when innocent persons are found deceptive. False negatives occur when guilty persons are found non-deceptive. 5623 5624 In identification systems, a false positive occurs when a system accepts a match where there is none. A false negative occurs when a system fails to recognize a match where there is one. 5625 5626 The probability of false positives is also a factor to consider when evaluating the value of DNA profile evidence. This means that the jury in Bill's case also needs to consider the false positive rate. The 5627 jury needs to ask: What is the probability that the laboratory reports a match between two samples that don't match? A reported match doesn't necessarily mean a true match. Errors happen. A possible 5628 explanation for the forensic match may be error due to contamination (accidental or deliberate), mishandling the evidence, or switching the samples. For example, in one rape case, technicians from the Houston 5629 police crime laboratory told the jury that they found a DNA match between a rapist's DNA and a male suspect. The man was convicted in 1999 and sent to prison for 25 years. In 2003, the Houston Police 5630 Department said that the DNA was not from the convicted man. 5631 5632 When evaluating case evidence we must consider the prior probability, the 5633 5634 probability of a random match, and the probability of a false positive. 5635 5636 175 5637 5638 - NINE - 5639 5640 MISREPRESENTATIVE EVIDENCE 5641 5642 [1mConditions, environments and circumstances change [0mPeople like to look for systems that have worked over the past 20 years or so. Ifyou could make money based on what has worked 5643 5644 the past 20 years, all of the richest people would be librarians. 5645 5646 - Warren Buffett 5647 5648 Bertrand Russell said in [3mProblems of Philosophy: [0m"The man who has fed the chicken every day throughout its life at last wrings its neck instead." Often the past is a good guide to the future - but not always. 5649 Statistics are a record of the past, not a prediction of the future. We can't automatically assume that the future will mirror the past. Processes and circumstances change. Warren Buffett says: "Conditions 5650 relating to technology and all aspects of human behavior can make the future a lot different than the past." 5651 5652 We need to consider changes in conditions before using past evidence to predict likely future outcomes. For example, it's in the nature of businesses and economic conditions to change. Competition and demand 5653 changes. If there are more ways for creating competition or less demand, we have to change the equation. Ask: Why was past experience the way it was? What reason is there to suppose that the future will 5654 resemble the past? Has the environment changed? Are the conditions similar? Are the context and circumstances that caused the past still present? 5655 5656 We also make mistakes if we ignore that past performance may have been achieved under far different circumstances than today. As Warren Buffett says, "The same mistake that a baseball manager would were he to 5657 judge the future prospects of a 42-year-old center fielder on the basis of his lifetime batting average." Management performance may also be conditioned on environment. What makes an individual successful in 5658 one environment does not guarantee success in 5659 5660 another. Ask: What is the company's or manager's ability to handle adversity? 5661 5662 "We can sell more if we market the illness rather than the drug,"said the manager of TransCorp's pharmaceutical division. 5663 5664 Is the frequency of a disease really increasing? We need to consider other factors 5665 5666 176 5667 5668 before we conclude that the frequency of an event has changed. For example, a disease may be more correctly diagnosed than it was in the past. Often we only see what we have names for - a disease that was 5669 formerly classified as "disease X" or "cause unknown" may now be re-classified or get a name. There may also be technological improvements in the collection and reporting of data. There may also be business 5670 incentives at work. For example, widening a market by creating a new condition, redefining adisease or exaggerating a minor one, thereby having more people labeled as having a disease. 5671 5672 If conditions change, we must update our assumptions to reflect the present 5673 5674 environment. Before we use the change as evidence for what is likely to happen, ask: What has changed? Are there more ways for some undesirable event to happen? Is the change permanent or temporary? 5675 5676 The single case or unrepresentative samples 5677 5678 Four out of five doctors recommend the drug. 5679 5680 This statement doesn't tell us anything if we don't know how many doctors were observed. Maybe it was just 1O; an observation that can't be extrapolated to include all doctors. A small sample size has no 5681 predictive value. The smaller the sample is, the more statistical fluctuations and the more likely it is that we find chance events. We need a representative comparison group, large enough sample size, and 5682 long enough periods of time. 5683 5684 Small samples can cause us to believe a risk is lower or higher than reality. Why? A small sample increases the chance that we won't find a particular relationship where it exists or find one where it doesn't 5685 exist. 5686 5687 Charles Munger gives an example of the importance of getting representative data - even if it's approximate: 5688 5689 The water system of California was designed looking at a fairly short period of weather history. If they'd been willing to take less perfect records and look an extra hundred years back, they'd have seen that 5690 they weren't designing it right to handle drought conditions which were entirely likely. 5691 5692 You see that again and again - that people have some information they can count well and they have other information much harder to count. So they make the decision based only on what they can count well. And 5693 they ignore much more important information because its quality in terms of numeracy is less - even though it's very important in terms of reaching the right cognitive result. All I can tell you is that 5694 around Wesco and Berkshire, we try not to be like that. We have Lord Keynes' attitude, which Warren quotes all the time: "We'd rather be roughly right than precisely wrong." In other words, if something 5695 5696 177 5697 5698 is terribly important, we'll guess at it rather than just make our judgment based on what happens to be easily countable. 5699 5700 Chance and performance 5701 5702 No victor believes in chance. 5703 5704 - Friedrich Wilhelm Nietzsche 5705 5706 Past performance is no guarantee of future results. Consider evidence that describes what happens in most similar situations or to most people. 5707 5708 Sometimes a track record is not a good indicator of what is likely to happen in the future. It may show up by luck. Imagine a room filled with 1,000 monkeys. Each is trying to predict the direction (up or 5709 down) of interest rates. At the end of 10 predictions, one monkey has a perfect record of predicting the direction of interest rates. He is considered agenius and the greatest economist in history. Even if it 5710 was just by chance. As soon as we have a large population of forecasters that predict events where chance plays a role, someone will be right, get press coverage and be presented as a hero. He will hold 5711 lectures and give sensible explanations. 5712 5713 Sometimes we only see the good performers. Partly because winners have a tendency to show up (one monkey). Losers don't (999 monkeys). Often we aren't interested in the losers anyway. But we shouldn't be 5714 amazed to see winners if there is a large population to choose from. 10,000 monkeys and we find 10 geniuses. When we measure performance we must consider both the number of successes (one monkey), the number 5715 of failures (999 monkeys), and the size of the relevant comparison population they came from (1,000 monkeys). The more people (or monkeys), involved in something where chance plays a role, the more likely it 5716 is that some people have great performances just by chance. An exception is in a group of high performers where we can observe some common 5717 5718 characteristics that may be a causal factor and not luck. 5719 5720 The same mistakes may happen when people base their conclusions on mere effects and ignore the influence of chance. Think about 100 monkeys. They each roll a die once. Select those 16 monkeys (1/6x100) who 5721 rolled a six. As a cure for their "roll-a-six" tendency we give them a new drug. After taking the drug they roll the die again. Now only 2 or 3 monkeys (1/6x16) rolled a six. The rest were "cured." Our false 5722 conclusion: "The drug obviously worked." 5723 5724 A con artist sets up a trap. He calls John with a tip. "Watch this stock. It will go up." After 3 correct predictions, John sends him his money. The con artist disappears. 5725 5726 What John didn't know was that the con artist made the same call to 80 people. 5727 5728 178 5729 5730 He told half of them the stock would go up, and the other half the stock would go down. And one of his predictions is sure to be right. 40 people were impressed. At the second call 20 people were impressed 5731 and at his third and last call he was considered a genius by 10 people who all sent him their money. 5732 5733 Ignoring failures 5734 5735 Evidence must be drawn from the frequency of both success and failure over time. Often we only consider the successful and supporting outcomes. The epidemiological literature refers to this as survival bias. 5736 Only the characteristics of the survivors of a disease or outcome under study are included in the study. Those who have died before the end of the study are excluded. If these are patients with more severe 5737 risk factors, the study reduces an apparent association between risk factors and outcomes. Survival bias is also common in all studies made after the outcomes have occurred (including back testing). They only 5738 focus on surviving cases or patients. The people who have died are not in the sampling pool. People may also select or omit certain information by only publishing positive outcomes and omitting negative ones. 5739 5740 If we only study successes or survivors, a performance record may look better than it really is. Charles Munger says that we give too little attention to failures: 5741 5742 It is assumed by many business school graduates, and by almost all consultants, that a corporation can easily improve its outcome by purchasing unrelated or tenuously related businesses. According to this 5743 widely shared view, if only the obvious steps had been taken, if the right "mission statement" had been adopted and the right "experts" hired, then each railroad, instead of remaining bound in chains by new 5744 forms of competition and obsolete and hostile laws and union rules, would have become another Federal Express, another United Parcel Service, or even another brilliant performer in the mode of Emerson 5745 Electric. 5746 5747 Our experience, both actual and vicarious, makes us less optimistic about easy solutions through business acquisition. We think undue optimism arises because successful records draw too much attention. Many 5748 people then reason as I would ifl forecasted good prospects in big-time tennis after observation limited to Ivan Lendl and Steffi Graf, or good prospects in the California lottery after limiting observations 5749 to winners. The converse is also true, only more so. Far too little attention is given to the terrible effects on shareholders (or other owners) of the worst examples of corporate acquisitions such as 5750 CBS-DuMont, Xerox-Scientific Data Systems, General Electric-Utah International, Exxon-Reliance Electric... and Avon Products. 5751 5752 In 1999, people said: ''internet businesses are doing great. " 5753 5754 Often we see only the businesses that do well and ignore the failures. Especially 5755 5756 179 5757 5758 in bull markets where successes get wide publicity. Ask: What is the relevant comparison population from which we measure 5-year performance (assume 100 Internet businesses)? How many are doing well (assume 5759 5). How many are not performing well (assume 80). How many have gone out of business (assume 15). From this we can draw the conclusion that the above statement is false. 5760 5761 TransCorps technical department developed a new defense system and claims a success rate of80%. WhenJohn observed IO tests, he witnessed 8 failures and only 2 successes. In 1992, Theodore Postal, a professor 5762 of science and national security at MIT, measured the effectiveness (not in terms of its psychological and political impact) of the Patriot anti-missile system in the Gulf War. Based on studying videotapes of 5763 26 Patriot/Scud engagements involving 25 misses and 1 hit, he told the Committee on Government Operations that, "the video evidence makes an overwhelming circumstantial case that Patriot did not come dose to 5764 achieving a 80 percent intercept rate in Saudi Arabia." The Pentagon reported firing 47 Patriot missiles at Scuds, at first claiming an 80% success rate. A congressional report later concluded that Patriots 5765 succeeded in downing only 4 Scuds. 5766 5767 If we assume that John's observations represent a valid random sample of tests, 5768 5769 how likely is it that he would observe exactly 2 "hits" and 8 "misses" if the technical department's claim was true? 5770 5771 This is an example of a binomial experiment. It describes experiments with repeated, identical trials where each trial can only have two possible outcomes (e.g. success or failure). Assuming independent 5772 engagements, the probability is only 0.007%. If the departments claim was true, then John witnessed an event of a very low probability. It is more likely that their claim was false. 5773 5774 Variability 5775 5776 You can, for example, never foretell what any man will do, but you can say with precision what an average number will be up to. Individuals vary, but percentages remain constant. So says the statistician. 5777 5778 - Arthur Conan Doyle (from The Sign of Four) 5779 5780 When evaluating likely outcomes, look at the whole distribution of possible outcomes 5781 5782 - average outcome, variability, and the probability of an extreme outcome and its consequences. What we mean by variability is how much the individual outcomes are spread out from the average outcome. The 5783 more spread out, the more variability. Ask: What has happened in the past? How much do the outcomes fluctuate around the average? What factors contribute to past variability? Have they changed? 5784 5785 180 5786 5787 The normal distribution curve shows a frequency distribution of outcomes and may sometimes help us find the most frequent outcomes and the variations. There are many ways a set of outcomes can be spread out 5788 or distributed. But some outcomes are more frequent than others. Many characteristics resulting from independent random factors have a bell-shaped frequency distribution. This means that the most frequent 5789 outcomes will be in the middle of the distribution, and the other outcomes will fall on either side of the middle. The 5790 5791 further away any outcome is from the middle, the less frequent it is. 5792 5793 Examples of normally distributed outcomes are heights or weights of adults (which depend on factors such as genes, diet, or environment), temperatures, car accidents, mortality rates, or the length of life of 5794 a light bulb. 5795 5796 What is the average height of female adults? 5797 5798 If we randomly select one thousand adult females and measure their height, we end up with a distribution of outcomes that look like a bell-shaped curve. Their heights will center around their average height, 5799 and the breadth of the curve indicates how variable around this average the heights are. Adding one extremely tall woman to a large sample doesn't really change the average height. 5800 5801 The same reasoning can be applied to an auto insurance company. The more of the same game the insurance company plays, the better the average becomes as a guide. Adding an extremely expensive car accident 5802 doesn't really change this. The average is representative and has predictive power. 5803 5804 But we can't use the normal distribution curve for those classes of insurance that involve mammoth and unusual risks. For an insurance company specializing in insuring unique events, the possible variability 5805 in outcomes is key. 5806 5807 TransCorp's new computer software grabbed 90% of the market. 5808 5809 In many cases, the normal distribution curve may not give us a true picture of reality. One single favorable or unfavorable extreme event can have a large impact and dramatically change the averages. We saw 5810 examples of this uneven type of distribution earlier with size and frequency. The less number of times or the shorter the time or the more impact a single event may have on the average, the more important it 5811 is to consider the variability, and the more unpredictable some factor becomes. For example, suppose the average sales of books are 5812 5813 $200,000. But if our sample contains one extreme best-seller (the Harry Potter 5814 5815 books), the average will not help us predict what a new book on average may sell for. Other examples are movie sales (the movie Titanic), price changes in financial markets (a sudden large depreciation of a 5816 currency, damages from 5817 5818 181 5819 5820 hurricanes (Katrina), or impact from innovations (TransCorp's new software). For example, there is no typical software and past averages don't mean anything. We see what has happened in the measured past. We 5821 don't know what the biggest hurricane will be or its likelihood of occurring. When we look back, we 5822 5823 only see what the biggest hurricane was in the documented past. 5824 5825 We can't use past statistics to predict these rare and high-impact events. We don't know their timing, frequency, or degree of impact. We can't exactly figure out their properties or develop a formula. We 5826 only know that they happen and that they can have a huge impact. In some cases, we may have some evidence telling us if the probabilities are changing. Also, many events are not independent but are instead 5827 interconnected. Financial markets are one example; markets have memories, assets may be correlated and one bad event may cause another. The danger of using the normal distribution curve in cases where one 5828 huge event can dramatically change reality is well described at length by the Epistemologist of Randomness Nassim Nicholas Taleb in his book The Black Swan. 5829 5830 10 people have a total wealth of$10 million i.e. the average wealth per person is $1 million. 5831 5832 What if one person has $10 million and nine nothing? How can the average 5833 5834 income soar? Suppose ten middle-class people are riding on a bus. One gets off the bus and a billionaire gets on. 5835 5836 John has an option to play one of two games. Each game has three equally likely outcomes. The game may be one of chance, insurance, investing, etc. 5837 5838 Outcomes Average outcome 5839 5840 Probability 5841 5842 Expected value 5843 5844 Gamel 5845 5846 30 40 50 5847 5848 40 5849 5850 1/3 1/3 1/3 5851 5852 40 5853 5854 Game2 5855 5856 0 20 100 5857 5858 40 5859 5860 1/3 1/3 1/3 5861 5862 40 5863 5864 If he plays each game over and over, the expected value is 40 for both, so it shouldn't matter what game he chooses to play. But what about ifJohn only plays this game once? He should play game 1 since it has 5865 less variability. 5866 5867 john has been offered to invest in a private venture capital fond. The venture manager's track record is an average rate of return of 25% over the last five years. 5868 5869 This doesn't say much if we don't look at how the underlying performance was produced. By looking closely at how this return was produced John found that the venture manager had done 10 deals. One deal had 5870 been a spectacular success 5871 5872 182 5873 5874 and the rest failures. Had this one deal been due to luck? 5875 5876 Remember that some people leave out data when reporting their performance. 5877 5878 Mary reads in the paper that the average price of a house is $1,000,000. 5879 5880 But this may cause her to get a false picture of reality. Assume there are 100 houses and 90 of them are priced at $500,000 and 10 "castles" at $5.5 million. We have to watch out for the variations. 5881 5882 A business executive tells us that his company had average earnings of $50 million over the last 3 years. But when we look closer we find great variability and a downward trend in the performance record: 5883 1998: $100 million, 1999: $50 million, 2000: $0. 5884 5885 The median is the middle of a distribution where half the outcomes are above the median and half below. If 9 people have $1 million each and one has $1 billion, the average wealth is about $101 million, but 5886 the median amount is $1 million. 5887 5888 In 1982, Stephen jay Gould was diagnosed with a rare and deadly form of cancer with a median mortality of 8 months after discovery. He beat the cancer for 20 years. Does an 8 month median mortality mean that 5889 a person will be dead in 8 months? Gould learned that an 8 month median mortality means half the people die before 8 months and half will live longer. But he found that there was a wider spread of outcomes 5890 after 8 months than before. This makes sense since there is a lower limit to the spread of outcomes during an 8 month period than after 8 months. No person will die before the start of the 8 month period but 5891 those who survive can live considerably longer than 8 months. We can't treat the average or the median as the most likely outcome for any single individual. Look at the variation between all outcomes. This 5892 means that a treatment ought to be determined based on whether an individual is likely to have an outcome better or worse than the median. 5893 5894 Effects of regression 5895 5896 "Regression to the mean" is a notion worked out by Sir Francis Galton (Charles Darwin's first cousin). It says that, in any series of events where chance is involved, very good or bad performances, high or 5897 low scores, extreme events, etc. tend on the average, to be followed by more average performance or less extreme events. If we do extremely well, we're likely to do worse the next time, while if we do poorly, 5898 we're likely to do better the next time. But regression to the mean is not a natural law. Merely a statistical tendency. And it may take a long time before it happens. 5899 5900 183 5901 5902 Dissatisfied with the new employees' performance, John put them into a skill enhancing program. He measures the employees' skills at the end of the program. 5903 5904 Their scores are now higher than they were on the first test. John's conclusion: "The skill-enhancing program caused the improvement in skill." This isn't necessarily true. Their higher scores could be the 5905 result of regression to the mean. Since these individuals were measured as being on the low end of the scale of skill, they would have shown an improvement even if they hadn't taken the skill-enhancing 5906 program. And there could be many reasons for their earlier performance - stress, fatigue, sickness, distraction, etc. Their true ability perhaps hasn't changed. 5907 5908 Our performance always varies around some average true performance. Extreme performance tends to get less extreme the next time. Why? Testing measurements can never be exact. All measurements are made up of 5909 one true part and one random error part. When the measurements are extreme, they are likely to be partly caused by chance. Chance is likely to contribute less on the second time we measure performance. 5910 5911 If we switch from one way of doing something to another merely because we 5912 5913 are unsuccessful, it's very likely that we do better the next time even if the new way of doing something is equal or worse. 5914 5915 Part Two and Three dealt with reasons for misjudgments and ideas for reducing them. Before we enter Part Four let's conclude with how we can learn from past mistakes. 5916 5917 Post Mortem 5918 5919 Spanish-American philosopher George Santayana once said: "Those who cannot remember the past are condemned to repeat it." How can we understand what is happening to us without any reference to the past? We 5920 conveniently forget to record our mistakes. But they should be highlighted. We should confess our errors and learn from them. We should look into their causes and take steps to prevent them from happening 5921 again. Ask: 5922 5923 What was my original reason for doing something? What did I know and what were my assumptions? What were my alternatives at the time? 5924 5925 How did reality work out relative to my original guess? What worked and what didn't? 5926 5927 Given the information that was available, should I have been able to predict what was going to happen? 5928 5929 What worked well? What should I do differently? What did I fail to do? What did I miss? What must I learn? What must I stop doing? 5930 5931 184 5932 5933 Why don't we do post mortems? Charles Munger says: 5934 5935 You tend to forget your own mistakes when reputation is threatened by remembering. For that very reason, one very wise company - Johnson & Johnson - has a system whereby two years or so after they've made 5936 some big acquisition they have a post-mortem. And they bring back the original projections and the original reasons for doing the deal. They identify the people who made the arguments and what have you. Then 5937 they compare them with how the deal worked out. 5938 5939 Warren Buffett says that, "Triumphs are trumpeted, but dumb decisions either get no follow-up or are rationalized." He continues: 5940 5941 Managers tend to be reluctant to look at the results of the capital projects or the acquisitions that they proposed with great detail only a year or two earlier to a board. And they don't want to actually 5942 stick the figures up there as to how the reality worked out relative to the projections. That's human nature. 5943 5944 But I think you're a better doctor if you drop by the pathology department occasionally. And I think you're a better manager or investor if you look at each decision that you've made of importance and see 5945 which ones worked out and which ones didn't - and figure your batting average. Then, if your batting average gets too bad, you better hand the decision-making over to someone else. 5946 5947 We could also use pre-mortems to help us anticipate problems and key vulnerabilities. For example, before making an important decision, imagine a failure where things really have gone wrong and ask: What 5948 could have caused this? 5949 5950 What guidelines and tools are there to better thinking? Charles Munger gives us some introductory remarks for Part Four: 5951 5952 Berkshire is basically a very old-fashioned kind of a place and we try to exert discipline to stay that way. I don't mean old-fashioned stupid. I mean the eternal verities: basic mathematics, basic horse 5953 sense, basic fear, basic diagnosis of human nature making possible predictions regarding human behavior. If you just do that with a certain amount of discipline, I think it's likely to work out quite well. 5954 5955 185 5956 5957 - PART FOUR - 5958 5959 [1mGUIDELINES TO BETTER THINKING [0m 5960 5961 The brain can be developed just the same way as the muscles can be developed, if one will only take the pains to train the mind to think. 5962 5963 - Thomas Alva Edison (American inventor, 1847-1931) 5964 5965 187 5966 5967 - ONE - 5968 5969 Sun Tzu said in [3mThe Art of War: [0m"The general who wins a battle makes many calculations in his temple before the battle is fought." 5970 5971 The purpose of this part is to explore tools that provide a foundation for rational thinking. Ideas that help us when achieving goals, explaining "why," preventing and reducing mistakes, solving problems, and 5972 evaluating statements. 5973 5974 The following 12 tools will be discussed. 5975 5976 Models of reality. 5977 5978 Meaning. 5979 5980 Simplification. 5981 5982 Rules and filters. 5983 5984 Goals. 5985 5986 Alternatives. 5987 5988 Consequences. 5989 5990 Quantification. 5991 5992 Evidence. 5993 5994 Backward thinking. 5995 5996 Risk. 5997 5998 Attitudes. 5999 6000 MODELS OF REALITY 6001 6002 Educated men are as superior to uneducated men as the living are to the dead. 6003 6004 -Aristotle 6005 6006 Learn, understand and use the big ideas and general principles that explain a lot about how the world works. When Charles Munger was asked what would be the best question he should ask himself, he said: 6007 6008 Ifyou ask not about investment matters, but about your personal lives, I think the best question is, "Is there anything I can do to make my whole life and my whole mental process work better?" 6009 6010 189 6011 6012 And I would say that developing the habit of mastering the multiple models which underlie reality is the best thing you can do.. .It's just so much fun - and it works so well. 6013 6014 A model is an idea that helps us better understand how the world works. Models illustrate consequences and answer questions like "why" and "how". Take the model of social proof as an example. What happens? 6015 When people are uncertain they often automatically do what others do without thinking about the correct thing to do. This idea helps explain "why" and predict "how" people are likely to behave in certain 6016 situations. 6017 6018 Models help us avoid problems. Assume that we are told that the earth consists of infinite resources. By knowing the idea about limits, we know the statement is false. Someone gives us an investment proposal 6019 about a project that contradicts the laws of physics. How much misery can be avoided by staying away from whatever doesn't make scientific sense? 6020 6021 What characterizes a useful model? 6022 6023 If a model agrees with reality, it is most likely true. One idea from biology that agrees with reality is that "people on average act out of self-interest." But not the idea that "people's personalities can 6024 be evaluated by using the Rorschach ink-blot test." It can't predict people's personalities. Ask: What is the underlying big idea? Do I understand its application in practical life? Does it help me understand 6025 the world? How does it work? Why does it work? Under what conditions does it work? How reliable is it? What are its limitations? How does it relate to other models? 6026 6027 Charles Munger gives an example of a useful idea from chemistry - autocatalysis: 6028 6029 If you get a certain kind of process going in chemistry, it speeds up on its own. So you get this marvelous boost in what you're trying to do that runs on and on. Now, the laws of physics are such that it 6030 doesn't run on [3mforever. [0mBut it runs on for a goodly while. So you get a huge boost. You accomplish A- and, all of a sudden, you're getting A+ B + C for awhile. 6031 6032 He continues telling us how this idea can be applied: 6033 6034 Disney is an amazing example of autocatalysis ... They had all those movies in the can. They owned the copyright. And just as Coke could prosper when refrigeration came, when the videocassette was invented, 6035 Disney didn't have to invent anything or do anything except take the thing out of the can and stick it on the cassette. 6036 6037 190 6038 6039 Which models are most reliable? Charles Munger answers: 6040 6041 The models that come from hard science and engineering are the most reliable models on this Earth. And engineering quality control - at least the guts of it that matters to you and me and people who are not 6042 professional engineers - is very much based on the elementary mathematics of Fermat and Pascal: It costs so much and you get so much less likelihood of it breaking if you spend this much ... 6043 6044 And, of course, the engineering idea of a backup system is a very powerful idea. The engineering idea ofbreakpoints- that's avery powerful model, too. The notion of a critical mass - that comes out of physics 6045 - is a very powerful model. 6046 6047 A valuable model produces meaningful explanations and predictions oflikely future consequences where the cost of being wrong is high. 6048 6049 A model should be easy to use. If it is complicated, we don't use it. 6050 6051 It is useful on a nearly daily basis. If it is not used, we forget it. And what use is knowledge if we don't use it? 6052 6053 Considering many ideas help us achieve a holistic view 6054 6055 Those who love wisdom must be inquirers into many things indeed. 6056 6057 Heraclitus 6058 6059 What can help us see the big picture? How can we consider many aspects of an issue? Use knowledge and insights from many disciplines. Most problems need to be studied from a variety of perspectives. Charles 6060 Munger says, "In most messy human problems, you have to be able to use all the big ideas and not just a few of them." 6061 6062 The world is multidisciplinary. Physics doesn't explain everything; neither does biology or economics. For example, in a business it is useful to know how scale changes behavior, how systems may break, how 6063 supply influences prices, and how incentives cause behavior. 6064 6065 Since no single discipline has all the answers, we need to understand and use the big ideas from all the important disciplines - mathematics, physics, chemistry, engineering, biology, psychology, and rank and 6066 use them in order of their reliability. Charles Munger illustrates the importance of this: 6067 6068 Suppose you want to be good at declarer play in contract bridge. Well, you know the contract - you know what you have to achieve. And you can count up the sure winners you have by laying down your high cards 6069 and your invincible trumps. 6070 6071 191 6072 6073 But if you're a trick or two short, how are you going to get the other needed tricks? Well, there are only six or so different, standard methods: You've got long-suit establishment. You've got finesses. 6074 You've got throw-in plays. You've got cross-ruffs. You've got squeezes. And you've got various ways of misleading the defense into making errors. So it's a very limited number of models. But if you only know 6075 one or two of those models, then you're going to be a horse's patoot in declarer play... 6076 6077 If you don't have the full repertoire, I guarantee you that you'll overutilize the limited 6078 6079 repertoire you have - including use of models that are inappropriate just because they're available to you in the limited stock you have in mind. 6080 6081 Suppose we have a problem and ask: What can explain this? How can we achieve this? How can we then use different ideas? Charles Munger tells us how to do it: 6082 6083 Have a full kit of tools... go through them in your mind checklist-sryle... you can never make any explanation that can be made in a more fundamental way in any other way than the most fundamental way. And 6084 you always take with full attribution to the most fundamental ideas that you are required to use. When you're using physics, you say you're using physics. When you're using biology, you say you're using 6085 biology. 6086 6087 We also need to understand how different ideas interact and combine. Charles Munger says: 6088 6089 You get lollapalooza effects when two, three or four forces are all operating in the same direction. And, frequently, you don't get simple addition. It's often like a critical mass in physics where you get a 6090 nuclear explosion if you get to a certain point of mass - and you don't get anything much worth seeing if you don't reach the mass. 6091 6092 Sometimes the forces just add like ordinary quantities and sometimes they combine on a break-point or critical-mass basis... More commonly, the forces coming out of... models are conflicting to some extent. 6093 And you get huge, miserable trade-offs ... So you [must] have the models and you [must] see the relatedness and the effects from the relatedness. 6094 6095 The British mathematician and philosopher Alfred North Whitehead said: "The problem of education is to make the pupil see the wood by means of the trees." We need to consider many aspects of an issue and 6096 synthesize and integrate them. We need to understand how it all fits together to form a coherent whole. The term synthesis comes from classical Greek and means literally "to put together." Below are some 6097 examples of how this can be used in problem-solving. 6098 6099 192 6100 6101 We can combine ideas within a discipline. We saw in Part Two how psychological tendencies can combine and give Lollapalooza effects. 6102 6103 We can try to find connections between ideas or derive new ideas from these connections. The modern evolutionary synthesis was a unification of several ideas within biology. 6104 6105 We can combine ideas from different disciplines. The ideas of scaling from mathematics, systems and constraints from physics, and competitive advantage from microeconomics often explain how business value is 6106 created or destroyed. 6107 6108 We can try to see relationships between phenomena, and try to find one principle that can explain them all. The British physicist James Clark Maxwell combined in one model the laws of electricity and 6109 magnetism with the laws of behavior of light. This single model explained optical, electrical and magnetic phenomena. 6110 6111 We can find similarities or functional equivalents within or between disciplines. The functional equivalent of viscosity from chemistry is stickiness in economics. 6112 6113 How can we learn an idea so it sticks in our memory? 6114 6115 Samuel Johnson said: "He is a benefactor of mankind who contracts the great rules of life into short sentences, that may be easily impressed on the memory, and so recur habitually to the mind." 6116 6117 Richard Feynman answered the following question in one of his physics lectures: 6118 6119 If, in some cataclysm, all of scientific knowledge were to be destroyed, and only one sentence passed on to the next generations of creatures, what statement would contain the most information in the fewest 6120 words? I believe it is the atomic hypothesis (or the atomic fact, or whatever you wish to call it) that all things are made ofatoms - little particles that move around in perpetual motion, attracting each 6121 other when they area little distance apart, but repelling upon being squeezed into one another. In that one sentence, you will see, there is an enormous amount of information about the world, if just a little 6122 imagination and thinking are applied. 6123 6124 We can use the Feynman "one sentence explanation" when dealing with big ideas. "What sentence contains the most information in the fewest words?" An example of a one-sentence idea from psychology is: "We get 6125 what we reward for." A sentence from physics is: "Energy is neither created nor destroyed - only changed from one form into another." 6126 6127 Another way to understand a model is to give it a "hook." Associate the model with a dramatic real-life story, analogy, individual, or picture. For example to 6128 6129 193 6130 6131 remember social proof, we can think about the Genovese homicide in New York City (see Part Two). 6132 6133 A Chinese proverb says, "I forget what I hear; I remember what I see; I know what I do." Since the best way to learn something is by doing it, we must apply models routinely to different situations. Like any 6134 skill, this takes both practice and discipline. 6135 6136 Search for explanations 6137 6138 What happens and why does it happen? 6139 6140 One way of forcing us to learn models to better deal with reality is to open our eyes and look at the things we see around us and ask "why" things are happening (or why things are not happening). Take some 6141 simple examples as "why do apples fall downward?" or "why do we fall down when we slip?" or "why don't we fall off the earth?" The English mathematician and physicist Sir Isaac Newton's law of gravitation can 6142 explain this. 6143 6144 Newton's 1st law tells us that an object in motion tends to continue in motion at a steady speed in a straight line, and an object at rest tends to stay at rest, unless the object is acted upon by an outside 6145 force. 6146 6147 This means that there are only 3 ways to change an object: an object at rest can start to move, an object in motion at a steady speed can go up or down in speed, and an object in motion in a straight line can 6148 change direction. And what is needed to change an object's motion? A force. 6149 6150 All change in motion happens in response to the action of force(s). By forces, we mean a push or a pull that acts on an object. When we open a door or throw a baseball, we are using forces (muscular effort). 6151 Almost everything we do involves forces. 6152 6153 Newton's 2nd law tells us that force is the product of mass and acceleration. Acceleration is any change in speed and/or direction. It depends on the mass (measures an object power to resist change in its 6154 state of motion) of an object and the magnitude and direction of the force acting on it. The more force we use at a given mass, the greater the acceleration. But the more mass, the more an object resists 6155 acceleration. For example, the more force we use to throw a baseball, the greater the acceleration of the ball. If we increase mass, we have to add more force to produce the same rate of acceleration. 6156 6157 Newton's 3rd law is that forces work in pairs. One object exerts a force on a second object, but the second object also exerts a force equal and opposite in direction to the force acting on it - the first 6158 object. As Newton said in Philosophiae Natura/is Principia Mathematica: "If you press a stone with your 6159 6160 194 6161 6162 finger, the finger is also pressed by the stone." If we throw a baseball, the ball also "throws" us or pushes back on our hand with the same force. 6163 6164 Now we come to the force of gravity. Influenced by Johannes Kepler's work on planetary motion and Galileo Galilei's work on freely falling objects, Newton found out that there was a force that attracts two 6165 objects to each other. Two factors influence the degree of attraction. Mass and distance. The greater the mass of two objects or the closer the distance between them, the greater the attraction between them. 6166 This also means that the greater the distance between the objects, the weaker the force of gravity. If we for example double the distance, the force is as fourth as strong. 6167 6168 Mathematically we can state the force of attraction or gravitation as equal to the mass of one object multiplied with the mass of the other object divided by the square of the distance between the objects. 6169 All this is multiplied with a constant (a number that doesn't change in value)-g (9.8 meters per second each second or 9.8m/s2 ). We can call g, the acceleration of gravity near the surface of the Earth. 6170 6171 It is the force ofgravity that makes an apple fall toward the Earth. 6172 6173 The Earth attracts the apple with a force that is proportional to its mass and inversely proportional to the square of the distance between them. But Newton's third law says that the apple also exerts an 6174 equal and opposite force on the Earth. The force of attraction on the apple by the Earth is the same as the force of attraction on the Earth by the apple. So even if it looks to us like the apple falls to the 6175 Earth, both the Earth and apple fall toward each other. The force is the same but as we see from Newton's second law, not the acceleration. Their masses differ. The Earth's mass is so large compared to the 6176 apple that we see the apple "falling." Apples fall, starting at rest, to the Earth since they have less mass than the Earth, meaning they accelerate (change speed) more toward the Earth than the Earth does 6177 toward the apple. The Earth's great mass also explains why we fall toward the Earth when we slip. 6178 6179 The same force draws the Moon to the Earth. But what keeps the Moon in orbit around the Earth instead of crashing into the Earth? 6180 6181 Newton knew that there must be some force pulling the Moon toward the Earth. Otherwise according to the 1st law the Moon would continue in motion in a straight line at a steady speed instead of its more 6182 elliptical motion. Some force must continuously pull the Moon out of its straight-line motion and change its direction. And since the Moon's orbit is circular, this force must originate from the center of the 6183 Earth. Why? Newton knew that a centripetal force (any force 6184 6185 195 6186 6187 directed toward a fixed center) controls objects going in a circle around a fixed point. 6188 6189 That force is gravity. It changes the Moons acceleration by continually changing its direction toward the center of the Earth causing the Moon to curve into circular motion. As the Moon moves horizontally in 6190 a direction tangent (the straight line that touches a curve) to the Earth, at each point along its path, gravity pulls it inward toward the center of the Earth and the result is a Moon in circular orbit. 6191 6192 The Moon's speed is great enough to ensure that its falling distance matches the Earth's curvature. The Moon remains at the same distance above Earth since the Earth curves at the same rate as the Moon 6193 "falls." By the time the Moon has fallen a certain distance toward Earth, it has moved sideways about the same distance. If its speed were much lower, the pull of gravity would gradually force the Moon 6194 6195 closer to the Earth until they crash into each other. If its speed where much higher, 6196 6197 the Moon would escape the force of gravity and move away from us. 6198 6199 The Moon doesn't accelerate as much as the apple, because of its distance to Earth (the force of gravity is weaker). The Moon in its orbit is about sixty times as far away from the Earth's center as the apple 6200 is. 6201 6202 Newton's law of gravitation isn't enough to describe the motion of objects whose speed is near the speed oflight. Why? According to Albert Einstein's theory of relativity, the mass of an object is not a 6203 constant. It increases as its speed approaches the speed oflight. Newton's theories and the theory of relativity also differ when gravitational fields are much larger than those found on Earth. Under most 6204 conditions, though, Newton's laws and his theory of gravitation are adequate. 6205 6206 The relative influence of gravity varies with size and scale. 6207 6208 Why does falling.from a high tree not harm an insect? 6209 6210 In Two New Sciences, Galileo Galilei wrote: "Who does not know that a horse falling from a height of three or four cubits will break his bones, while a dog falling from the same height or a cat from a height 6211 of eight or ten cubits will suffer no injury?" 6212 6213 Imagine if a mouse, a horse and a human were to be thrown out of an airplane from 1,000 yards. What happens? The biologist J.B.S. Haldane said in On Being the Right Size (reprinted in The World of 6214 Mathematics): "You can drop a mouse 6215 6216 down a thousand-yard mine shaft; and, on arriving at the bottom, it gets a slight shock and walks away, provided that the ground is fairly soft. A rat is killed, a man is broken, a horse splashes." 6217 6218 196 6219 6220 Physical forces act on animals differently. Gravity has a more powerful effect on bigger things, than on smaller things. Gravity is a major influence on us, but is of minor significance to smaller animals. 6221 Since human surface area is so small, gravitational forces act upon our weight. But gravity is negligible to very small animals with high surface area to volume ratios. The dominant force is then surface 6222 force. Haldane says: "Divide an animal's length, breadth, and height each by ten; its weight is reduced to a thousandth, but its surface only to a hundredth. So the resistance to falling in the case of the 6223 small animal is relatively ten times greater than the driving force [of gravity]." 6224 6225 "Weight affects speed when air resistance is present. 6226 6227 On smaller scales, gravity becomes less and less important compared with air resistance. Throw a mouse off the plane and it floats down as frictional forces acting on its surface overcome the influence of 6228 gravity. 6229 6230 A falling object falls faster and faster, until the force of air drag acting in the opposite direction (arising from air resistance) equals its weight. Air drag depends on the surface area (the amount of air 6231 the falling object must plow through as it falls) and the speed of the falling object. Since a mouse has so much surface area compared to its small weight, it doesn't have to fall very fast before the upward 6232 acting air drag builds up to its downward-acting weight. The net force on the mouse is then zero and the mouse stops accelerating. 6233 6234 The force of air resistance against the falling horse is much greater than the force against the mouse. This happens because the horse plows through more air than the mouse does. The heavier horse falls 6235 faster through the air, increasing air resistance even more. The horse falls faster than the human before the air drag equals its weight and will therefore reach the ground first. 6236 6237 The horse has a greater surface area than the mouse, but the mouse has a greater surface area for its volume than the horse has. A mouse obeys the same law of gravitation as a human, and also the same law of 6238 air-resistance. But gravitation is key for humans, while air-resistance is all-important for the mouse. On the other hand, due to surface tension, the mouse will have problems when climbing from a pool of 6239 water. Haldane tells us a wet mouse has to carry its own weight of water. Imagine how hard it would be to get out of the bathtub if we 6240 6241 carried on our body a weight of water equal to our weight. 6242 6243 These examples show how we can better deal with reality by observing and ask "why" things happen. So look around, ask questions and remember the words of inventor and engineer Charles Proteus Steinmetz: 6244 "There are no foolish questions and no man becomes a fool until he has stopped asking questions." 6245 6246 197 6247 6248 Assume that the big ideas are true until learning otherwise. All knowledge is subject to change as new evidence arrives. This mean we have to continuously learn and re-learn. 6249 6250 Keeping knowledge alive and adding knowledge over time comes with an extra benefit. "Just as iron rusts from disuse, and stagnant water putrefies, or when cold turns to ice, so our intellect wastes unless it 6251 is kept in use," wrote Leonardo da Vinci. Research by Integrative Biology Professor Marian Cleeves Diamond at the University of California, Berkeley, reveals that a stimulating environment, curiosity and 6252 education are nourishment to the brain and therefore healthy. The more stimulation we give our brains, the better off we are. In Psychology Today (1984) she says, "I looked for people who were extremely 6253 active after 88 years of age. I found that the people who use their brains don't lose them. It was that simple." 6254 6255 Remember, knowing a definition or memorizing an idea is useless if we don't understand its meaning. Alfred North Whitehead said in The Aims of Education: "Education should be useful, whatever your aim in 6256 life." 6257 6258 198 6259 6260 - Two - 6261 6262 MEANING 6263 6264 Bad terminology is the enemy ofgood thinking. 6265 6266 Warren Buffett 6267 6268 Words, definitions, propositions, statements, or goals don't tell us anything. We need to understand what they mean. It is the same with knowledge. Knowledge is only valuable if it's useful and something is 6269 only useful if we understand what it means. 6270 6271 Richard Feynman's father, Melville, taught his son, the difference between knowing the name of something and knowing what goes on: 6272 6273 See that bird? It's a brown-throated thrush, but in Germany it's called a halzenfugel and in Chinese they call it a chung ling and even if you know all those names for it, you still know nothing about the 6274 bird. You only know something about people; what they call the bird. 6275 6276 Now that thrush sings, and teaches its young to fly, and flies so many miles away during the summer across the country, and nobody knows how it finds its way. 6277 6278 Doesn't this tell us something in the sense of learning? Words or names don't constitute knowledge. Knowing the name of something doesn't help us understand it. Since understanding implies action and 6279 accomplishment, one way of understanding is to see what happens. Feynman illustrates: 6280 6281 There is a picture of a dog, a windable toy dog, and a hand comes to the winder, and then the dog is able to move. Under the last picture, it says "What makes it move?" ... the answer I was trying to learn is 6282 that "energy makes it move." ... 6283 6284 It would be equally well to say that "God makes it move," or "spirit makes it move," or "movability makes it move." (In fact one could equally well say "energy makes it stop.") 6285 6286 Look at it this way: That's only the definition of energy. It should be reversed. We might say when something can move that it has energy in it, but not "what makes it move is energy."... 6287 6288 If you ask a child what makes the toy dog move, you should think about what an ordinary human being would answer. The answer is that you wound up the spring; it tries 6289 6290 199 6291 6292 to unwind and pushes the gear around. What a good way to begin a science course. Take apart the toy; see how it works... 6293 6294 I think, for lesson number one, to learn a mystic formula for answering questions is very bad. 6295 6296 Feynman gives another example of an empty definition: "the soles of your shoes wear out because of friction." Real knowledge is: "Shoe leather wears out because it rubs against the sidewalk and the little 6297 notches and bumps on the sidewalk grab pieces and pull them off." 6298 6299 Feynman provides a test we can do to check our understanding: 6300 6301 Without using the new word which you have just learned, try to rephrase what you have just learned in your own language. Without using the word "energy," tell me what you know now about the dog's motion. 6302 6303 Understanding "meaning" requires that we observe and ask basic questions. 6304 6305 Examples of some questions are: 6306 6307 Meaning of words: What do the words mean? What do they imply? Do they mean anything? Can we translate words, ideas or statements into an ordinary situation that tells us something? An expression is always 6308 relative. We have to judge and measure it against something. 6309 6310 Meaning of an event: What effect is produced? What is really happening using ordinary words? What is it doing? What is accomplished? Under what conditions does it happen? What else does it mean? 6311 6312 Causes: What is happening here and why? Is this working? Why or why not? Why did that happen? Why does it work here but not there? How can it happen? What are the mechanisms behind? What makes it happen? 6313 6314 Implications: What is the consequence of this observation, event, or experience? What does that imply? 6315 6316 Purpose: Why should we do that? Why do I want this to happen? 6317 6318 Reason: Why is this better than that? 6319 6320 Usefulness: What is the applicability of this? Does it mean anything in relation to what I want to achieve? 6321 6322 Danish physicist Niels Bohr said: "Never express yourself more clearly, than you are able to think." When describing something, tell it as it is and use words that people understand, and in terms of ideas 6323 with which they are familiar. Albert Einstein said: "If you can't explain it simply, you don't understand it well enough." Get to the point. Ask: What do I want to say? One reason for 6324 6325 200 6326 6327 miscommunication can be that the words mean one thing to you and something else to the person you're talking to. 6328 6329 Ask "What happens?" 6330 6331 Why have Warren Buffett and Charles Munger successfully compounded the book value of Berkshire Hathaway 3700 times over the last 42 years? Why do many people lose money investing? 6332 6333 The reason we invest in an economic asset like a business, apartment building, farm, or bond is to make money. But what does that mean? What is making money? What happens when we make money? 6334 6335 Follow the cash. "How much cash do I get and when do I get it?" 6336 6337 What happens when we make money is that we get more money back in the future than we invest today. For example, we invest $100 and get back $150. 6338 6339 What determines our return from investing in an economic asset? The price we pay, how much money we get back, and when we get it back. It makes a huge difference if we get $150 back in 2 years or 10 years. 6340 The difference in yearly return is 22% versus 4%. Our return can be measured against the expected returns from other available investment opportunities. This means that the value of an economic asset is 6341 influenced by interest rates. If interest changes, value changes. The higher the rates, the less the value. 6342 6343 If we knew for certain we would get $10 in cash every year for 5 years and we use a risk-free government bond rate of 6% as the discount rate, then the asset has a value of about $42. This means that if we 6344 pay $42, we get a 6% average yearly rate of return. If we pay $30, our return rises to 20%. The larger the difference between an economic asset's value (e.g. $42) and the price we pay, the higher our yearly 6345 return becomes. 6346 6347 Warren Buffett says, "We use the risk-free rate merely to equate one item to another. In other words, we're looking for whatever is the most attractive. In order to estimate the present value of anything, 6348 we're going to use a number. And, obviously, we can always buy government bonds. Therefore, that becomes the yardstick rate... to simply compare all kinds of investment opportunities across the spectrum: oil 6349 wells, farms, whatever it may be." 6350 6351 Don't pay more than what you get back in value. 6352 6353 Benjamin Franklin said: "I conceive that great part of the miseries of mankind are brought upon them by the false estimates they have made of the value of things, and by their giving too much for their 6354 whistles." One of Francois Due de 6355 6356 201 6357 6358 la Rochefoucauld's maxims was: "The height of ability consists in a thorough knowledge of the true value of things." 6359 6360 The key question we should ask when investing money in economic assets is: What is the expected future cash we can take out and when does it appear? How else can we know what an asset may be worth and what 6361 kind of return we can expect at a given price? Warren Buffett says: "In the end, what you have to decide is whether you're going to value a business at $400 million, $600 million or $800 million - and then 6362 compare that with the price." 6363 6364 john wants to buy an ice cream store (it doesn't matter if it is a small ice cream store or 100 shares in a billion dollar business, the relevant reasoning is the same). 6365 6366 Is this a good deal? It depends on the price John pays, and the discounted value of the cash that can be taken out of the ice cream store during its remaining life. How much cash can John take out? When can 6367 he take it out? This depends on the amount and timing of the free cash flow that is generated by the store or how much cash he can take out (and when) without hurting the store's present position against 6368 competition. 6369 6370 Warren Buffett says of the "cash flow" numbers that are often set forth in Wall Street reports: 6371 6372 These numbers routinely include (a) [reported earnings] plus (b) [depreciation, depletion, amortization, and certain other non-cash charges] - but do not subtract (c) [the average annual amount of capitalized 6373 expenditures for plant and equipment, etc.] Most sales brochures of investment bankers also feature deceptive presentations of this kind. These imply that the business being offered is the commercial 6374 counterpart of the Pyramids - forever state-of-the-art, never needing to be replaced, improved or refurbished. 6375 6376 Some cash is always needed for reinvestment in capital expenditures for plant and equipment and working capital merely to enable a business to stay in business or maintain its unit volume and long-term 6377 competitive position. A classic example is a retail store that needs to install air-conditioning because other stores have made the investment. It doesn't generate any extra business, but without it, the 6378 store may lose customers to competition. 6379 6380 Buffett also says that we have to watch out for certain figures: "When companies or investment professionals use terms such as "EBITDA" and "pro forma," they want you to unthinkingly accept concepts that are 6381 dangerously flawed." 6382 6383 202 6384 6385 He continues: 6386 6387 Trumpeting EBITDA (earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization) is a particularly pernicious practice. Doing so implies that depreciation is not truly an expense, given that it is a 6388 "non-cash" charge. That's nonsense. In truth, depreciation is a particularly unattractive expense because the cash outlay it represents is paid up front, before the asset acquired has delivered any benefits 6389 to the business. Imagine, if you will, that at the beginning of this year a company paid all of its employees for the next ten years of their service (in the way they would lay out cash for a fixed asset to 6390 be useful for ten years). In the following nine years, compensation would be a "non-cash" expense - a reduction of a prepaid compensation asset established this year. Would anyone care to argue that the 6391 recording of the expense in years two through ten would be simply a bookkeeping formality? 6392 6393 But isn't it earnings that matter for stockholders? John Burr Williams wrote in his 1938 book, The Theory of Investment Value: 6394 6395 If earnings not paid out in dividends are all successfully reinvested at compound interest for the benefit of the stockholder ... then these earnings should produce dividends later; if not, then they are 6396 money lost.... Earnings are only a means to an end, and the means should not be mistaken for the end. Therefore we must say that a stock derives its value from its dividends, not its earnings, In short, a 6397 stock is worth only what you can get out of it... for we are discussing permanent investment, not speculative trading, and dividends for years to come, not income for the moment only. 6398 6399 Warren Buffett adds, "If somebody's reinvesting all their cash flow, they better have some very big figures coming in down the road because a financial asset has to give you back a lot more cash one day in 6400 order to justify your laying out cash for it now." 6401 6402 Is value a precise figure? 6403 6404 Warren Buffett says: 6405 6406 Intrinsic value is an estimate rather than a precise figure, and it is additionally an estimate that must be changed if interest rates move or forecasts of future cash flows are revised. Two people looking at 6407 the same set of facts, moreover - and this would apply even to Charlie and me - will almost inevitably come up with at least slightly different intrinsic value figures. 6408 6409 203 6410 6411 Using precise numbers is, in fact, foolish; working with a range of possibilities is the better approach. 6412 6413 Is there a difference between how we value different businesses? 6414 6415 No matter whether a company makes telecom equipment, cars, or candy, it's still the same question: How much cash do we get and when? The name attached to the cash doesn't matter. Warren Buffett says: 6416 6417 What you're trying to do is to look at all the cash a business will produce between now and judgment day and discount it back to the present using an appropriate discount rate and buy a lot cheaper than that. 6418 Whether the money comes from a bank, an Internet company, a brick company...the money all spends the same. Why pay more for a telecom business than a brick business? Money doesn't know where it comes from. 6419 There's no sense in paying more for a glamorous business if you're getting the same amount of money, but paying more for it. It's the same money that you can get from a brick company at a lower cost. The 6420 question is what are the economic characteristics of the bank, the Internet company or the brick company. That's going to tell you how much cash they generate over long periods in the future. 6421 6422 What ifJohn needs to invest more cash in the store? 6423 6424 We have to consider the amount and timing of both cash into and from the store. As many investors in "growth" companies are well aware of, some businesses seem to need a never-ending supply of new cash. 6425 Warren Buffett says, "Growth can destroy value if it requires cash inputs in the early years of a project or enterprise that exceed the discounted value of the cash that those assets will generate in later 6426 years... Growth is simply a component- usually a plus, sometimes a minus - in the value equation." 6427 6428 But isn't it easy going wrong in estimating the amount and timing of future cash flows in and out ofa business? 6429 6430 At Berkshire, they deal with this problem in two ways. Warren Buffett says: 6431 6432 First, we try to stick to businesses we believe we understand. That means they must be relatively simple and stable in character. If a business is complex or subject to constant change, we're not smart enough 6433 to predict future cash flows. Incidentally, that shortcoming doesn't bother us. What counts for most people in investing is not how much they know, but rather how realistically they define what they don't 6434 know. An investor needs to do very few things right as long as he or she avoids big mistakes. 6435 6436 Second, and equally important, we insist on a margin of safety in our purchase price. If 6437 6438 204 6439 6440 we calculate the value of a common stock to be only slightly higher than its price, we're not interested in buying. We believe this margin-of-safety principle, so strongly emphasized by Ben Graham, to be the 6441 cornerstone of investment success. 6442 6443 Warren Buffett also says that, "we try... to keep our estimates conservative." He continues: 6444 6445 ... take all of the variables and calculate 'em reasonably conservatively... don't focus too much on extreme conservatism on each variable in terms of the discount rate and the growth rate and so on; but try 6446 to be as realistic as you can on these numbers, with any errors being on the conservative side. And then when you get all through, you apply the margin of safety. 6447 6448 It's the same thing Berkshire does in insurance. Buffett gives an example: 6449 6450 If we're trying to figure out what we should charge for, say, the chances of a 6.0 earthquake in California, we know that in the last century I think there've been 26 or so earthquakes in California that 6451 registered 6.0 or greater. And let's forget about whether they occur in remote areas. Let's just say we were writing a policy that paid off on a 6.0 or greater quake in California, regardless of whether it 6452 occurred in a desert and did no damage. Well, we would look at the history and we'd say, "Well, there've been 26 in the last century." 6453 6454 And we would probably assume a little higher number in the next century. That'd just be our nature. However, we wouldn't assume 50 - because if we did, we wouldn't write any business. But we might assume a 6455 little higher. IfI were pricing it myself, I'd probably say, well, I'll assume that there are going to be 30 - or maybe 32 or something like that. 6456 6457 And then when I'm all through, I'll want to put a premium on it that incorporates a margin of safety. In other words, if I were to figure that the proper rate for 32 was $1 million, I would probably want to 6458 charge something more than $1 million to build in that margin of safety. But I want to be conservative at all the levels - and then I want to have that significant margin of safety at the end. 6459 6460 What can john reasonably expect the store to be worth? 6461 6462 How much should John pay for the store? What future free cash flow can rationally be expected? How much cash can John take out and when? 6463 6464 Warren Buffett says, "You'd try to figure out what you were laying out currently and what you're likely to get back over time, how certain you felt about getting it and how it compared to other alternatives." 6465 He continues: "For our discount rate, we basically think in terms of the long-term government rate... But in times 6466 6467 205 6468 6469 of what seem like very low rates, we might use a little higher rate." Buffett also says, "And that discount rate doesn't pay you as high a rate as it needs to." 6470 6471 In 2003, Warren Buffett said, "We love owning common stocks - if they can be purchased at attractive prices... Unless, however, we see a very high probability of at least 10% pre-tax returns, we will sit on 6472 the sidelines." 6473 6474 Let's assume based on the store's history and expecting the same conditions in the future, John estimates that he can take out $300,000 in cash every year. Knowing he can always buy a risk-free government 6475 bond, John uses a bond rate of 6% as the discount rate. He also knows he can reinvest whatever cash he can take out from the store at 6%. The value of the store is then $5 million ($300,000/0.06). 6476 6477 Whatever he can pay below this figure increases his expected return. But since cash from a business can't be as certain as cash from a government bond, why should John pay $5 million? Why should John take 6478 time and effort investing in something that gives him the same return as doing nothing? And since John can't know for certain whether expected cash flows will turn out as he expects, he should buy the store 6479 at a price that gives him a huge margin of safety. 6480 6481 If John's required rate of return is 10%, the value of the store is $3 million. 6482 6483 Each person should use his own required rate of return. But whatever discount rate we use, we should always require a substantial discount from the estimated value in order to justify making the investment. 6484 6485 We shouldn't engage in false precision. Warren Buffett says, "We believe that if you can pinpoint it, you're kidding yourself. Therefore, we think that when we make a decision there ought to be such a margin 6486 of safety - it ought to be so attractive - that you don't have to carry it out three decimal places." He continues: "We are very inexact ... How certain we are is the most important part... You'd be amazed at 6487 how inexact we are." Charles Munger says, "We never sit down, run the numbers out and discount them back to net present value... The decision should be obvious." 6488 6489 We can use whatever discount rate we require and we can always compare investment opportunities with the long-term Treasury rate. But there is no point in calculating the value of the unpredictable. We need 6490 some certainty. Ask: How much confidence do I have in the numbers? 6491 6492 We can't compensate what we can't predict with a higher discount rate. Warren Buffett says: 6493 6494 When we look at the future of businesses, we look at riskiness as being sort of a go/no-go valve. In other words, if we think that we simply don't know what's going to happen in the 6495 6496 206 6497 6498 future, that doesn't mean it's risky for everyone. It means we don't know - that it's risky for 6499 6500 us. It may not be risky for someone else who understands the business. 6501 6502 However, in that case, we just give up. We don't try to predict those things. We don't say, "Well, we don't know what's going to happen. Therefore, we'll discount some cash flows that we don't even know at 9% 6503 instead of7%." That is not our way to approach it. Once it passes a threshold test of being something about which we feel quite certain, we tend to apply the same discount factor to everything. And we try to 6504 only buy businesses 6505 6506 about which we're quite certain. 6507 6508 Should john always take out whatever cash he can? 6509 6510 That depends on if the return for keeping the cash in the business is higher than the return John gets if he takes it out and invests somewhere else. Why should John want to take it out if he could reinvest 6511 the cash in the business at a higher return than 6%? And why should he not take the cash out if he can't reinvest it in the business at a higher return than 6%? 6512 6513 Here is a big difference between a company controlled by John and a public company where John only owns a part of the business. He doesn't control when to take the cash out in a public company. Both in 6514 private and public companies, cash may be reinvested at a mediocre return or into ideas that don't work. History has shown that many times reinvested cash has been wasted money and that a pay-out would have 6515 been better. 6516 6517 How much cash flow the store will generate is mainly determined by three variables: (1) Sales - how many units of ice cream will be sold at what price? (2) Operating costs - how much does it cost to make the 6518 ice cream and conduct the business? (3) Invested capital - how much capital is needed to conduct the business? To what degree is this capital financed with debt rather than equity and at what cost? 6519 6520 These variables determine what return the business earns on the capital that is invested in the store. Sales, costs, and capital need are largely determined by demand, competition from similar or substituting 6521 products, advantages against competition and their sustainability, cost and capital efficiency, and operational effectiveness in execution. What does this mean? Let's translate it into a simple question: Does 6522 the ice cream store have something people need or want now and in the future (demand), that no one else has (competitive advantage) or can copy or get now and in the future (sustainable) and can these 6523 advantages be translated into business value? 6524 6525 For example, why do customers choose to buy ice cream from this store rather than from somewhere else? Is it location, assortment, taste, service, 6526 6527 207 6528 6529 price? What do they associate the store and its products with? What is important to customers? Why do they come back? Have their motivations changed over the years or are they likely to change over the next 6530 10 years? What incentives can cause customers to switch to or away from the store? What threats are there? 6531 6532 Warren Buffett illustrates his thinking: 6533 6534 If you and I were looking at the chewing gum business (and we own no Wrigley's, so I use it fairly often in class), you'd pick a figure that you would expect unit volumes of chewing gum to grow in the next 6535 10-20 years and you'd give me your expectations about how much pricing flexibility Wrigley's has and how much danger there is that Wrigley's market share might be dramatically reduced-you'd go through all of 6536 that... We're evaluating the moat, the price elasticity that interacts with the moat in certain ways, the likelihood of unit demand changing in the future or management being either very bright with the cash 6537 that they develop or very stupid with it... 6538 6539 I would say you can almost measure the strength of a business over time by the agony its managers go through in determining whether a price increase can be sustained ... You can learn a lot about the 6540 durability of the economics of a business by observing the price behavior. 6541 6542 Can competitors make the store's product obsolete or copy its advantages? 6543 6544 If someone puts a store next to John's and customers don't see any difference between two stores products and services, then customers are likely to buy the ice cream in the store with the lowest prices. 6545 6546 Could John still make money having the lowest price? Yes, if demand exceeds supply or if John can produce and sell his ice cream at a lower cost than competition assuming of course competition doesn't want to 6547 run its business at a loss. John must run the store with extreme cost and capital efficiency relative to the competition. Lower costs and better use of capital allows him to keep the lowest price and still 6548 make money. 6549 6550 How important is store management? 6551 6552 How much cash and when John gets it is also a function of the ability and integrity of management. Management can influence owners' return by influencing the return of the business. It can influence where 6553 capital is being employed, and under what conditions money is to be reinvested. 6554 6555 When it comes to integrity, Warren Buffett says it best: 6556 6557 208 6558 6559 One friend of mine said that in hiring they look for three things: intelligence, energy, and character. If they don't have the last one, the first two will kill you because, it's true, if you are going to 6560 hire somebody that doesn't have character, you had really better hope they are dumb and lazy, because, if they are smart and energetic, they'll get you in all kinds of trouble. 6561 6562 A business may look to have a huge margin of safety in price but without an able and honest management this margin may end up as an illusion. History is filled with stories about great businesses that were 6563 destroyed by poor management. Ask: Is the company equipped with a competent and honest management that focuses on value? Will they use free cash flow for the benefit of the owners? 6564 6565 But in some businesses, not even brilliant management helps. Warren Buffett shares his experiences: 6566 6567 My conclusion from my own experiences and from much observation of other businesses is that a good managerial record (measured by economic returns) is far more a function of what business boat you get into 6568 than it is of how effectively you row (though intelligence and effort help considerable, of course, in any business, good or bad). Some years ago I wrote: "When a management with a repuration for brilliance 6569 tackles a business with a reputation for poor fundamental economics, it is the reputation of the business that remains intact." Nothing has since changed my point of view on that matter. Should you find 6570 yourself in a chronically-leaking boat, energy devoted to changing vessels is likely to be more productive than energy devoted to patching leaks. 6571 6572 Let's take another example of "what happens". This time we describe a model from chemistry and give an example of a misused word - entropy. 6573 6574 At 3.54 a.m. the city of Los Angeles woke up to a 6.5 earthquake. 6575 6576 Why does an earthquake crush so many structures and cause so many deaths? Why doesn't hot coffee stay hot? The answer to these questions gets to the heart of every spontaneous (means in chemistry "by itself, 6577 without energy input") physical or chemical event in our lives. The warmth in a hot beverage is due to fast moving molecules. They collide with slower moving molecules in the (relatively colder) environment 6578 and cause the slower ones to speed up. Energy is spread out from the hot liquid to the cup, the air, and by the currents of the air, to distant places. That is the nature of energy. 6579 6580 The instant we drop a ball on the floor its energy becomes kinetic energy or energy due to movement. But the term isn't important. What happens is. All 6581 6582 209 6583 6584 energy tends to spread, to become dispersed, if it is not hindered from doing so. That explains why iron rusts, why there are hurricanes, why objects break, etc. Why does a speeding truck running into a brick 6585 wall cause enormous destruction? Its kinetic energy not only tends to spread out; it spreads out catastrophically. 6586 6587 The same with the earthquake. Stress in the earth caused by the slow movement of the earth's crust floating on its hot molten energy-filled core suddenly spreads. Its potential energy is instantly changed to 6588 kinetic energy as the earth moves. When such gigantic energy spreads, it shakes everything for miles around an epicenter. Because of that energy dispersal, not only buildings collapse, but lives are cut 6589 short. 6590 6591 Our lives are based on energy dispersal. Each second, chemicals in our body (converted within us from the food we eat and oxygen we breathe) keep our hearts beating. Our lungs pump oxygen into us and carbon 6592 dioxide out. We are energy processing machines. We must keep spreading out energy so that we are warm and keep making chemicals so our hearts beat and muscles work and our lungs function. If these processes 6593 are seriously interrupted - as they are in any major accident like an earthquake - we die. 6594 6595 What does it mean (what happens) when we hear it was a magnitude 6.5 earthquake? The Richter scale is a logarithmic scale developed by the geophysicist Charles F. Richter and measures the amplitude (size) of 6596 an earthquake from the recording of earthquake waves made on a seismograph. Each unit increase in the scale corresponds to a 10-fold increase in ground motion. A magnitude 7.5 earthquake produces 10 times 6597 more ground motion than a magnitude 6.5 earthquake. But since energy causes the damage, the important difference lies in the energy release. For every unit increase, energy release increases by a factor of 6598 about 32. A 7.5 earthquake releases about 32 times more energy than a 6.5. 6599 6600 Since 1900, the biggest earthquake in the U.S. occurred in Alaska in 1964. It had a magnitude of 9.2. What is the difference in strength or energy between a magnitude 9.2 earthquake and a 6.5 earthquake? 6601 About 11,220 times. This means that it would take 11,220 earthquakes of magnitude 6.5 to equal the energy released by a 9.2 earthquake. This explains the destructive power of big quakes. 6602 6603 "Follow the energy. " 6604 6605 Entropy measures how much energy is spread out in a process, or how widely spread out it becomes - at a specific temperature. Entropy is a misused word, 6606 6607 210 6608 6609 often used to explain all kinds of "disorder." Disorder is certainly characteristic of many of our situations in life - failed relationships, social problems, messy desks, disorderly bedrooms, etc. However, 6610 entropy has no relevance to these things. Only to the scientific measure of physical energy flow from being concentrated to being spread out. 6611 6612 A room doesn't have a tendency to get messy by itself. Some outside energy is needed. It is the energy concentrated in our muscles that is being spread and causes our desks to be messed up. There is no energy 6613 being spread out in the papers themselves. As Chemistry Professor Frank Lambert says, "There isn't any 'tendency of objects to become disorganized' in nature any more than bank tellers have a 'tendency to 6614 give money to robbers' without a gun." 6615 6616 That energy tends to spread explains why metal rusts, why things break and wear down. Since energy always flows from being concentrated to less concentrated; physical objects and chemical systems deteriorate, 6617 break or become destroyed. But these things don't happen immediately or spontaneously. The repetition of time and energy must be considered. A small push (or activation energy) is needed to start a reaction. 6618 Gasoline needs a spark or flame to react with oxygen. We need a match to light a fire. For example, it took a single spark to initiate the reaction between hydrogen gas and oxygen, causing the airship 6619 Hindenburg to burn. It takes movements of wind and warm moisture from a tropical ocean to form a hurricane. It takes oxygen and moisture to make iron rust. It takes energy to make wood rot. And this process 6620 can be delayed. This happens if we for example paint iron to prevent rusting. Painting keeps oxygen away from the iron so a reaction can't happen. 6621 6622 These examples show how by observing "what happens" we can better understand reality. 6623 6624 211 6625 6626 - THREE - 6627 6628 SIMPLIFICATION 6629 6630 We have a passion for keeping things simple. 6631 6632 - Charles Munger 6633 6634 john fears that being simple reduces his importance. 6635 6636 Former General Electric CEO Jack Welch said: "You can't believe how hard it is for people to be simple, how much they fear being simple. They worry that if they're simple, people will think they're 6637 simple-minded. In reality, of course, it's just the reverse. Clear tough-minded people are the most simple." 6638 6639 Warren Buffett agrees: "We haven't succeeded because we have some great, complicated systems or magic formulas we apply or anything of the sort. What we have is just simplicity itself." Charles Munger adds: 6640 "If something is too hard, we move on to something else. What could be more simple than that?" 6641 6642 Simplify the way we do things 6643 6644 It's amazing how people even today use a computer to do something you can do with a pencil and paper in less time. 6645 6646 - Richard Feynman (from No Ordinary Genius) 6647 6648 Make problems easier to solve. Turn complicated problems into simpler ones. Eliminate everything except the essentials. Break down a problem into its components but look at the problem holistically. Draw a 6649 picture of the problem. Put down on a paper the key factors and their relationship. Charles Munger says: "I generally try to approach complex tasks by first disposing of the easy decisions." 6650 6651 Be problem-oriented. Not method-oriented. Use whatever works. Why? 6652 6653 Because the result is what matters, not the method we use to arrive at it. 6654 6655 Look for good enough solutions appropriate to the problem at hand. Not perfection and beauty. 6656 6657 Make fewer and better decisions. Why? Because it forces us to think more on each decision and thereby reduces our chance of mistakes. Warren Buffett gives another compelling reason: 6658 6659 212 6660 6661 Charlie and I decided long ago that in an investment lifetime, it's just too hard to make hundreds of smart decisions. That judgment became ever more compelling as Berkshire's capital mushroomed and the 6662 universe of investments that could significantly affect our result shrank dramatically. Therefore, we adopted a strategy that required our being smart 6663 6664 - and not too smart at that - only a very few times. 6665 6666 William James said: "The art of being wise is the art of knowing what to overlook." Charles Munger tells us about the importance of eliminating nonsense: "Part of that [having uncommon sense], I think, is 6667 being able to tune out folly, as distinguished from recognizing wisdom. You've got whole categories of things you just bat away so your brain isn't cluttered with them. That way, you're better able to pick up 6668 a few sensible things to do." 6669 6670 Warren Buffett agrees: 6671 6672 Yeah, we don't consider many stupid things. I mean, we get rid of 'em fast... Just getting rid of the nonsense - just figuring out that if people call you and say, ''I've got this great, wonderful idea'', you 6673 don't spend 10 minutes once you know in the first sentence that it isn't a great, wonderful idea... Don't be polite and go through the whole process. 6674 6675 Often we try to get too much information, including misinformation, or information of no use to explain or predict. We also focus on details and what's irrelevant or unknowable and overlook the obvious 6676 truths. Dealing with what's important forces us to prioritize. There are often just a few actions that produce most of what we are trying to achieve. There are only a few decisions of real importance. 6677 6678 More information doesn't equal more knowledge or better decisions. And remember that today we not only have access to more information, but also misinformation. Charles Munger says: "The harder you work, the 6679 more confidence you get. But you may be working hard on something that is false." 6680 6681 In Arthur Conan Doyle's The Reigate Puzzle, Sherlock Holmes says: "It is of the highest importance in the art of detection to be able to recognize, out of a number of facts, which are incidental and which 6682 vital." 6683 6684 Turn off the noise or what's irrelevant and look at the big picture. Ask: Why am I doing this? What really matters? What is important for what I want to achieve? Will more information affect my decision? 6685 Don't collect data randomly. Start with why the particular information is needed in the first place. 6686 6687 When asked if he used a computer, Charles Munger said: 6688 6689 213 6690 6691 I'm a follower of what I call the Thomas Hunt Morgan school. Morgan was one of the great biologists in the history of the world who figured out a lot of genetics [Morgan established that chromosomes carried 6692 the units of inheritance] with very slender resources in a so-called "fly room" - first at Columbia and then at Caltech. And when Morgan reached Caltech, he did something that was very peculiar. He banned the 6693 Friden calculator 6694 6695 - which was the computer of that age - from the biology department. Everybody else at Caltech used the Friden calculator endlessly for all kinds of statistical correlations and much else. Morgan banned it. 6696 6697 And they asked, "Why are you doing this?" He said, 'Tm so located in life that I'm like 6698 6699 a gold miner in 1848 who could just walk along the banks of the river and pick up enormous nuggets of gold with organized common sense. And as long as I can do this, I'm not going to use scarce resources in 6700 placer mining." 6701 6702 Well, that's the way I go at life. I think if you get the big points with organized common sense, it's amazing the placer mining you never have to do ... 6703 6704 But is there still enormous gain to be made with organized common sense that doesn't require a computer? I think the answer is "yes." Are there dangers in getting too caught up in the minutiae of using a 6705 computer so that you miss the organized common sense? There are huge dangers. There'll always be huge dangers. People calculate too much and think too little. 6706 6707 Avoid certain things 6708 6709 There are things that we stay away from. Were like the man who said he had three baskets on his desk: in, out and too tough. We have such baskets - mental baskets - in our office. An awfal lot ofstujfgoes in 6710 the "too tough" basket. 6711 6712 - Charles Munger 6713 6714 Deal with the situations in life by knowing what to avoid. Reducing mistakes by learning what areas, situations and people to avoid is often a better use of time than seeking out new ways of succeeding. Also, 6715 it is often simpler to prevent something than to solve it. 13th Century jurist and priest Henry de Bracton said: "An ounce of prevention is worth a pound of cure." 6716 6717 Warren Buffett describes how he and Charles Munger do it: 6718 6719 Easy does it. After 25 years of buying and supervising a great variety of businesses, Charlie and I have not learned how to solve difficult business problems. What we have learned is to avoid them. To the 6720 extent we have been successful, it is because we concentrated on identifying one-foot hurdles that we could step over rather than because we acquired any 6721 6722 214 6723 6724 ability to clear seven-footers. The finding may seem unfair, but in both business and investments it is usually far more profitable to simply stick with the easy and obvious than it is to resolve the 6725 difficult. 6726 6727 We basically have the attitude that you can't make a good deal with a bad person. We don't try to protect ourselves by contracts or all kinds of due diligence - we just forget about it. We can do fine over 6728 time dealing with people we like and admire and trust. 6729 6730 And the bad actor will try to tantalize you in one way or another. But you won't win. It pays to just avoid him. We started out with that attitude. However, one or two experiences have convinced us even more 6731 so that that's the way to play the game. 6732 6733 Charles Munger follows up with: 6734 6735 I've heard Warren say since very early in his life that the difference between agood business and a bad one is that a good business throws up one easy decision after another, whereas a bad one gives you 6736 horrible choices - decisions that are extremely hard to make: "Can it work?" "Is it worth the money?" 6737 6738 One way to determine which is the good business and which is the bad one is to see which one is throwing management bloopers - pleasant, no-brainer decisions - time after time after time. 6739 6740 Focus leads to understanding and efficiency 6741 6742 Those who attain to any excellence commonly spend life in some single pursuit, for excellence is not often gained upon easier terms. 6743 6744 - Samuel Johnson 6745 6746 It is impossible for our brain to think too many things at the same time and expect to do well. Shifting our mental attention between tasks costs time and comprehension, especially when we switch between more 6747 complicated and unfamiliar tasks. 6748 6749 Actions and decisions are simpler when we focus on one thing at the time. Publilius Syrus said: "To do two things at once is to do neither." If we only have one thing to focus on, we tend to do it well and 6750 build knowledge. 6751 6752 Always think with a purpose in mind. Ask: What do I want to achieve or avoid? Is focus important in business and for management? Warren Buffett says: 6753 6754 A... serious problem occurs when the management of a great company gets sidetracked and neglects its wonderful base business while purchasing other businesses that are so-so 6755 6756 215 6757 6758 or worse... (Would you believe that a few decades back they were growing shrimp at Coke and exploring for oil at Gillette?) Loss of focus is what most worries Charlie and me when we contemplate investing in 6759 businesses that in general look outstanding. All too often, we've seen value stagnate in the presence of hubris or of boredom that caused the attention of managers to wander ... 6760 6761 I love focused management ... And when you lose that focus - it shows... GEICO 6762 6763 actually started fooling around in a number of things in the early 1980s. And they paid a price for it - actually a very big price. They paid a direct price in terms of the cost for those things - because 6764 they almost all worked out badly. And then they paid an additional price in terms of the loss of focus on the main business. 6765 6766 Focus on what you can know and that makes a difference 6767 6768 Before attacking a problem ask if it is worth solving or spending time on. Warren Buffett explains one of the reasons for his and Charles Munger's success in life and business: 6769 6770 There are two questions you ask yourself as you look at the decision you'll make. A) is it knowable? B) is it important? Ifit is not knowable, as you know there are all kinds of things that are important but 6771 not knowable, we forget about those. And if it's unimportant, whether it's knowable or not, it won't make any difference. We don't care. 6772 6773 What's knowable and important? And what can be translated into useful action? Some important things we can't know. Like where the stock market is going. Other things we can know but they are not important. 6774 6775 Ask the right questions 6776 6777 The formulation ofa problem is often more essential than its solution, which may be merely a matter of mathematical or experimental skill. 6778 6779 - Albert Einstein 6780 6781 Sometimes it is harder to understand a problem than to solve it. Asking the important questions may help. Start with basic questions like: What does it mean? What is the simplest example? What is the number 6782 one question? How can I tell if the answer is right? Can I come up with an example that makes it clear what the problem is? 6783 6784 But it is not enough to ask the right questions. We must look at the right place and ask the right person. We can't rely too much on assumptions since we can't be sure that someone else's assumptions are the 6785 same as ours, unless we ask them to explain. 6786 6787 216 6788 6789 Patience 6790 6791 It's not that I'm so smart; it's just that I stay with problems longer. 6792 6793 Albert Einstein 6794 6795 The best thinking is often done when there is no stress, time limit, threats, or judging. Thinking takes time and the simple truths often reveal themselves when we're doing something else. 6796 6797 We are more likely to solve a specific problem or gain new insight if we leave the problem alone for awhile and let our subconscious mind work. This is well illustrated by the physicists Albert Einstein and 6798 Leopold Infeld: 6799 6800 In nearly every detective novel since the admirable stories of Conan Doyle there comes a time where the investigator has collected all the facts he needs for at least some phase of his problem. These facts 6801 often seem quite strange, incoherent, and wholly unrelated. The great detective, however, realizes that no further investigation is needed at the moment, and that only pure thinking will lead to a correlation 6802 of the facts collected. So he plays his violin, or lounges in his armchair enjoying a pipe, when suddenly, by Jove, he has it! 6803 6804 Roger Lowenstein describes Warren Buffett in [3mBuffett: The Making of an American Capitalist: [0m"Buffett's genius was largely a genius of character - of patience, discipline and rationality...His talent sprang 6805 from his unrivaled independence of mind and ability to focus on his work and shut out the world." Have patience in waiting for opportunities. Resist the temptation to always do something. If we are in a 6806 hurry, it's easier to make misjudgments. This is key in investing. Warren Buffett says, "In allocating capital, activity does not correlate with achievement. Indeed, in the fields of investments and 6807 acquisitions, frenetic behavior is often counterproductive." He continues: "If you feel like you have to invest every day, you're going to make a lot of mistakes. It isn't that kind of a 6808 6809 business. You have to wait for the fat pitch." Charles Munger adds: 6810 6811 A few major opportunities, clearly recognizable as such, will usually come to one who continuously searches and waits, with a curious mind, loving diagnosis involving multiple variables. And then all that is 6812 required is a willingness to bet heavily when the odds are extremely favorable, using resources available as a result of prudence and patience in the past. 6813 6814 217 6815 6816 - FOUR - 6817 6818 RULES AND FILTERS 6819 6820 Rules are for the obedience of fools and the guidance of wise men. 6821 6822 David Ogilvy (Advertising executive, 1911-1999) 6823 6824 What can help us avoid problems and act as guidelines when making decisions? Based on our knowledge of reality and our personal situation we should establish some "what to do" and "what to avoid" rules. 6825 6826 Charles Munger gives an example of a rule: 6827 6828 Any time anybody offers you [3manything [0mwith a big commission and a 200-page prospectus, don't buy it. Occasionally, you'll be wrong if you adopt "Munger's Rule". However, over a lifetime, you'll be a long way 6829 ahead - and you will miss a lot of unhappy experiences that might otherwise reduce your love for your fellow man. 6830 6831 Another rule comes from Benjamin Franklin: "To apply myself industriously to whatever business I take at hand, and not divert my mind from my business by any foolish project of growing suddenly rich; for 6832 industry and patience are the surest means of plenty." 6833 6834 Other rules could be, "Walk away from anything I don't understand or can't quantify or doesn't work. Only deal with people I trust. " 6835 6836 Warren Buffett provides us with guidelines on how to win in insurance, which applies to other areas as well: 6837 6838 What counts in this business is underwriting discipline. The winners are those that unfailingly stick to three key principles: 6839 6840 They accept only those risks that they are able to properly evaluate (staying within their circle of competence) and that, after they have evaluated all relevant factors including remote loss scenarios, carry 6841 the expectancy ofprofit. These insurers ignore market-share considerations andare sanguine about losing business to competitors that are offering foolish prices or policy conditions. 6842 6843 They limit the business they accept in a manner that guarantees they will suffer no aggregation of losses.from a single event or.from related events that will threaten their solvency. They ceaselessly search 6844 for possible correlation among seemingly-unrelated risks. 6845 6846 218 6847 6848 3. They avoid business involving moral risk: No matter what the rate, trying to write good contracts with bad people doesn't work. While most policyholders and clients are honorable and ethical, doing 6849 business with the few exceptions is usually expensive, sometimes extraordinarily so. 6850 6851 I have known the details of almost every policy that Ajit [Ajit Jain] has written... and never on even a single occasion have I seen him break any of our three underwriting rules. His extraordinary 6852 discipline, of course, does not eliminate losses; it does, however, prevent foolish losses. And that's the key: Just as in the case of investing, insurers produce outstanding long term results primarily by 6853 avoiding dumb decisions, rather than by making brilliant ones. 6854 6855 Filters 6856 6857 We really can say no in 10 seconds or so to 90% + of all the things that come along simply because we have these filters. 6858 6859 - Warren Buffett 6860 6861 Filters help us prioritize and figure out what makes sense. 6862 6863 When we know what we want, we need criteria to evaluate alternatives. Ask: What are the most critical (and knowable) factors that will cause what I want to achieve or avoid? Criteria must be based on evidence 6864 and be reasonably predictive, i.e., we must do better than chance by relying on them. Try to use as few criteria as necessary to make your judgment. Then rank them in order of their importance and use them as 6865 filters. Set decision thresholds in a way that minimizes the likelihood of false alarms and misses (in investing, choosing a bad investment or missing a good investment). Consider the consequences of being 6866 wrong. For example, in medicine, a threshold depends on factors such as the prevalence of a condition, its seriousness, the availability of corrective measures, and the emotional and financial costs of false 6867 alarms. 6868 6869 Past criminal and prison records are more reliable than expert criminologists in predicting success on parole. 6870 6871 Studies show that in some fields, when based on the same evidence, a more mechanical prediction process involving a small number of relevant variables is more reliable than the predictions of trained and 6872 experienced experts. This has been shown in diagnoses of medical conditions, predictions of academic performance, in determining gambling odds, and loan and credit risk. Why does it work better? Because we 6873 humans are not always consistent. As we have seen, recent experiences, suggestions, or how information is presented may influence us. Add to this our natural limitations in memory, attention, and processing. 6874 6875 219 6876 6877 More information doesn't mean we are better off. Sometimes extra information is useless and confusing. 6878 6879 A man is rushed to a hospital in the throes ofa heart attack. The doctor needs to decide whether the victim should be treated as a low risk or high-risk patient. 6880 6881 Criteria don't have to be numerous or complicated. Late Statistics Professor Leo Breiman and colleagues at University of California, Berkeley, developed a method to classify high-risk heart attack patients 6882 using only a maximum of 3 variables. Blood pressure, age and sinus tachycardia (rapid heartbeat). 6883 6884 If a patient's minimum systolic blood pressure over the initial 24-hour period is less than 91, he is immediately classified as high risk. If not, the second variable is age. If the patient is over 62.5 years 6885 old, then one more variable - sinus tachycardia 6886 6887 is needed to classify him as high or low risk. If the patient displays sinus tachycardia he is classified as high risk. Thus, the doctor needs to answer three yes no questions to reach a decision. The method 6888 is more accurate in classifying high risk heart attack patients than complex statistical classification methods. 6889 6890 At a press conference in 2001, when Warren Buffett was asked how he evaluated new business ideas, he said he used 4 criteria as filters. 6891 6892 Can I understand it? If it passes this filter, 6893 6894 Does it look like it has some kind of sustainable competitive advantage? If it passes this filter, 6895 6896 Is the management composed of able and honest people? Ifit passes this filter, 6897 6898 Is the price right? If it passes this filter, then we write a check 6899 6900 What does Warren Buffett mean by "understanding?" Predictability: "Our definition of understanding is thinking that we have a reasonable probability of being able to assess where the business will be in 10 6901 years." He continues: 6902 6903 The only way we know how to make money is to try and evaluate businesses. And if we can't evaluate a carbon steel company, we don't buy it. It doesn't mean it isn't a good buy. It doesn't mean it isn't 6904 selling for a fraction of what its worth. It just means that we don't know how to evaluate it. If we can't evaluate the sense of putting in a chemical plant or something in Brazil, we don't do it... 6905 6906 We understand the product. We understand what it does for people. We just don't know [what its economics will be] 10 years from now... You can understand steel. You can understand homebuilding. But if you 6907 look at a homebuilder and try to think where the economics of it is going to be in five or 10 years, that's another question. It's not a question 6908 6909 220 6910 6911 of understanding the product they turn out, the means they use to distribute it- all of that sort of thing - it's the predictability of the economics of the situation 10 years out. 6912 6913 Let's take an example where we combine rules and filters. Reality often shows that one cause of problems is getting involved with wrong people. A rule could therefore be: "Avoid low quality people." As a 6914 consequence a filter may be: "Good track record and character traits." Then we look for dues and ask questions designed to answer the question: "High or low grade individual?" 6915 6916 Elimination 6917 6918 Elimination is a great conservator of effort. For example, place the burden of proof on statements that contradict basic scientific ideas. Eliminate situations that may cause great sorrow, what is not 6919 important or knowable, what can't happen or be achieved, what can't usefully be predicted or explained, what can't be tested, what is already disproved, the easy decisions, the wrong assumptions, what we 6920 can't do something about or problems where we don't have any competence. 6921 6922 Science works by elimination. To avoid drowning in low-information observations or experiments, scientists think in advance about what the most important and conclusive experiments would be: What are we 6923 trying to achieve or prove, and how can we reach these ends? What can't happen? This way, they narrow down the possibilities. It is similar to what Warren Buffett told us in Part One - eliminate possibilities 6924 and get down to the few that have any chance of success. Look for certain things that narrow down the possibilities. 6925 6926 Checklist procedures 6927 6928 Air carrier cockpit checklists to be reviewed in an effort to ensure that each list provides a means of reminding the crew, immediately prior to takeoff, that all items critical for safe flight have been 6929 accomplished. 6930 6931 - National Transportation Safety Board, 1969 6932 6933 In 1987, Northwest Airlines flight 255 crashed shortly after take-off All 155 persons aboard expect one were killed A federal report concluded that the probable cause of the accident was the flight crew's 6934 failure to use the taxi checklist to ensure that the flaps and slats were extended for takeoff. Contributing to the accident was the absence of electrical power to the airplane's takeoff warning system, which 6935 consequently could not warn the flight crew that the airplane was not configured properly for takeoff. Use checklist procedures. Together with other tools they help us reduce the 6936 6937 221 6938 6939 chance of harm. Concentrate on the critical items. If we don't check for them we may get harmed. Pilots call these the "killer items." 6940 6941 Charles Munger suggests using models in a checklist fashion: 6942 6943 Generally speaking, I think you need mental models - and what I call checklist procedures 6944 6945 where you take a worthwhile list of models and run right down them: "Is this here? Is that here?" and so on and so on ... Now if there are two or three items that are very important chat aren't on your 6946 checklist - well, if you're an airplane pilot, you can crash. Likewise, if you're trying to analyze a company without using an adequate checklist, you may make a very bad investment. 6947 6948 Some issues to think about when designing checklists are: 6949 6950 Different issues need different checklists. 6951 6952 A checklist must include each critical item necessary for "safety'' and avoiding "accidents" so we don't need to rely on memory for items to be checked. 6953 6954 Readily usable and easy to use. 6955 6956 Agree with reality. 6957 6958 Contributing to the accident was the captain's over-reliance on automated flight systems. 6959 6960 Avoid excessive reliance on checklists. They may sometimes give us a false sense of security. Checklists work well as long as what may happen can be foreseen. But the unexpected sometimes happens. An 6961 unmentioned item may be the core cause of a problem. 6962 6963 Doing something according to pre-established rules, filters and checklists often makes more sense than doing something out of pure emotion. But we can't have too many rules, filters or items without thinking. 6964 We must always understand what we're trying to accomplish. 6965 6966 222 6967 6968 - FIVE - 6969 6970 GOALS 6971 6972 Our plans miscarry because they have no aim. When a man does not know what harbor he is headingfor, no wind is the right wind. 6973 6974 - Lucius Annaeus Seneca 6975 6976 "Why doesn't our employee, Tom, perform well?" 6977 6978 Often we are surprised when people don't perform as we expect. 6979 6980 How does Tom perceive he is being measured and rewarded? What does he perceive is expected of him? Do we give him mixed messages? What skills, knowledge and information does he need? Does he have those? What 6981 response do we give him about his performance? 6982 6983 Tom: "I have the right knowledge and understand the goal. I also know how to achieve the goal and why my way makes the most sense. I have the authority to make the relevant decisions and can measure the 6984 outcome continuously. If I achieve the goal, I will be rewarded. I decide the amount of reward I will get. If I don't accomplish the goal, I lose my job. Since I have the responsibility, it is only right that 6985 I face the consequences." 6986 6987 Have goals that cause what we want to accomplish. Do we know what we want to achieve and why? fu Aristotle said: ''Are we not more likely to hit the mark if we have a target?" How can we make the right 6988 decision if we don't know what we want to achieve? Even if we don't know what we want, we often know what we don't want, meaning that our goal can be to avoid certain things. 6989 6990 Meaningful goals need to be backed by reasons as a way of testing that we set the right goal. Goals should be: 6991 6992 Clearly defined. Don't say: "I want to have a better life." Be concrete. For example: "I want a new Volvo." 6993 6994 Focused on results. 6995 6996 Realistic and logical - what can and can't be achieved? Low goals may produce low performance and unrealistic goals may cause people to cheat. Lucius Annaeus Seneca said we should: "Never work either for 6997 useless goals, or impossible ones." 6998 6999 Measurable. 7000 7001 223 7002 7003 Tailored to our individual needs. 7004 7005 Subject to change. Ask: Given our current objective, what is the best course of action to take? 7006 7007 Goals also need target dates and control stations measuring the degree to which the goal is being achieved. 7008 7009 Do we know what causes our goal to be achieved? We can't achieve what we want if we don't understand what makes it happen. And are we sure our goal is the right one for what we finally want to achieve? 7010 7011 Warren Buffett and Charles Munger elaborated on the issue of the energy crisis at the 2001 Berkshire Hathaway Annual Meeting: 7012 7013 In power systems we need surplus of capacity. And how do we get that? By giving people an incentive for having extra capacity. A power business can't be punished for not having excess capacity and can't be 7014 rewarded for having less then what is needed. 7015 7016 We need three things for this not to happen again. One is that we need reasonable efficiency in operations. Secondly, since it does tend to have in many situations monopoly characteristics, we want something 7017 that produced a fair return, but not a great return, on capital - enough to attract new capital. And third, we need a margin of safety or a little more capacity than needed. And we need the whole equation. 7018 7019 Always ask: What end result do I want? What causes that? What factors have a major impact on the outcome? What single factor has the most impact? Do I have the variable(s) needed for the goal to be achieved? 7020 What is the best way to achieve my goal? Have I considered what other effects my actions will have that will influence the final outcome? 7021 7022 When we solve problems and know what we want to achieve, we need to prioritize or focus on the right problems. What should we do first? Ask: How serious are the problems? Are they fixable? What is the most 7023 important problem? Are the assumptions behind them correct? Did we consider the interconnected ness of the problems? The long-term consequences? 7024 7025 Since big effects - bad or good - happen when we optimize some factors or combine many factors, we should use whatever factors necessary to achieve our goal. 7026 7027 224 7028 7029 - SIX - 7030 7031 ALTERNATIVES 7032 7033 Ifyou've got two suitors who are really eager to have you and one is way the hell better than the other, you do not have to spend much time 7034 7035 with the other. And that's the way we filter out buying opportunities. 7036 7037 - Charles Munger 7038 7039 "Allocate the money to us!" 7040 7041 How should we best allocate our scarce resources? TransCorp has ten different projects to choose from. Should they invest in all? Should each project get the same amount of funding? People, money, time, 7042 talent and other resources are limited. They also have alternative uses. Some options are also better than others. 7043 7044 Opportunity cost 7045 7046 "I weigh my use of capital and time against other available alternate uses. " 7047 7048 One filter that can be used to measure choices against each other is our own personal opportunity cost. Our time and money are limited. If we make a decision to do one thing we are deciding not to do some 7049 other available thing. Every minute we choose to spend on one thing is a minute unavailable to spend on other things. Every dollar we invest is a dollar unavailable for other available investments. If we 7050 decide to spend money today instead of investing for the future we give up the opportunity to spend more in the future. Ifl decide to play golf today I miss the opportunity to finish this book on time. If I 7051 write, I miss the opportunity to spend time with my children. Since children grow up, this opportunity has a time limit. 7052 7053 Choices have costs. Even understanding has an opportunity cost. If we understand one thing well we may understand other things better. The cost of using a limited resource like time, effort and money for a 7054 specific purpose, can be measured as the value or opportunity lost by not using it in its best available alternative use (assuming it achieves the same purpose). 7055 7056 Do you choose to work or go to college? 7057 7058 What is the real cost of choosing one alternative in favor of another? To use a 7059 7060 225 7061 7062 somewhat changed example from Warren Buffett: What is the real cost of not having a college education? What is the difference in income over a lifetime between having an education or not? If we ignore the 7063 non-economic benefits of having an education, this difference in income discounted to graduation day is the value of the education or the real cost of not having an education. 7064 7065 What is our time worth? Do we spend ten hours doing repairs on our house or do we use a carpenter? The real cost of doing the repairs ourselves is the money that we would have earned doing something else. 7066 7067 Does "free health care" mean it is really ftee? 7068 7069 No, had it not been free, the resources used for providing free health care could have been used for something else. Often we only see the benefits of government spending. We don't see what is prevented from 7070 happening or that resources are diverted from alternative uses. 7071 7072 "Employ 3 more sales representatives in Montana. " 7073 7074 Should TransCorp take the time, money and talent to build a market presence in Montana? The real cost of doing that is the value of the time, money and talent used in its best alternative use. Maybe 7075 increasing their presence in a state where they already have a market share is creating more value. Sometimes it is more profitable to marginally increase a cost where a company already has an infrastructure. 7076 Where do they marginally get the most leverage on resources spent? Always ask: What is the change of value of taking a specific action? Where is it best to invest resources from a value point of view? 7077 7078 john's return ftom the investment was a meager I%. 7079 7080 The 10-year $100,000 investment in the private partnership promised a yearly return of 15%. John's next best available investment at the time was a long-term 7081 7082 U.S. government bond yielding 6%. 10 years later reality kicked in. He got back 7083 7084 $110,000. His yearly return was only 1%. If he hadn't made the investment back then, but had earned returns comparable with the government bond, John would now have $179,000 (pretax) instead of the $110,000 7085 (pretax). His real cost of doing this investment was $69,000. The money invested tied him in other ways. This doesn't include the mental stress he experienced during the ride. 7086 7087 We all have a lot of things we like: our spouse, job, house, car, investments, etc. When we decide whether to change something, we should measure it against the best of what we already have. 7088 7089 A complementary filter to evaluate alternatives is to list their respective pros 7090 7091 226 7092 7093 and cons and then weigh all the points. Charles Darwin did this in order to decide whether to marry. Warren Buffett tells us what to look for in a spouse: "Look for someone who will love you unconditionally 7094 and will subtly encourage you to be better than you thought you can be." 7095 7096 We can also weigh alternatives the way Benjamin Franklin did. Make up a list of reasons for and against and assign them weights. 7097 7098 All decisions are not equally important. Some decisions have a greater influence on our lives. A decision we make today that will influence our lives ten years from now is far more important than one that 7099 will influence us only today. If we make a mistake in choosing the wrong vacation, the consequences over time will most likely be minor. But if, for example, we choose the wrong spouse, the wrong education, 7100 career, friends, or investment, it may haunt us a long, long time. 7101 7102 227 7103 7104 - SEVEN - 7105 7106 CONSEQUENCES 7107 7108 The key thing in economics, whenever someone makes an assertion to you, is to always ask, "And then what?" Actually, it's not such a bad idea to ask it about everything. But you should always ask, "And then 7109 what?" 7110 7111 - Warren Buffett 7112 7113 John told the CEO of TransCorp: "We see the immediate benefits of investment in machines. We don't see competitive actions and that all the benefits go to the customer." 7114 7115 "In the department of economy, an act, a habit, an institution, a law, gives birth 7116 7117 not only to an effect, but to a series of effects," wrote the French journalist economist Claude Frederic Bastiat in his 1850 essay, ThatWhich is Seen, and That Which is Not Seen. He continues: 7118 7119 Of these effects, the first only is immediate; it manifests itself simultaneously with its cause 7120 7121 - it is seen. The others unfold in succession - they are not seen... Between a good and a bad economist this constitutes the whole difference - the one takes account of the visible effect; the other takes 7122 account both of the effects which are seen, and also of those which it is necessary to foresee. 7123 7124 Consider secondary and long-term effects of an action. Charles Munger points out that in a commodity business or in a business earning substandard returns, 7125 7126 All of the advantages from great improvements are going to flow through to the customers ... the people who sell the machinery - and, by and large, even the internal bureaucrats urging you to buy the 7127 equipment - show you projections with the amount you'll save at current prices with the new technology. However, they don't do the second step of the analysis-which is to determine how much is going to stay 7128 home and how much is just going to flow through to the customer. 7129 7130 I've never seen a single projection incorporating that second step in my life. And I see them all the time. Rather, they always read: "This capital outlay will save you so much money that it will pay for 7131 itself in three years." So you keep buying things that will pay for 7132 7133 228 7134 7135 themselves in three years. And after 20 years of doing it, somehow you've earned a return of only about 4% per annum. That's the textile business. 7136 7137 And it isn't that the machines weren't better. It's just that the savings didn't go to you. The cost reductions came through all right. But the [3mbenefit [0mof the cost reductions didn't go to the guy who bought 7138 the equipment. 7139 7140 Warren Buffett tells us about the illusionary benefits: 7141 7142 Many of our competitors ... were stepping up to the same kind of expenditures and, once enough companies did so, their reduced costs became the baseline for reduced prices industrywide. Viewed individually, 7143 each company's capital investment decision appeared cost-effective and rational; viewed collectively, the decisions neutralized each other and were irrational. 7144 7145 Whenever we install a policy, take an action or evaluate statements, we must trace the consequences. When doing so, we must remember four key things: 7146 7147 Pay attention to the whole system. Direct and indirect effects, 7148 7149 Consequences have implications or more consequences, some which may be unwanted. We can't estimate all possible consequences but there is at least one unwanted consequence we should look our for, 7150 7151 Consider the effects offeedback, time, scale, repetition, critical thresholds and limits, 7152 7153 Different alternatives have different consequences in terms of costs and benefits. Estimate the net effects over time and how desirable these are compared to what we want to achieve. 7154 7155 We can't get something/or nothing. 7156 7157 Take the issue on alternative energy sources. Some relevant headlines when thinking about alternatives: Energy used versus usable energy produced (considering the entire production process)? Infrastructure 7158 requirements? Scalable? Transport and storage? Costs (considering subsidies)? Who pays? Environmental benefits and costs? Sustainability? Consequences over time? Degree of difficulty in properly evaluating 7159 all the factors involved? Consequences of being wrong? 7160 7161 Judge an action by its net consequences over time considering the whole system. Follow up changes in individual variables by determining how the rest of the system will respond over time. Reducing risk in one 7162 area may increase it in 7163 7164 229 7165 7166 another. Changes in one variable may change the entire system. One change may cause another change causing another, etc. This includes considering short and long-term consequences since there may be a long 7167 time between an action and its full effects. 7168 7169 Marcus Tullius Cicero said: "Extreme justice is extreme injustice." Some systems should be made deliberately a little unfair if they carry better consequences for us all. Charles Munger tells us about the 7170 Navy model - a rule with net benefits: 7171 7172 If you're a captain in the Navy and you've been up for 24 hours straight and have to go to sleep and you turn the ship over to a competent first mate in tough conditions and he takes the ship aground - 7173 clearly through no fault of yours - they don't court martial you, but your naval career is over. 7174 7175 Napoleon said he liked luckier generals - he wasn't into supporting losers. Well, the Navy likes luckier captains. 7176 7177 You can say, "That's too tough. That's not law school. That's not due process." Well, the Navy model is better in its context than would be the law school model. The Navy model really forces people to pay 7178 attention when conditions are tough - because they know that there's no excuse. Very simply, if your ship goes aground, your career is over. 7179 7180 "It doesn't matter whether it was your fault or not. Nobody's interested in your fault. It's just a rule that we happen to have - for the good of all, all effects considered." 7181 7182 I like some rules like that - I think that the civilization works better with some of these no-fault rules. But that stuff tends to be anathema around law schools. "It's not due process. You're not really 7183 searching for justice." 7184 7185 Well, I am searching for justice when I argue for the Navy rule - for the justice of fewer ships going aground. Considering the net benefit, I don't care if one captain has some unfairness in his life. After 7186 all, it's not like he's being court marshalled. He just has to look for a new line of work. And he keeps vested pension rights and so on. So it's not like it's the end of the world. 7187 7188 230 7189 7190 - EIGHT - 7191 7192 QUANTIFICATION 7193 7194 To talk sense, is to talk in quantities. It is no use saying that the nation is large, 7195 7196 - [3mHow large? It is no use saying that radium is scarce, [0m- [3mHow scarce? [0m-Alfred North Whitehead (from The Aims of Education) 7197 7198 Most aspects of our life depend on our ability to quantify and understand patterns and relationships, proportions, or magnitudes. What does math do? It helps us develop consequences, and evaluate when things 7199 make sense. And math is stable. Two plus two is four was true 1 million years ago and will be true 1 million years from today. 7200 7201 When we translate something into numbers we can make comparisons. How can we evaluate if a decision is intelligent or not if we can't measure it against a relevant and important yardstick? 7202 7203 Some things can't be measured exactly, so estimating a range is the next best alternative. 7204 7205 "It is better to be roughly right than precisely wrong," said J.M. Keynes. Don't overweigh what can be counted and underweigh what cannot. Beware of false concreteness - often we believe that data based on 7206 figures with lots of decimal places are more accurate than words alone. Charles Munger says: 7207 7208 You've got a complex system, and it spews out a lot of wonderful numbers that enable you to measure some factors. But there are other factors that are terribly important and there's no precise numbering you 7209 can put to these factors. You know they're important but you don't have the numbers. Well, practically everybody overweighs the stuff that can be numbered, because it yields to the statistical techniques 7210 they're taught in academia, and doesn't mix in the hard-to-measure stuff that may be more important. 7211 7212 Let's illustrate the importance of quantification with examples from the world of business and investing. 7213 7214 How much capital is needed to produce a dollar of cash flow? 7215 7216 Does return on invested capital make a difference? Assume two businesses - X 7217 7218 231 7219 7220 and Y - generate the same cash earnings of $10 million and "perpetual" growth of 5%. The difference lies in how much capital they use to produce these earnings. X needs $100 million and Y $40 million. This 7221 means that their return on invested capital is 10% respective 25%. This also means that they differ in the free cash flow (after reinvesting) or distributable cash they generate. X generates 7222 7223 $5 million and Y $8 million. Return on invested capital makes a difference in value. 7224 7225 Business X 7226 7227 Business Y 7228 7229 Invested capital 7230 7231 100 7232 7233 40 7234 7235 Free cash flow 7236 7237 10 7238 7239 10 7240 7241 Reinvested capital 7242 7243 -5 7244 7245 -2 7246 7247 Return on reinvested capital 7248 7249 10% 7250 7251 25% 7252 7253 Available cash flow for distribution 7254 7255 5 7256 7257 8 7258 7259 Value at 10% discount rate 7260 7261 100 (5/(0.1-0.05)) 7262 7263 160 7264 7265 Warren Buffett describes what businesses are best to own: 7266 7267 Leaving the question of price aside, the best business to own is one that over an extended period can employ large amounts of incremental capital at very high rates of return. The worst business to own is one 7268 that must, or will, do the opposite - that is, consistently employ ever-greater amounts of capital at very low rates of return. 7269 7270 Should higher earnings automatically impress us? 7271 7272 Warren Buffett gives an example from one of Berkshire's subsidiaries: 7273 7274 While an increase in earnings from $8 million to $72 million sounds terrific - and usually is -you should not automatically assume that to be the case. You must first make sure that earnings were not 7275 depressed in the base year. If they were instead substantial in relation to capital employed, an even more important point must be examined: how much additional capital was required to produce the additional 7276 earnings? 7277 7278 We need to understand what is behind the numbers. Warren Buffett says that, "return on beginning equity capital" is "the most appropriate measure of single year managerial performance. Informed use of that 7279 yardstick, however, requires, an understanding of many factors, including accounting policies, historical carrying values of assets, financial leverage, and industry conditions." 7280 7281 We can't expect to get a higher return on investment over time than the 7282 7283 232 7284 7285 underlying business produces on its invested capital over time. Charles Munger says: 7286 7287 Over the long term, it's hard for a stock to earn a much better return than the business which underlies it earns. If the business earns 6% on capital over 40 years and you hold it for that 40 years, you're 7288 not going to make much different than a 6% return - even if you originally buy it at a huge discount. Conversely, if a business earns 18% on capital over 20 or 30 years, even if you pay an expensive looking 7289 price, you'll end up with a fine result. 7290 7291 Few companies can manage, over a ten to twenty-year period, to keep earning high returns on 20% or more on invested capital while reinvesting all or most of their earnings. Changes in the competitive arena, 7292 buyer habits, and the environment will make that almost a certainty. 7293 7294 Warren Buffett reveals the limits of earnings growth and how lofty predictions lead to dumb behavior: 7295 7296 Examine the record of, say, the 200 highest earning companies from 1970 or 1980 and tabulate how many have increased per-share earnings by 15% annually since those dates. You will find that only a handful 7297 have. I would wager you avery significant sum that fewer than 10 of the 200 most profitable companies in 2000 will attain 15% annual growth in earnings-per-share over the next 20 years. 7298 7299 He continues: 7300 7301 Finally, be suspICtous of companies that trumpet earnings projections and growth expectations. Businesses seldom operate in a tranquil, no-surprise environment, and earnings simply don't advance smoothly 7302 (except, of course, in the offering books of investment bankers). 7303 7304 Charlie and I not only don't know today what our businesses will earn [3mnext year [0m- we don't even know what they will earn [3mnext quarter. [0mWe are suspicious of those CEOs who regularly claim they do know the 7305 future - and we become downright incredulous if they consistently reach their declared targets. Managers that always promise to "make the numbers" will at some point be tempted to [3mmake up [0mthe numbers. 7306 7307 Suddenly demand goes down and price competition rises. 7308 7309 How does a change in growth rate change business value? Business value is a function of the amount and timing of future cash flows. If cash flows decreases and/or appears further off in the future, business 7310 value declines. 7311 7312 233 7313 7314 Warren Buffett illustrates how valuations must change when growth expectations are revised: 7315 7316 A few years ago the conventional wisdom held that a newspaper, television or magazine property would forever increase its earnings at 6% or so annually and would do so without the employment of additional 7317 capital for the reason that depreciation charges would roughly match capital expenditures and working capital requirements would be minor. Therefore, reported earnings (before amortization of intangibles) 7318 were also freely distributable earnings, which meant that ownership of a media property could be construed as akin to owning a perpetual annuity set to grow at 6% a year. Say, next, that a discount rate of 7319 10% was used to determine the present value of that earnings stream. One could then calculate that it was appropriate to pay a whopping $25 million for a property with current after-tax earnings of $1 million 7320 (1/0.1-0.06). 7321 7322 Now change the assumption and posit that the $1 million represents "normal earning power" and that earnings will bob around this figure cyclically. A "bob-around" pattern is indeed the lot of most businesses, 7323 whose income stream grows only if their owners are willing to commit more capital (usually in the form of retained earnings). Under our revised assumption, $1 million of earnings, discounted by the same 10%, 7324 translates to a 7325 7326 $10 million valuation. Thus a seemingly modest shift in assumptions reduce the property's valuation to 10 times after-tax earnings. 7327 7328 Do we pay the same price for a business financed with debt as for a business with no debt? 7329 7330 Assume Mary is interested in buying a furniture store. The business is stable with no growth, free cash flow of 15 and financed with 75 in equity. A price of 100 (15/0.15) will give her a 15% return. Does 7331 debt make a difference? Yes, the seller could then make extra money by leveraging the business before selling it.If the seller refinances the business with 50 in debt (and the business can borrow at 6% 7332 interest) and withdraws 50 as a dividend, income after interest would be 12 (15-3). If Mary then buys the store for 80 (12/0.15) the seller would have made an extra 30 (50+80- 7333 7334 100) without any change in the underlying operations of the business. 7335 7336 Instead Mary should assume she acquires a debt-free business and adjust for 50 of debt and pay 50 (15/0.15-50). She should also correct (add to the price) for excess cash - cash or cash assets that aren't 7337 needed to conduct the business. 7338 7339 This is the same type of reasoning as when we buy a house. If we for example 7340 7341 buy a house for $500,000 and put in $200,000 of our own saved money and mortgage the rest or $300,000, the price of the house is still $500,000. 7342 7343 234 7344 7345 "The synergies we expected from the merger never materialized They were mere illusions. " 7346 7347 Don't forget to quantify consequences when making acquisitions. Take the profit & loss statement and balance sheet of the acquiring company and the target company. Calculate what happens with volume, prices, 7348 cost, and invested capital when the companies combine, considering consequences and behavioral changes of employees, suppliers, customers, and competition. How does business value change? Be realistic. 7349 Studies show that most mergers fail to generate value for the acquiring company's owners. The main reason is that the buyer paid too much for synergies that weren't real. 7350 7351 "Of one thing, however, be certain," says Warren Buffett, "If a CEO is enthused about a particularly foolish acquisition, both his internal staff and his outside advisors will come up with whatever 7352 projections are needed to justify his stance. Only in fairy tales are emperors told they are naked." 7353 7354 john reads the paper. A company announced a $10 million contract and its market capitalization jumped $1 billion. 7355 7356 Does this make sense? If we assume the contract generates a 15% profit margin, 7357 7358 the implied market value increase is $1.5 million. And even a high-margin project can be a loser if it requires a lot of capital and human resources. 7359 7360 If present value is the same for different businesses, does the timing of the dividend matter? 7361 7362 Assume there are 2 different businesses -X and Y -with the following forecasted dividends. After year 5 the two companies close down. 7363 7364 Year 7365 7366 1 7367 7368 2 7369 7370 3 7371 7372 4 7373 7374 5 7375 7376 Dividends from X 7377 7378 10 7379 7380 10 7381 7382 10 7383 7384 10 7385 7386 10 7387 7388 Dividends from Y 7389 7390 0 7391 7392 0 7393 7394 0 7395 7396 0 7397 7398 61 7399 7400 All cash generated by X is each year distributed to its owners. The free cash flow generated by Y is reinvested and not paid out until after the five year period. Assuming we want a 10% return, the present 7401 value of X's respective Y's dividends are the same or about 38. But this assumes that we can reinvest our dividends from X at 10% so that we have 61 after 5 years. It also assumes that Y can reinvest their 7402 cash flow at rates that cause the dividend to be 61 after 5 years. But in both cases the future may turn out different than expected. The business environment may change and competition increase making the 7403 dividends from X and Y come 7404 7405 235 7406 7407 out differently from what we expect. The more our calculation depends on cash flows far out in the future, the more opportunities there are for unwanted events, and the more uncertain our expected return. 7408 7409 Do the math! 7410 7411 We can do a simple exercise to test our possible return from investing in a company and if its market valuation makes sense. Just think about the math implicit. 7412 7413 Below are some examples where we have ignored dividends and options (in reality we need to properly account for options and make sure that the company's accounting reflects reality and the true operational 7414 performance.) Think of a stock as part of a business and remember that small changes in assumptions can dramatically change value. 7415 7416 John is thinking of buying 1,000 shares of stock in a public ice cream manufacturer with a market value of $1 billion and no debt or off-balance sheet obligations. How should John reason? 7417 7418 What is my estimated annual rate of return? 7419 7420 John projects the future value, and then compares that value with the present market value of $1 billion. What is his implied annual rate of return? Will the price paid give him an adequate return? 7421 7422 The business has initial cash earnings (earnings+ amortization of goodwill) of 7423 7424 $40 million and an assumed average annual growth rate in cash earnings of 10% for 10 years. This translates into $104 million in cash earnings in year 10. Assume the market pays an average multiple of 15 for 7425 this type of business. This implies 7426 7427 $1.56 billion in market value in year 10. If John compares this figure with the present market value, his implied yearly return is 4.5%. John compares this return with the return from other available 7428 investment opportunities. A business may have a great track record, but if the math doesn't work, stay away. 7429 7430 What scenario achieves a 15% annual rate of return? 7431 7432 How much must the ice cream manufacturer earn to generate a 15% annual rate of return for John? If the present market value compounds at 15%, what does this imply and is it reasonable? 7433 7434 A present market value of $1 billion and an annual return of 15% imply $4 billion in market value in year 10. This is what $1 billion will grow to in 10 years if it grows 15% per year. An average multiple of 7435 15 implies $270 million in cash earnings in year 10. This translates into an average annual growth rate in cash earnings of 21% (from a base of $40 million). A profit margin of 15% implies 7436 7437 236 7438 7439 $1.8 billion in sales year 10. He can continue with implied future sales volume, number of users and usage, market share, etc. 7440 7441 John then asks: What causes this future value? What does this imply in numbers today? Is it reasonable regarding evidence of track record in growth, earnings, profit margins, market size/volume growth, market 7442 share, competitive advantage, etc? Which factor has the greatest impact on future cash earnings and thereby value? What forces can change this scenario? How can the company lose its advantages? 7443 7444 If the company doesn't make money today, what future free cash flow is implied by their market value if I want a 10% return? 7445 7446 In the midst of the Internet mania, Warren Buffett said: 7447 7448 When we buy a stock, we always think in terms of buying the whole enterprise because it enables us to think as businessmen rather than stock speculators. So let's just take a company that has marvelous 7449 prospects, that paying you nothing now where you buy it at a valuation of$500 billion... For example, let's assume that there's only going to be a one year delay before the business starts paying out to you 7450 and you want to get a 10% return. If you paid $500 billion, then $55 billion in cash is the amount that it's going to have to 7451 7452 be able to disgorge to you year after year after year. To do that, it has to make perhaps $80 billion, or close to it, pretax. Look around at the universe of businesses in this world and see how many are 7453 earning $80 billion pretax - or $70 billion or $60 or $50 or $40 or even 7454 7455 $30 billion. You won't find any. 7456 7457 Whether a business sells nails or telecom equipment, if more money is going out than coming in, on a present value basis, it is worthless. As Warren Buffett says, "Value is destroyed, not created, by any 7458 business that loses money over its lifetime, no matter how high its interim valuation may get." 7459 7460 He continues: 7461 7462 There's plenty of magic in short term in rising P/E multiples and the games people play with accounting and so on. But in the end, you can't get more out of a business between now and its extinction than the 7463 business makes. And actually you'll make something less depending on who your business managers are, how often there's turnover in the security and how much you pay the investment manager and so on. 7464 7465 237 7466 7467 - NINE - 7468 7469 EVIDENCE 7470 7471 It is undesirable to believe a proposition when there is no ground whatsoever for supposing it true. 7472 7473 - Bertrand Russell 7474 7475 Evidence helps us prove what is likely to happen or likely to be true or false. Evidence comes from facts, observations, experiences, comparisons, and experiments. 7476 7477 The methods of science 7478 7479 There are in fact two things: science and opinion; the former begets knowledge, the latter ignorance. 7480 7481 - Hippocrates 7482 7483 "What experiment can I do to figure this out?" 7484 7485 In 1986, the space shuttle Challenger exploded on launch, killing all astronauts aboard. After the disaster, NASA put together a commission where Richard Feynman showed that the fuel booster rockets were not 7486 safe when the temperature was cold. The temperature at takeoff was 32 F. During a launch, vibrations cause the rocket joints to move. Inside the rocket joints there were rubber O-rings that are used in a 7487 certain key stage in the space shuttle's fuel delivery system. 7488 7489 Richard Feynman did a simple experiment with a rubber O-ring from the Challenger rocket. He squeezed the rings in a C-clamp and dipped them in a glass of ice water (32 F) and showed that the rubber didn't 7490 expand. Since there was no resilience in the rubber at 32 F, the O-ring could not fill the gap in the expanding rocket booster joints. It consequently caused an explosion of the booster and the space shuttle. 7491 7492 This also illustrates that an experiment doesn't have to be complicated. 7493 7494 Do what scientists do: Strive for objectivity. Scientists try to describe the world as it is, not as they want it to be. They seek to answer "why" and "how" questions and try to predict natural phenomena and 7495 processes by using methods of scientific integrity. Adam Smith said in An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of 7496 7497 238 7498 7499 the Wealth of Nations: "Science is the great antidote to the poison of enthusiasm and superstition." 7500 7501 The scientific process involves the following steps (of course, trial and error, luck and intuition also matters - scientists use any methods that help them solve a problem): 7502 7503 Problem or observation - We try to figure something out. We have a problem or we observe some phenomena and wonder what happens and why (what matters is what actually happens). 7504 7505 Guess [1mwhy- [0mWe try to find a possible solution or an explanation (a hypothesis of why or how something happens) that can be proved or disproved by testing it against experiment and observation. Maybe some rule 7506 or model can solve the problem or explain our observation. Our guess must be measurable and agree with nature and proven evidence. 7507 7508 Predict consequences - We work out all logical consequences of our guess and see what would be implied if our guess was right. 7509 7510 Test - "If I do this, what will happen?" Testability is key. We compare the implied consequences of our guess with experiment, evidence and observation. We repeat the experiment against error, fraud, 7511 coincidence, and change in circumstances or environment. We report our results honestly. The more evidence that agrees with our guess, the more likely the guess was right. If the guess disagrees with 7512 experiment or evidence, it is wrong. As Richard Feynman says: 7513 7514 It does not make any difference how beautiful your guess is. It does not make any difference how smart you are, who made the guess, or what his name is - if it disagrees with experiment it is wrong. 7515 7516 Darwin realized that for an observation to be of any use, it must be tested for or against a theory, hypothesis or model (if we don't "guess why", there can be no experiments since a test has nothing to guide 7517 it). On board the HMS Beagle, in a letter to his friend Henry Fawcett, Darwin wrote: 7518 7519 About thirty years ago there was much talk that geologists ought only to observe and not to theorize; and I well remember someone saying that at this rate a man might as well go into agravel pit and count the 7520 pebbles and describe the colours. How odd it is that anyone should not see that all observation must be for or against some view if it is to be of any service! 7521 7522 We don't merely observe some behavior; we observe with some purpose in mind or in light of some theory or with some background about what is important to 7523 7524 239 7525 7526 look for. It is the same when we search for information. Charles Munger says: 7527 7528 ... you have to have some idea of why you're looking for the information. Don't read annual reports the way Francis Bacon said you do science ... where you just collect endless [amounts of] data and then only 7529 later do you try to make sense ofit. You have to start with some ideas of reality. And then you have to look to see whether what you're seeing fits in with that basic thought structure. 7530 7531 Occam's Razor is a principle attributed to the 14th Century logician William of Occam: "Entities should not be multiplied unnecessarily." If we face two possible explanations which make the same predictions, 7532 the one based on the least number of unproven assumptions is preferable, until more evidence comes along. Occam doesn't rule out other explanations. To paraphrase Albert Einstein: "Theories should be as 7533 simple as possible, but no simpler." 7534 7535 Finding evidence from the past 7536 7537 Study the past if you would divine the future. 7538 7539 - Confucius 7540 7541 john is thinking of hiring a new manager. Does the managers past record matter? 7542 7543 Warren Buffett says: 7544 7545 The best judgment we can make about managerial competence does not depend on what people say, but simply what the record shows. At Berkshire Hathaway, when we buy a business we usually keep whoever has been 7546 running it, so we already have a batting average. Take the case of Mrs. B. who ran our Furniture Mart. Over a SO-year period, we'd seen her take $500 and turn it into a business that made $18 million pretax. 7547 So we knew she was competent ... Clearly, the lesson here is that the past record is the best single guide. 7548 7549 Then you run into the problem of the 14-year-old horse. Let's say you buy The Daily Racing Form and it shows that the horse won the Kentucky Derby as a four-year-old. Based on past performance, you know this 7550 was one hell of a horse. But now he's 14 and can barely move. So you have to ask yourself, "Is there anything about the past record that makes it a poor guideline as a forecaster of the future?" 7551 7552 The following questions help us decide if past evidence is representative for the future: 7553 7554 Observation: Will past/present behavior continue? How long can it continue? 7555 7556 240 7557 7558 Explanation: Why did it happen in the past or why does it happen now? How did it happen? We must understand the reasons why a past outcome occurred. What are the key factors? This demands that we understand 7559 the equation - the key variables involved and their relationships. Start with a hypothesis. Compare the implied consequences of our explanation of causes with appropriate evidence 7560 7561 - for and against. 7562 7563 Predictability: How predictive (representative) is the past/present evidence for what is likely to happen in the future? Are the conditions now and in the future likely to change? Make sure that the evidence 7564 isn't random. What worked in the past could have been the result of chance. 7565 7566 [1mContinuation and Change: [0mWhat is required to make the past/ present record continue or to achieve the goal (look at the equation again)? What must happen? What must not happen? What forces can change it or 7567 cause what we don't want? Likely? Antidotes to what we don't want to happen? 7568 7569 Certainty and Consequences: How certain am I? What single event am I betting on that must happen or not happen? What are the consequences of being wrong? 7570 7571 Falsify and disprove 7572 7573 All our commonsense ideas should always be open to criticism. 7574 7575 - Karl Popper (Austrian-British philosopher, 1902-1994) 7576 7577 Scientific results always have some probability attached to them. Tomorrow may bring new evidence. Instead of verifying a statement, it is sometimes better to prove it false. A single piece of evidence in 7578 favor of a statement does not prove its truth - it only supports it. But a single piece of evidence against it will show that it is false. Albert Einstein said: "No number of experiments can prove me right; a 7579 single experiment can prove me wrong." 7580 7581 "All swans are white. " 7582 7583 How could we test this statement? We could open our eyes, and go out looking for non-white swans. If we find one swan that is not white we have disproved the statement. The more swans we find to be white, the 7584 more support the statement has. But it is not proven. One black swan and the statement is rejected. 7585 7586 "The universe is no more than 10,000 years old." 7587 7588 What experiment can we perform to falsify this statement? We can look up at the sky and observe stars that are millions of light-years away. This means we are seeing them as they were millions of years ago. 7589 7590 241 7591 7592 "The medical treatment worked. Tm cured. " "Compared to what?" 7593 7594 How can we test whether a cure is due to treatment, good salesmanship, the power of suggestion, or the patient's imagination? To reduce error and bias, medical research uses a randomized, double blind 7595 placebo-controlled study. Research subjects are randomly divided in two groups that match each other in age, physical status and other factors. One group receives the treatment and the other group the 7596 placebo. Neither the research subjects nor the researchers know who's getting the treatment or the placebo. Then the researchers compare the effects. 7597 7598 "There is no risk in using this medicine. " 7599 7600 That there is no evidence of harm (or benefit) isn't the same as evidence that something is safe (or harmful). Only safe (or harmful) based on what we know so far. Compare archaeology - just because something 7601 hasn't been found doesn't mean it won't be found. 7602 7603 Disprove ideas. Charles Darwin always looked at the possibility that he was wrong: 7604 7605 I had, also, during many years, followed a golden rule, namely, that whenever a published fact, a new observation or thought came across me, which was opposed to my general results, to make a memorandum of it 7606 without fail and at once: for I had found by experience that such facts and thoughts were far more apt to escape from the memory than favourable ones. Owing to this habit, very few objections were raised 7607 against my views which I had not at least noticed and attempted to answer ... 7608 7609 I think that I have become a little more skillful in guessing right explanations and in devising experimental tests; but this may probably be the result of mere practice, and of a larger store of knowledge. I 7610 have as much difficulty as ever in expressing myself clearly and concisely; and this difficulty has caused me a very great loss of time; but it has had the compensating advantage of forcing me to think long 7611 and intently about every sentence, and thus I have been led to see errors in reasoning and in my own observations or those of others. 7612 7613 "Since a lot of evidence agrees with my explanation, I must be right. " 7614 7615 Not necessarily, the same evidence may agree with other explanations. Look for evidence that disproves your explanation. 7616 7617 Don't spend time on already disproved ideas or arguments or those that can't be disproved. Ask: What test can disprove this? For example, someone tells us that there is life on planet Zeta. This can't be 7618 tested. That doesn't mean there is 7619 7620 242 7621 7622 no life on the planet. It only means that there is no way we can test it today. 7623 7624 Theories based on observations have priority over theories alone since observations can disprove theories. Galileo Galilei based his theories on observations in the debate whether the sun revolved around the 7625 Earth. 7626 7627 Engage in self-criticism. Question your assumptions. Explain the opposite of your beliefs. Ask: Assume I'm wrong, how will I know? Why may an opposite theory be correct? Assuming my answer is correct, what 7628 would cause me to change my mind? Then, look for that evidence. 7629 7630 Often we don't see our weaknesses and thus are not motivated to improve. Therefore, encourage the right people to give objective feedback that will help us improve. 7631 7632 Look back and measure how you are doing against your original expectations. 7633 7634 Find your mistakes early and correct them quickly before they cause harm. 7635 7636 The next tool forces us to be objective. Charles Munger says on backward thinking: 7637 7638 The mental habit of thinking backward [3mforces [0mobjectivity - because one of the ways you think a thing through backward is you take your initial assumption and say, "Let's try and [3mdisprove [0mit." 7639 7640 That is [3mnot [0mwhat most people do with their initial assumption. They try and [3mconfirm [0mit. It's an automatic tendency in psychology- often called "first-conclusion bias". But it's only a tendency. You can train 7641 yourself away from the tendency to a substantial degree. You just constantly take your own assumptions and try and disprove them. 7642 7643 243 7644 7645 - TEN - 7646 7647 BACKWARD THINKING 7648 7649 Alot of success in life and success in business comes from knowing what you really want to avoid - like early death and a bad marriage. 7650 7651 Charles Munger 7652 7653 Avoid what causes the opposite of what you want to achieve. 7654 7655 "You must always invert," said the 19th Century German mathematician Karl Jacobi when asked the secret of his mathematical discoveries. Whenever we try to achieve a goal, solve problems, predict what is 7656 likely to happen or likely to be true or false, we should think things through backwards. 7657 7658 At the weekly meeting with his managers, John asked· "What actions could our company take to destroy as much value as possible in as short time as possible?" "Treat the employees badly. Reward bad work. Don't 7659 appeal to the employee's self interests but to a goal no one understands. Don't inform people what the company stands for, what rules apply, and the consequences for breaking them. Make sure people don't know 7660 their areas of responsibility. Put the right person in the wrong place. Don't let people know if they achieve a goal. Everything should be impossible to measure. Never tell people why something should be 7661 done. 7662 7663 Surround the CEO with confused, unmotivated subordinates. Give key customers reasons to be angry. Late and wrong deliveries, delays, and arrogance will help. Let the customers associate the business with 7664 misery and make sure that this feeling gets reinforced at every contact with the company." 7665 7666 Thinking backwards, we can determine what actions must be avoided. As Charles Munger says, "If you were hired by the World Bank to help India, it would be very helpful to determine the three best ways to 7667 increase man-years of misery in India - and, then, turn around and avoid those ways." 7668 7669 Instead of asking how we can achieve a goal, we ask the opposite question: What don't I want to achieve (non-goal)? What causes the non-goal? How can I avoid that? What do I now want to achieve? How can I do 7670 that? For example, instead of searching for how John and Mary can improve their marriage, they ask: "What qualities will destroy our marriage?" One quality is dishonesty. Now they 7671 7672 244 7673 7674 reinvert the question back and ask: "How can we improve our marriage?" Be honest. (See also Charles Munger's brilliant speech on prescriptions for guaranteed misery in Appendix One). 7675 7676 Charles Munger provides an enlightening example on how dumb systems cause dumb behavior: 7677 7678 Let's say you have a desire to do public service. As a natural part of your planning, you think in reverse and ask, "What can I do to ruin our civilization?" That's easy. If what you want to do is to ruin 7679 your civilization, just go to the legislature and pass laws that create systems wherein people can easily cheat. It will work perfectly. Take the workers' compensation system in California. Stress is real And 7680 its misery can be real. So you want 7681 7682 to compensate people for their stress in the workplace. It seems like a noble thing to do. But the trouble with such a compensation practice is that it's practically impossible to delete huge cheating. And 7683 once you reward cheating, you get crooked lawyers, crooked doctors, crooked unions, etc. participating in referral schemes. You get a total miasma of disastrous behavior. And the behavior makes all the people 7684 doing it worse as they do it. So you were trying to help your civilization. But what you did was create enormous damage, net. So it's much better to let some things go uncompensated - to let life be hard - 7685 than 7686 7687 to create systems that are easy to cheat. 7688 7689 "Don't think about the color red!" 7690 7691 If someone told you not to think of the color red, you might automatically think of that color. Why? Because in order to know what not to think about, your brain must first think about it. When John is on a 7692 golf course trying to hit over a water hazard in front of the green, he doesn't say to himself, "I don't want to hit the ball in the water," but instead "I want to hit the ball on the green." So when we tell 7693 people what to avoid, we should end with what we want them to achieve. 7694 7695 Study errors. 7696 7697 Marcus Porcius Cato wrote: "Wise men profit more from fools than fools from wise men; for the wise men shun the mistakes of the fools, but fools do not imitate the successes of the wise." 7698 7699 To reduce mistakes, we should study failures with severe consequences. Both in business and in life. We should look at their causes over time and see if they are unchanged. 7700 7701 Often we learn more from understanding why something doesn't work than from why it does. Studies also show that dramatic error-story training is an 7702 7703 245 7704 7705 effective method of learning. Errors are salient and memorable. Studying errors encourage effortful thinking, and improves our capacity to deal with change and new or unusual situations. Ask: Why did that 7706 happen? Why do certain businesses lose money or fail? Why do smart people engage in foolish behavior? Why do certain accidents happen? What was the mistake that caused bad performance? What circumstances were 7707 present? What's the lesson? 7708 7709 When we know this, we should ask: What people or businesses are doing things that history has proven causes failure? How can we best avoid what we don't want to happen? How can we create the best conditions 7710 to avoid mistakes? How can we prevent causes that can't be eliminated? How can we limit the consequences of what we want to avoid? How can we limit the probability of what we want to avoid? 7711 7712 We can organize the study of errors, by using a table like the one below. 7713 7714 What to avoid 7715 7716 What were the mistakes? 7717 7718 Cause Antidote 7719 7720 Why did those happen? What are the major risk factors? 7721 7722 How do specific errors evolve? What factors contribute? 7723 7724 Stupidity/Irrationality 7725 7726 Big idea that helps explain and predict? 7727 7728 What is rational? How can I create the best conditions to make good decisions? What can be eliminated or prevented? 7729 7730 Turn the negative into an advantage. 7731 7732 In 1796, British physician Edward Jenner discovered vaccination. He noticed that milkmaids who had contracted a mild and usually non-lethal form of the pox virus - cowpox - seemed to be immune to the lethal 7733 form of the virus, smallpox. He then took samples of a milkmaid's lesions and inoculated a young boy with cowpox. The boy built up antibodies in his immune system that prevented him from getting smallpox and 7734 subsequently survived the epidemic. 7735 7736 Begin with the end in mind 7737 7738 In the 4th Century the Greek mathematician Pappus of Alexandria wrote: "Let us start with what is being seeked and assume that we already found it." Assume we've achieved our goal, then ask: What was the 7739 purpose? Was this what I wanted? If so, from which earlier position do I get there? What is needed to achieve this? Then work backward to the beginning. By working backwards we can easier see 7740 7741 246 7742 7743 how and if something may work. An example of this is retrospective disease studies. Researchers study the disease then work backward to see what prior conditions are associated with it. 7744 7745 "We need discipline in schools. " 7746 7747 What would be the consequences if this statement were false? Turn a statement backwards and show that the opposite is worse. What are the consequences? Unbelievable or negative? Suppose there was no 7748 discipline in schools, would there be more behavior we don't want? 7749 7750 When we believe we have arrived at the right judgment, we should consider what could cause the opposite of our prediction -what we don't want to happen. Suppose we make a personality judgment and conclude 7751 that the individual is of good character and we want to enter a relationship. Ask: What can ruin this relationship? What causes me to misjudge character? 7752 7753 Other uses of backward thinking are: Study evidence that implies the opposite of what is normal and ask "why." Use "negative" rules - tell people what they can't do. Practice zero base thinking - start with a 7754 clean sheet of paper and ask: If we weren't already doing what we do, how can we best achieve our goal? 7755 7756 Next chapter is about risk or the possibility of loss. If we put our head in the lion's mouth, we shouldn't be surprised if it's bitten off. 7757 7758 247 7759 7760 - ELEVEN - 7761 7762 RISK 7763 7764 Alife without adventure is likely to be unsatisfying, but a life in which adventure is allowed to take whatever form it will is sure to be short. 7765 7766 Bertrand Russell (from Authority and the Individual) 7767 7768 "Why do you want to buy this stock?What must happen for the investment to succeed? What is the downside?" 7769 7770 Reflect on what can go wrong. Ask: What may cause this to turn into a catastrophe? What is the potential downside? What should I worry about? What is the likelihood and magnitude of a possible loss? What's 7771 the worst thing chat could happen? What can I do to prevent it? What will I do if it happens? 7772 7773 We need to look at the downside when we invest. According to Forbes 7774 7775 Magazine, Charles Munger's way of reasoning is: 7776 7777 The simple fact is that you can't tell whether an idea is likely to work unless you consider all the possible negatives... Okay, it's a good company. But is the price low enough? Is the management made up of 7778 people Munger and Buffett are comfortable with? If it is cheap enough to buy, is it cheap for the wrong reason or the right reason? As Munger puts it: "What's the flip side, what can go wrong that I haven't 7779 seen?" 7780 7781 Being wrong causes both an actual loss and an opportunity cost. When investing, we can either lose our capital - we invest 10 and get back 5 - or we get an inadequate return - for example 3% versus 6% from a 7782 bond. What does Warren Buffett say about business risk? 7783 7784 When we look at businesses, we try to look at businesses that are good businesses today and think about what can go wrong. We think of business risk in terms of what can happen five, 10 or 15 years from now 7785 that will destroy, modify or reduce the economic strengths we believe currently exist in the business. And for some businesses, that's impossible to figure - at least it's impossible for us to figure - and we 7786 don't even think about it. If we can think of very much that can go wrong, we just forget it. 7787 7788 248 7789 7790 Warren Buffett says that "the best way to minimize risk is to think". He also tells us how Berkshire reduces risk: 7791 7792 In stocks, we expect every commitment to work out well because we concentrate on conservatively financed businesses with strong competitive strengths, run by able and honest people. If we buy into these 7793 companies at sensible prices, losses should be rare. Indeed, during the 38 years we have run the company's affairs, gains from the equities we manage at Berkshire (that is, excluding those managed at General 7794 Re and GEICO) have exceeded losses by a ratio of about 100 to one. 7795 7796 Do we need to take a lot of risks to get ahead in life? Charles Munger tells a story: 7797 7798 I had a relative by marriage who died in his late 80s. And I don't think he ever had a loss. He only did about eight things in his lifetime. He started with a small poke, and if something wasn't a near cinch, 7799 he didn't do it. He lived well and died rich. I think it's possible for a great many people to live a life like that where there isn't much risk of disaster and where they're virtually sure to get ahead a 7800 reasonable amount. It takes a lot of judgment, a lot of discipline and an absence of hyperactivity. By this method, I think most intelligent people can take a lot of risk out oflife. 7801 7802 A fool and his money are soon parted 7803 7804 What traits are necessary to be an outstanding long-term investor? Warren Buffett gives us some clues in Berkshire Hathaway's 2006 Chairman's letter, where he mentions Berkshire's intention of hiring someone 7805 to succeed him as Berkshire's chief investment officer when the need arises: 7806 7807 Picking the right person(s) will not be an easy task. It's not hard, of course, to find smart people, among them individuals who have impressive investment records. But there is far more to successful 7808 long-term investing than brains and performance that has recently been good. 7809 7810 Over time, markets will do extraordinarily, even bizarre things. A single, big mistake 7811 7812 could wipe out a long string of successes. We therefore need someone genetically programmed to recognize and avoid serious risks, including those never before encountered. Certain perils that lurk in 7813 investment strategies cannot be spotted by use of the models commonly employed today by financial institutions. 7814 7815 Temperament is also important. Independent thinking, emotional stability, and a keen understanding of both human and institutional behavior is vital to long-term investment success. 7816 7817 249 7818 7819 The consequences of being wrong 7820 7821 If we can't tolerate a possible consequence, remote though it may be, we steer clear of planting its seeds. 7822 7823 - Warren Buffett 7824 7825 Experience tells me that the foture will be similar to the past. 7826 7827 It may or may not. We don't know the future. What if the consequences of being wrong are terrible and can cause us great harm? If the decision is important, we should largely ignore what has happened in the 7828 past and focus on the consequences of being wrong. 7829 7830 Why do we insure our houses? We do it because the consequences of being wrong 7831 7832 - a fire - is devastating, and the cost of insurance is relatively minor in comparison. For example, the cost of a $1.000 premium decreases my happiness very little, while the potential loss of $300,000 would 7833 lead to considerable misery. Ask: What could go wrong? What can I do to prevent harm or to deal with it if it happens? 7834 7835 john wants to buy another ice cream store. 7836 7837 The key variable he's betting on is that "Unit volume will increase." What are the consequences ifhe is wrong? 7838 7839 The worse the consequence of being wrong, the less inclined we must be to 7840 7841 take a specific action or the more evidence we need in favor of something. 7842 7843 Ask: What is the cost of being wrong versus the benefit of being right compared to other investment opportunities? Cost: John may lose money, reputation, and experience mental stress. It will also take his 7844 focus away from other business. Benefit: Possibility to make more money over a period of time. Alternative: More time to concentrate on the present business or other opportunities. 7845 7846 Or stated another way: Ifl do this because I bet that unit volume will increase but I'm wrong (volume remains the same or decreases due to less demand and more competition or unfavorable environment) what are 7847 the consequences? Can I handle them? Are they reversible? IfI don't do this because I bet that unit volume will go down or stay the same, but I'm wrong, what are the consequences? In which alternative do I 7848 lose less? 7849 7850 Margin of safety 7851 7852 We try to arrange [our affairs] so that no matter what happens, we'll never have to 'go back to go. " 7853 7854 Charles Munger 7855 7856 250 7857 7858 Albert Einstein said: "Whoever undertakes to set himself up as a judge of truth and knowledge is shipwrecked by the laughter of the gods." We can't predict what is going to happen in life. Never underestimate 7859 the chance of rare events. 7860 7861 To protect us from all the unknowns that lie ahead we can either avoid certain situations, make decisions that work out for a wide range of outcomes, have backups or a huge margin of safety. For example, when 7862 investing money the following can guide us: know the underlying business value, don't use leverage, enter situations where the management is able and honest, and invest with a huge margin of safety. 7863 7864 How much margin of safety do we need? Warren Buffett answers: 7865 7866 If you understand a business - if you can see its future perfectly- then, obviously, you need very little in the way of margin of safety. Conversely, the more things that can happen, the more uncertainty 7867 there is, the more vulnerable the business is or the greater the possibility of change, the larger margin of safety you require... 7868 7869 If you're driving a 9,800 pound truck across a bridge that says it holds 10,000 pounds and the bridge is only about six inches above the ground, then you may feel OK. However, if the bridge is over the Grand 7870 Canyon, then you may want a little larger margin of safety. And, therefore, you may only drive a 4,000 pound truck across. So it depends on the nature of the underlying risk. 7871 7872 What else is important? We have a better chance of avoiding misjudgment and improving our lives if we have the right attitude and follow certain values. 7873 7874 In writer Janet Lowe's wonderful biography of Charles Munger, [3mDamn Right!, [0mwe can learn some of Charles Munger's views on values and behavior from his stepson, Hal Borthwick: 7875 7876 Charlie drummed in the notion that a person should always "Do the best that you can do. Never tell a lie. If you say you're going to do it, get it done. Nobody gives a shit about an excuse. Leave for the 7877 meeting early. Don't be late, but if you are late, don't bother giving people excuses. Just apologize... Return your calls quickly. The other thing is the five second no. You've got to make your mind up. You 7878 don't leave people hanging." 7879 7880 251 7881 7882 - TWELVE - 7883 7884 ATTITUDES 7885 7886 Be happy while you're living, for you are a long time dead. 7887 7888 Scottish proverb 7889 7890 Life is long if we know how to use it 7891 7892 The Roman philosopher Lucius Annaeus Seneca tells us in his Moral Essays that it's not that we have so little time but that we waste much of it: 7893 7894 Why do we complain of Nature? She has shown herself kindly; life, if you know how to use it, is long. But one man is possessed by an avarice that is insatiable, another by a toilsome devotion to tasks that 7895 are useless; one man is besotted with wine, another is paralyzed by sloth; one man is exhausted by an ambition that always hangs upon the decision of others, another, driven on by the greed of the trader, is 7896 led over all lands and all seas by the hope of gain... many are kept busy either in the pursuit of other men's fortune or in complaining of their own; many, following no fixed aim, shifting and inconstant and 7897 dissatisfied, are plunged by their fickleness into plans that are ever new; some have no fixed principle bywhich to direct their course, but Fate takes them unawares while they loll and yawn - so surely does 7898 it happen that I cannot doubt the truth of that utterance which the greatest of poets delivered with all the seeming of an oracle: "The part of life we really live is small." For all the rest of existence is 7899 not life, but merely time. 7900 7901 He continues: "You live as if you were destined to live forever, no thought of your frailty ever enters your head, of how much time has already gone by you take no heed.": 7902 7903 You squander time as if you drew from a full and abundant supply, though all the while that day which you bestow on some person or thing is perhaps your last. You have all the fears of mortals and all the 7904 desires of immortals. You will hear many men saying: "After my fiftieth year I shall retire into leisure, my sixtieth year shall release me from public duties." And what guarantee, pray, have you that your 7905 life will last longer? Who will suffer your course to be just as you plan it? Are you not ashamed to reserve for yourself only the remnant of life, and to set apart for wisdom only that time which cannot be 7906 devoted to 7907 7908 252 7909 7910 any business? How late it is to begin to live just when we must cease to live! What foolish forgetfulness of mortality to postpone wholesome plans to the fiftieth and sixtieth year, and to intend to begin 7911 life at a point to which few have attained! 7912 7913 Life is too short to waste. Samuel Johnson said: "It matters not how a man dies, but how he lives. The act of dying is not of importance, it lasts so short a time." We only have one life so we should try to 7914 create a life we enjoy. Comedian George Burns said: "You can either do what you love or love what you do. I don't 7915 7916 see there's any other choice." 7917 7918 We all have 24 hours in the day. We can't save time, only spend it wisely or foolishly. How do we use our time? What is the best use? What do we want out of life? Do we live in a way to make that possible? 7919 The shorter the list, the more likely it is to focus on things that matter. Know what we want and don't want. Do we do what we want to do or what others expect us to do? Who or what is most important in our 7920 life? Do we have a sense of meaning? 7921 7922 Part of avoiding misjudgments and improving our lives is having the right attitude toward life. Since people are different, there is no one-size-fits-all strategy. We each must figure out our own style. But 7923 there are guidelines that apply to us all. 7924 7925 We should act in a way that agrees with our nature, advantages and limitations and we should establish (and follow) some values. 7926 7927 How can we expect to succeed in a field we don't understand? We reduce the likelihood of making mistakes if we deal with things that agree with our nature, and things we understand and do well. We have a 7928 better chance solving problems and evaluating statements if they are within our area of competence. Confucius said: "To know that we know what we know, and that we do not know, what we do not know; that is 7929 true knowledge." We must determine our abilities and limitations. We need to know what we don't know or are not capable of knowing and avoid those areas. As Warren Buffett says: 7930 7931 You have to stick within what I call your circle of competence. You have to know what you understand and what you don't understand. It's not terribly important how big the circle is. But it's terribly 7932 important that you know where the perimeter is. 7933 7934 Charles Munger adds: 7935 7936 We'd rather deal with what we understand. Why should we want to play a competitive game in a field where we have no advantage - maybe a disadvantage - instead of playing in a field where we have a clear 7937 advantage? 7938 7939 253 7940 7941 Each of you will have to figure out where your talents lie. And you'll have to use your advantages. But if you try to succeed in what you're worst at, you're going to have a very louse career. I can almost 7942 guarantee it. To do otherwise, you'd have to buy a winning lottery ticket or get very lucky somewhere else. 7943 7944 Ask: What is my nature? What motivates me? What is my tolerance for pain and risk? What has given me happiness and unhappiness in the past? What things and people am I comfortable with? What are my talents 7945 and skills? Do I know the difference between what I want and what I'm good at? Where do I have an edge over others? What are my limitations? 7946 7947 How can we do what is important if we don't have any values? If we don't stand for something, we fall for anything. 7948 7949 Be honest 7950 7951 Honesty is the first chapter of the book of wisdom. 7952 7953 - Thomas Jefferson (American President 1743-1826) 7954 7955 Act honorably. Listen to the words of Mark Twain: "Always do right. This will gratify some people and astonish the rest." 7956 7957 Tell the truth. Follow Lou Vincenti's rule (former Chairman ofWesco): "If you tell the truth you don't have to remember your lies." 7958 7959 Honesty pays. Charles Munger says: "More often we've made extra money out of morality. Ben Franklin was right for us. He didn't say honesty was the best morals, he said that it was the best policy." 7960 7961 Act with integrity and individuality. Heraclitus said: "The content of your character is your choice. Day by day, what you choose, what you think, and what you do is who you become. Your integrity is your 7962 destiny.. .it is the light that guides your way." 7963 7964 Every human being is unique so we have the right to be different. Why is integrity the real freedom? Because if we have nothing to hide we have nothing to fear. 7965 7966 Charles Munger says: 7967 7968 We think there should be a huge area between ... what you are willing to do and what you can do without a significant risk of suffering criminal penalty or causing losses. We believe you shouldn't go anywhere 7969 near that line. You ought to have an internal compass. So there should be all kinds of things you won't do even though they're perfectly legal. That's the way we try to operate. 7970 7971 254 7972 7973 Stay out of anything questionable and deal with honorable people. Use the Warren Buffett "front-page test:" "Would I be willing to see my action immediately described by an informed and critical reporter on 7974 the front page of my local paper, there to be read by my spouse, children and friends?" 7975 7976 Trusting people is efficient. Charles Munger says: "Good character is very efficient. If you can trust people, your systems can be way simpler. There's enormous efficiency in good character and dis-efficiency 7977 in bad character." 7978 7979 Act as an exemplar 7980 7981 Wealth is a blessing to those who know how to use it, a curse to those who don't. 7982 7983 - Publius Terentius 7984 7985 Observe what signals you send out. Charles Munger tells us that some people have a duty to create the right appearance: ''A person who rises high in the Army or becomes a Supreme Court justice is expected to 7986 be an exemplar, so why shouldn't someone who rises high in a big corporation act as an exemplar?" 7987 7988 He continues: 7989 7990 You don't want your first grade teacher to be fornicating on the floor or drinking booze in the classroom. Similarly, I don't think you want your stock exchange to be all over the headlines because of its 7991 wretched excess. And I certainly don't think that you want to turn the country's major stock exchange into even more of a casino than it is already. 7992 7993 The military has the right model. Munger continues: 7994 7995 One of the things that's been horribly underdone is the concept where the military equivalent is conduct unbecoming an officer. When you rise to a certain point in a civilization, you ought to have a duty to 7996 behave as an exemplar. When is the last time you heard in a boardroom, 'Is this consistent with our duties as exemplars?' I mean the very word has an antique ring to it 'exemplar'. But that's exactly what is 7997 horribly lacking. 7998 7999 And everybody can see that that's what's required. The military concept of conduct unbecoming an officer is an important one. Your duty is to not cause resentment and envy and a lot of other things. You have 8000 a big duty as an exemplar." 8001 8002 How can we teach ethics? Charles Munger says: 8003 8004 I think the best single way to teach ethics is by example. And that means if you take in people who demonstrate in all their daily conduct an appropriate ethical framework, I think that has 8005 8006 255 8007 8008 enormous influence on the people who watch it. Conversely, if your ethics slip, and if people are being rewarded for ethical slips, then I think your ethics cascade downward at a very, very rapid rate. 8009 8010 I think ethics are terribly important, but I think they're best taught indirectly by example. If 8011 8012 you just sort oflearn a few rules and remember 'em well enough to pass a test, my guess is it doesn't do all that much for people's ethics. But if you see people you admire behaving a certain way- 8013 particularly under stress - I think you're likely to remember and be affected by that for a long, long time. 8014 8015 Treat people fairly 8016 8017 Warren Buffett says that: "The only way to be loved is to be lovable. You always get back more than you give away. If you don't give any you won't get any." Lao Tsu said: "Respond intelligently even to 8018 unintelligent treatment." Be nice to people and if they are not nice to you - don't be nasty - just avoid them in the future. Follow the advice of Charles Darwin - avoid controversies: 8019 8020 I rejoice that I have avoided controversies, and this I owe to Lyell, who many years ago, in reference to my geological works, strongly advised me never to get entangled in a controversy, as it rarely did any 8021 good and caused a miserable loss of time and temper. .. 8022 8023 All that I think is that you [letter to E. Haeckel) will excite anger, and that anger so completely blinds every one that your arguments would have no chance of influencing those who are already opposed to 8024 our views. 8025 8026 Don't take life too seriously 8027 8028 Life is too important to be taken seriously. 8029 8030 - Oscar Wilde 8031 8032 Have perspective. Remember Samuel Johnson's words: "Distance has the same effect on the mind as on the eye." When we fail we should view it as a learning expenence. 8033 8034 Have a positive attitude. Mayo Clinic researchers report that optimists report a higher level of physical and mental functioning than pessimists. Studies at the Mayo Clinic also show that optimists live 8035 longer than pessimists. Having a positive attitude also causes the body to produce pain-suppressing hormones, called endorphins, which work like morphine. 8036 8037 Warren Buffett says on the value of enthusiasm: 8038 8039 256 8040 8041 I do think enthusiasm is a good quality to have generally. It has helped me... I like managers in our businesses that are enthusiastic. These people are enthusiastic about their work in the same way people 8042 can get enthusiastic about golf, and that translates into results. If you are in a job that you are not enthusiastic about, find something else. You're not doing yourself any favor, and you're not doing your 8043 employer any favor and you're going to make a change anyway at some point. We're here on earth only one time, unless Shirley MacLaine is right, so you ought to be doing something that you enjoy as you go 8044 along, and can be enthusiastic about. 8045 8046 He also says that we should do what we enjoy: "Do what turns you on. Do something that if you had all the money in the world, you'd still be doing it. You've got to have a reason to jump out of bed in the 8047 morning... Don't look for the money. Look for something you love, and if you're good, the money will come." 8048 8049 Have reasonable expectations 8050 8051 Blessed is he that expects nothing, for he shall never be disappointed. 8052 8053 - Benjamin Franklin 8054 8055 If we don't hope for much, reality often beats our expectations. If we always expect the best or have unreal expectations, we are often disappointed. We feel worse and make bad judgments. 8056 8057 Expect adversity. We encounter adversity in whatever we choose to do in life. Charles Munger gives his iron prescription for life: 8058 8059 Whenever you think that some situation or some person is ruining your life, it is actually you who are ruining your life... Feeling like a victim is a perfectly disastrous way to go through life. If you just 8060 take the attitude that however bad it is in any way, it's always your fault and you just fix it as best you can - the so-called "iron prescription" - I think that really works. 8061 8062 When bad things happen, ask: What else does this mean? See life's obstacles as temporary setbacks, not disasters. Mark Twain says: "[Our] race, in its poverty, has unquestionably one really effective weapon - 8063 laughter... Against the assault oflaughter nothing can stand." 8064 8065 257 8066 8067 Live in the present 8068 8069 The superior man does not waste himself on what is distant, on what is absent. He stands in the here and now, in the real situation. 8070 8071 - Confucius 8072 8073 Often we tend to emphasize the destination so much that we miss the journey. Stay in the present and enjoy life today. Blaise Pascal wrote: 8074 8075 Let each of us examine his thoughts; he will find them wholly concerned with the past or the future. We almost never think of the present, and if we do think of it, it is only to see what light it throws on 8076 our plans for the future. The present is never our end. The past and the present are our means, the future alone our end. Thus we never actually live, but hope to live, and since we are always planning how to 8077 be happy, it is inevitable that we should never be so. 8078 8079 Be curious and open-minded. Always ask "why'' 8080 8081 Curiosity is one of the permanent and certain characteristics of a vigorous mind. 8082 8083 Samuel Johnson 8084 8085 Thomas Henry Huxley said: "Sit down before facts like a child, and be prepared to give up every preconceived Notion, follow humbly wherever and to whatever abysses Nature leads, or you shall learn nothing." A 8086 child is curious and asks "why?" As grown-ups we seem to forget the "whys" and accept what others say. We should all be children again and see the world as if through the eyes of a curious child without 8087 preconceptions. 8088 8089 The End 8090 8091 I confess that I have been as blind as a mole, but it is better to learn wisdom late than never to learn it at all. 8092 8093 Sherlock Holmes (Arthur Conan Doyle, The Man with the Twisted Lip) 8094 8095 I hope this book is helpful in both understanding and improving your thinking. I also hope that you will continue in your search for wisdom. We are still going to make misjudgments (at least I still do them), 8096 but we can improve. 8097 8098 258 8099 8100 - APPENDIX ONE - 8101 8102 CHARLES T. MUNGER HARVARD SCHOOL COMMENCEMENT SPEECH 8103 8104 [1mjUNE 13, 1986 [0m 8105 8106 Prescriptions for Guaranteed Misery in Life 8107 8108 Now that Headmaster Berrisford has selected one of the oldest and longest-serving trustees to make a commencement speech, it behooves the speaker to address two questions in every mind: 8109 8110 Why was such a selection made? and, 8111 8112 How long is the speech going to last? 8113 8114 I will answer the first question from long experience alongside Berrisford. He is seeking enhanced reputation for our school in the manner of the man who proudly displays his horse which can count to seven. 8115 The man knows that counting to seven is not much of a mathematical feat but he expects approval because doing so is creditable, considering that the performer is a horse. 8116 8117 The second question, regarding length of speech, I am not going to answer in advance. It 8118 8119 would deprive your upturned faces oflively curiosity and obvious keen anticipation, which I prefer to retain, regardless of source. 8120 8121 But I will tell you how my consideration of speech length created the subject matter of the speech itself. I was puffed up when invited to speak. While not having significant public speaking experience, I do 8122 hold a black belt in chutzpah, and, I immediately considered Demosthenes and Cicero as role models and anticipated trying to earn a compliment like Cicero gave when asked which was his favorite among the 8123 orations of Demosthenes. Cicero replied: "The longest one." 8124 8125 However, fortunately for this audience, I also thought of Samuel Johnson's famous comment when he addressed Milton's poem, Paradise Lost, and correctly said: "No one ever wished it longer." And that made me 8126 consider which of all the twenty Harvard School graduation speeches I had heard that I wished longer. There was only one such speech, that given byJohnny Carson, specifying Carson's prescriptions for 8127 guaranteed misery in life. I therefore decided to repeat Carson's speech but in expanded form with some added prescriptions of my own. 8128 8129 After all, I am much older than Carson was when he spoke and have failed and been miserable more often and in more ways than was possible for a charming humorist speaking at younger age. I am plainly 8130 well-qualified to expand on Carson's theme. 8131 8132 What Carson said was that he couldn't tell the graduating class how to be happy, but he could tell them from personal experience how to guarantee misery. Carson's prescriptions for sure misery included: 8133 8134 260 8135 8136 Ingesting chemicals in an effort to alter mood or perception; 8137 8138 Envy; and 8139 8140 Resentment. 8141 8142 I can still recall Carson's absolute conviction as he told how he had tried these things on occasion after occasion and had become miserable every time. 8143 8144 It is easy to understand Carson's first prescription for misery - ingesting chemicals. I add 8145 8146 my voice. The four closest friends of my youth were highly intelligent, ethical, humorous types, favored in person and background. Two are long dead, with alcohol a contributing factor, and a third is a 8147 living alcoholic - if you call that living. While susceptibility varies, addiction can happen to any of us, through a subtle process where the bonds of degradation are too light to be felt until they are too 8148 strong to be broken. And I have yet to meet anyone, in over six decades of life, whose life was worsened by overfear and overavoidance of such a deceptive pathway to destruction. 8149 8150 Envy, of course, joins chemicals in winning some sort of quantity price for causing misery. It was wreaking havoc long before it got a bad press in the laws of Moses. If you wish to retain the contribution of 8151 envy to misery, I recommend that you never read any of the biographies of that good Christian, Samuel Johnson, because his life demonstrates in an enticing way the possibility and advantage of transcending 8152 envy. 8153 8154 Resentment has always worked for me exactly as it worked for Carson. I cannot recommend it highly enough to you if you desire misery. Johnson spoke well when he said that life is hard enough to swallow 8155 without squeezing in the bitter rind of resentment. 8156 8157 For those of you who want misery, I also recommend refraining from practice of the Disraeli compromise, designed for people who find it impossible to quit resentment cold turkey. Disraeli, as he rose to 8158 become one of the greatest Prime Ministers, learned to give up vengeance as a motivation for action, but he did retain some outlet for resentment by putting the names of people who wronged him on pieces of 8159 paper in a drawer. Then, from time to time, he reviewed these names and took pleasure in noting the way the world had taken his enemies down without his assistance. 8160 8161 Well, so much for Carson's three prescriptions. Here are four more prescriptions from Munger: 8162 8163 First, be unreliable. Do not faithfully do what you have engaged to do. If you will only master this one habit you will more than counterbalance the combined effect of all your virtues, howsoever great. If 8164 you like being distrusted and excluded from the best human contribution and company, this prescription is for you. Master this one habit and you can always play the role of the hare in the fable, except that 8165 instead of being outrun by one fine turtle you will be outrun by hordes and hordes of mediocre turtles and even by some mediocre turtles on crutches. 8166 8167 I must warn you that if you don't follow my first prescription it may be hard to end up miserable, even if you start disadvantaged. I had a roommate in college who was and is severely dyslexic. But he is 8168 perhaps the most reliable man I have ever known. He has had a wonderful life so far, outstanding wife and children, chief executive of a multibillion dollar corporation. 8169 8170 261 8171 8172 If you want to avoid a conventional, main-culture, establishment result of this kind, you simply can't count on your other handicaps to hold you back if you persist in being reliable. 8173 8174 I cannot here pass by a reference to a life described as "wonderful so far," without reinforcing the "so far" aspects of the human condition by repeating the remark of Croesus, once the richest king in the 8175 world. Later, in ignominious captivity, as he prepared to be burned alive, he said: "Well now do I remember the words of the historian Solon: "No man's life should be accounted a happy one until it is over." 8176 8177 My second prescription for misery is ro learn everything you possibly can from your own personal experience, minimizing what you learn vicariously from the good and bad experience of others, living and dead. 8178 This prescription is a sure-shot producer of misery and second-rate achievement. 8179 8180 You can see the results of not learning from others' mistakes by simply looking about you. How little originality there is in the common disasters of mankind - drunk driving deaths, reckless driving maimings, 8181 incurable venereal diseases, conversion of bright college students into brainwashed zombies as members of destructive cults, business failures through repetition of obvious mistakes made by predecessors, 8182 various forms of crowd folly, and so on. I recommend as a memory clue to finding the way to real trouble from heedless, unoriginal error the modern saying: "If at first you don't succeed, well, so much for 8183 hang gliding." 8184 8185 The other aspect of avoiding vicarious wisdom is the rule for not learning from the best work done before yours. The prescription is to become as non-educated as you reasonable can. 8186 8187 Perhaps you will better see the type of non-miserable result you can thus avoid if I render a short historical account. There once was a man who assiduously mastered the work of his best predecessors, despite 8188 a poor start and very tough time in analytic geometry. Eventually his own original work attracted wide attention and he said of that work: 8189 8190 "lfl have seen a little farther than other men it is because I stood on the shoulders of giants." 8191 8192 The bones of that man lie buried now, in Westminster Abbey, under an unusual inscription: 8193 8194 "Here lie the remains of all that was mortal in Sir Isaac Newton." 8195 8196 My third prescription for misery is to go down and stay down when you get your first, second, or third severe reverse in the battle oflife. Because there is so much adversity out there, even for the lucky and 8197 wise, this will guarantee that, in due course, you will be permanently mired in misery. Ignore at all cost the lesson contained in the accurate epitaph written for himself by Epicetus: "Here lies Epicetus, a 8198 slave, maimed in body, the ultimate in poverty, and favored by the Gods." 8199 8200 My final prescription to you for a life of fuzzy thinking and infelicity is to ignore a story they told me when I was very young about a rustic who said: "I wish I knew where I was going to die, and then I'd 8201 never go there." Most people smile (as you did) at the rustic's ignorance and ignore his basic wisdom. If my experience is any guide, the rustic's approach is to be avoided at all cost by someone bent on 8202 misery. To help fail you should discount as mere quirk, with 8203 8204 262 8205 8206 no useful message, the method of the rustic, which is the same one used in Carson's speech. What Carson did was to approach the study of how to create X by turning the question backward, that is, by studying 8207 how to create non-X. The great algebraist, Jacobi, had exactly the same approach as Carson and was known for his constant repetition of one phrase: "Invert, always invert." It is in the nature of things, as 8208 Jacobi knew, that many hard problems are best solved only when they are addressed backward. For instance, when almost everyone else was trying to revise the electromagnetic laws of Maxwell to be consistent 8209 with the motion laws of Newton, Einstein discovered special relativity as he made a 180 degree turn and 8210 8211 revised Newton's laws to fit Maxwell's. 8212 8213 It is my opinion, as a certified biography nut, that Charles Robert Darwin would have ranked near the middle of the Harvard School graduating class of 1986. Yet he is now famous in the history of science. 8214 This is precisely the type of example you should learn nothing from if bent on minimizing your results from your own endowment. 8215 8216 Darwin's result was due in large measure to his working method, which violated all my rules for misery and particularly emphasized a backward twist in that he always gave priority attention to evidence 8217 tending to disconfirm whatever cherished and hard-won theory he already had. In contrast, most people early achieve and later intensify a tendency to process new and disconfirming information so that any 8218 original conclusion remains intact. They become people of whom Philip Wylie observed: "You couldn't squeeze a dime between what they already know and what they will never learn." 8219 8220 The life of Darwin demonstrates how a turtle may outrun the hares, aided by extreme 8221 8222 objectivity, which helps the objective person end up like the only player without blindfold in a game of pin-the-donkey. 8223 8224 If you minimize objectivity, you ignore not only a lesson from Darwin but also one from 8225 8226 Einstein. Einstein said that his successful theories came from: "Curiosity, concentration, perseverance and self-criticism. And by self-criticism he meant the testing and destruction of his own well-loved 8227 ideas. 8228 8229 Finally, minimizing objectivity will help you lessen the compromises and burdens of owning worldly goods, because objectivity does not work only for great physicists and biologists. It also adds power to the 8230 work of a plumbing contractor in Bemidji. Therefore, if you interpret being true to yourself as requiring that you retain every notion of your youth you will be safely underway, not only toward maximizing 8231 ignorance, but also toward whatever misery can be obtained through unpleasant experiences in business. 8232 8233 It is fitting now that a backward sort of speech end with a backward sort of toast, inspired by Elihu Root's repeated accounts of how the dog went to Dover, "leg over leg." To the class of 1986: 8234 8235 Gentlemen, may each of you rise high by spending each day of a long life aiming low. 8236 8237 263 8238 8239 - APPENDIX Two - 8240 8241 WISDOM FROM CHARLES T. MUNGER AND WARREN E. BUFFETT 8242 8243 On how to change people 8244 8245 Suppose you've got a client who really wants to commit tax fraud. If he doesn't push the tax law away beyond the line, he can't stand it. He can't shave in the morning if he thinks there's been any cheating 8246 he could get by with that he hasn't done. And there are people like that. They just feel they aren't living aggressively enough. 8247 8248 You can approach that situation in either of two ways: (A) you can say, "I just won't work for him," and duck it. Or, (B) you can say, "Well, the circumstances of my life require that I work for him. And what 8249 Tm doing for him doesn't involve my cheating. Therefore, I'll do it." And if you see he wants to do something really stupid, it probably won't work to tell him, 8250 8251 "What you're doing is bad. I have better morals than you." 8252 8253 That offends him. You're young. He's old. Therefore, instead of being persuaded, he's more likely to react with, "Who in the hell are you to establish the moral code of the whole world?" But instead, you can 8254 say to him, "You can't do that without three other people beneath you knowing about it. Therefore, you're making yourself subject to blackmail. You're risking your 8255 8256 reputation. You're risking your family, your money, etc." 8257 8258 That is likely to work. And you're telling him something that's true. Do you want to spend a lot of time working for people where you have to use methods like that to get them to behave well? I think the 8259 answer is no. But if you're hooked with it, appealing to interest is likely to work better as a matter of human persuasion than appeal to anything else. That, again, is a powerful psychological principle with 8260 deep biological roots. 8261 8262 I saw that psychological principle totally blown at Salomon. Salomon's general council knew that the CEO, Gutfreund, should have promptly told the Federal authorities all about Salomon's trading improprieties 8263 in which Gutfreund didn't participate and which he hadn't caused. And the general counsel urged Gutfreund to do it. He told Gutfreund, in effect, "You're probably not legally required to do that, but it's the 8264 right thing to do. You really should." 8265 8266 But it didn't work. The task was easy to put off - because it was unpleasant. So that's what Gutfreund did - he put it off. 8267 8268 And the general counsel had very little constituency within Salomon except for the CEO. If the CEO went down, the general counsel was going down with him. Therefore, his whole career was on the line. So to 8269 save his career, he needed to talk the dilatory CEO into doing the right thing. 8270 8271 It would've been child's play to get that job done right. All the general counsel had to do was to tell his boss, "John, this situation could ruin your life. You could lose your wealth. You could lose your 8272 reputation... "And it would have worked. CEOs don't like the idea of being 8273 8274 264 8275 8276 ruined, disgraced and fired. (Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, p.59.) 8277 8278 On some reasons to why managers don't make rational decisions 8279 8280 My most surprising discovery: the overwhelming importance in business of an unseen force that we might call "the institutional imperative." In business school, I was given no hint of the imperative's 8281 existence and I did not intuitively understand it when I entered the business world. I thought then that decent, intelligent, and experienced managers would automatically make rational business decisions. But 8282 I learned over time that isn't so. Instead, rationality frequently wilts when the institutional imperative comes into play. 8283 8284 For example: (1) As if governed by Newton's First Law of Motion, an institution will resist any change in its current direction; (2) Just as work expands to fill available time, corporate projects or 8285 acquisitions will materialize to soak up available funds; (3) Any business craving of the leader, however foolish, will be quickly supported by detailed rate-of-return and strategic studies prepared by his 8286 troops; and (4) The behavior of peer companies, whether they are expanding, acquiring, setting executive compensation or whatever, will be mindlessly imitated. 8287 8288 Institutional dynamics, not venality or stupidity, set businesses on these courses, which are too often misguided. After making some expensive mistakes because I ignored the power of the imperative, I have 8289 tried to organize and manage Berkshire in ways that minimize its influence. Furthermore, Charlie and I have attempted to concentrate our investments in companies that appear alert to the problem. (Warren 8290 Buffett, Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1989, p.62.) 8291 8292 On the difficulty of replacing a CEO 8293 8294 Most organizations depend on the self-interest of the superior to weed out the second-rate inferior. If I'm a sales manager and I've got lots of lousy salesmen, it hurts my performance and it probably hurts 8295 my income to keep on the sub-par performers. It certainly hurts a football coach to keep a sub-par quarterback or any other player in there ifhe can get a better one. In almost all jobs, there is a reward or 8296 penalty system that causes the superior to think actively about whether the people beneath him are doing a first-class job and to do something about it if they aren't. 8297 8298 That works all the way up to the CEO. But the CEO's superiors are the directors of the publicly held company. And are the directors of the company going to suffer if the CEO is sub-par? Probably only if 8299 they're embarrassed. That's the way you hurt the superior in that case. You don't take away his directors' fee. And as a practical matter, you don't displace directors very often. So the only system that's 8300 comparable to the problem of the football coach or the sales manager is probably to hurt psychically the position of the inferior director 8301 8302 - and that will work. Otherwise, the motivation to correct the CEO problem is not strong unless there's a big ownership among directors - and even that doesn't always work perfectly. To change directors 8303 usually takes the action of big shareholders. It doesn't happen any other way. It's a very awkward situation for a management or a group of directors, who have somehow selected other weak directors, to make 8304 changes. It goes against all the natural 8305 8306 265 8307 8308 societal norms to walk up to some guy at a meeting- who isn't causing any harm and is sitting there like a potted palm - and turn to him and say, "We've all thought it over. And you're really not any good." 8309 It just doesn't happen. (Warren Buffett, Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1993, Outstanding Investor Digest, June 30, 1993, p.32.) 8310 8311 On the kind of people we should do business with 8312 8313 I have been asked by a number of people just what secrets the Blumkins [Nebraska Furniture Mart] bring to their business. These are not very esoteric. All members of the family: (1) apply themselves with an 8314 enthusiasm and energy that would make Ben Franklin and Horatio Alger look like dropouts; (2) define with extraordinary realism their area of special competence and act decisively on all matters within it; (3) 8315 ignore even the most enticing propositions falling outside of that area of special competence; and (4) unfailingly behave in a high-grade manner with everyone they deal with. (Mrs. B boils it down to "sell 8316 cheap and tell the truth".) (Warren Buffett, Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1984, p.87.) 8317 8318 We really don't want to buy into any organization that we felt would be lacking that quality [intellectual honesty] in the first place - because we really don't believe in buying into organizations to change 8319 them. We may change the comp system a little or something of the sort... 8320 8321 We want people joining us who already are the type that face reality and that basically [not only] tell us the truth, but tell themselves the truth - which is even more important. Once you get an organization 8322 that lies to itself- and there are plenty that do - I just think you get into all kinds of problems. And people know it throughout the organization and they adopt the norms of what they think is happening up 8323 above them. Particularly in a financial organization - really in any organization, but particularly in a financial organization - that is death over time. We wouldn't buy into something that we felt had that 8324 problem with the idea that we would correct it - because we wouldn't. We've had a little experience with some organizations that have had that sort of problem. And it's not correctable - at least based on the 8325 life span of humans. It's too much to commit to. (Warren Buffett, Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2000, Outstanding Investor Digest, OID.Com, continued from December 18, 2000 &Year End 2000 Editions.) 8326 8327 We find it meaningful when an owner cares about whom he sells to. We like to do business with someone who loves his company, not just the money that a sale will bring him (though we certainly understand why 8328 he likes that as well). When chis emotional attachment exists, it signals that important qualities will likely be found within the business: honest accounting, pride of product, respect for customers, and a 8329 loyal group of associates having a strong sense of direction. The reverse is apt to be true, also. When an owner auctions off his business, exhibiting a total lack of interest in what follows, you will 8330 frequently find that it has been dressed up for sale, particularly when the seller is a "financial owner." And if owners behave with little regard for their business and its people, their conduct will often 8331 contaminate attitudes and practices throughout the company. (Warren Buffett, Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2000 Annual Report, p.7.) 8332 8333 266 8334 8335 On picking up the right character traits 8336 8337 Buffett: It does pay to have the right models.. .I think that it just stands to reason that if you copy the people that you look up to - particularly if you do it at an early enough age... If you influence 8338 the role models of a five-year old or an eight-year old or a ten-year old, then it's going to have a huge impact. 8339 8340 And of course, virtually everybody starts out with their initial models being their parents. So they are the ones that are going to have a huge effect on 'em. And if that parent turns out to be a great model, 8341 I think it's going to be a huge plus for the child. I think it beats a whole lot of other things in life to have the right models around... 8342 8343 But you've got to start early. It's very tough to change behavior later on. I tell the students 8344 8345 in classes, "Just pick out the person you admire the most in the class, and sit down and write the reasons why you admire him and then try and figure out why you can't have the same qualities." After all, 8346 they're not like the ability to throw a football 60 yards or run the 100 in ten seconds flat or something like that. They're qualities of personality, character and temperament that can be emulated. 8347 8348 And you can apply the reverse ofit following Charlie's theory: You can find the people you don't like and say, "What don't I like about these people?" It takes a little strength of character, but you can look 8349 inwards and say, "Have I got some of that in me?" 8350 8351 It's not complicated. Ben Graham did it, Ben Franklin did it. And nothing could be more simple than to try and figure out what you find admirable and then decide that the person you really would like to 8352 admire is yourself And the only way you're going to do it is to take on the qualities of other people you admire. 8353 8354 Munger: Also, there is no reason to look only for living models. The eminent dead are in the nature of things some of the best models around. And if a model is all you want, you're really better off not 8355 limiting yourself to the living. Some of the very best models have been dead for a long time. (Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2000, Outstanding Investor Digest, Year End 2000 Edition, pp.62-63.) 8356 8357 On overconfidence 8358 8359 About 99% of American management thinks that if they're wonderful at doing one thing that they'll be wonderful at doing something else. They're like a duck on a pond when it's raining 8360 8361 - they're going up in the world. They start thinking that they're the ones that are causing themselves to rise. So they go over to some place where it isn't raining and they just sit there on the ground. But 8362 nothing happens. Then they usually fire their number rwo in command or hire a consultant. They very seldom see what really happens is that they have left their circle of competence ... 8363 8364 If you take the CEOs of America's largest corporations, they do not know what their circle of competence is. That's one of the reasons they make so many dumb acquisitions. They rise to the top of the business 8365 because they're great salesmen, great production people or whatever. All of a sudden, they're running a multi-billion dollar business and their job is to allocate capital and to buy businesses. They've never 8366 bought a business in their life. They don't know what it's all about. 8367 8368 So they usually do one or rwo things. Either they set up an internal department, hire a 8369 8370 267 8371 8372 bunch of guys and have them tell him something to do. Of course, the guys know if they don't tell him something to do, then there will be no jobs. So you can imagine what activity takes place then. Or they go 8373 out and hire investment bankers who get paid by the transaction. (Warren Buffett, lecture at Stanford Law School, March 23, 1990, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mApril 18, 1990, pp.13-14.) 8374 8375 On some reasons to why bad lending happen so often 8376 8377 Granting the presence of perverse incentives, what are the operating mechanics that cause widespread bad loans (where the higher interest rates do not adequately cover increased risk ofloss) under our present 8378 system? After all, the bad lending, while it has a surface plausibility to bankers under cost pressure, is, by definition, not rational, at least for the lending banks and the wider civilization. How then 8379 does bad lending occur so often? 8380 8381 It occurs (partly) because there are predictable irrationalities among people as social animals. It is now pretty clear (in experimental social psychology) that people on the horns of a dilemma, which is 8382 where our system has placed our bankers, are extra likely to react unwisely to the example of other people's conduct, now widely called "social proo£" So, once some banker has apparently (but not really) 8383 solved his cost-pressure problem by unwise lending, a considerable amount of imitative "crowd folly," relying on the "social proof," is the natural consequence. Additional massive irrational lending is caused 8384 by "reinforcement" of foolish behavior, caused by unwise accounting convention in a manner discussed later in this letter. It is hard to be wise when the messages which drive you are wrong messages provided 8385 by a mal-designed system ... 8386 8387 Many eminent "experts" would not agree with our notions about systemic irresponsibility from combining (1) "free-market" pricing of interest rates with (2) government guarantees of payment. If many eminent 8388 "experts" are wrong, how could this happen? Our explanation is that the "experts" are over-charmed with an admirable, powerful, predictive model, coming down from Adam Smith. Those discretionary interest 8389 rates on deposits have a "free-market" 8390 8391 image, making it easy to conclude, automatically, that the discretionary rates, like other free market processes, must be good. Indeed, they are appraised as remaining good even when combined with 8392 governmental deposit insurance, a radical non-free-market element. 8393 8394 Such illogical thinking displays the standard folly bedeviling the "expert" role in any soft science: one tends to use only models from one's own segment of a discipline, ignoring or underweighing others. 8395 Furthermore, the more powerful and useful is any model, the more error it tends to produce through overconfident misuse. 8396 8397 This brings to mind Ben Graham's paradoxical observation that good ideas cause more investment mischief than bad ideas. He had it right. It is so easy for us all to push a really good idea to wretched excess, 8398 as in the case of the Florida land bubble or the "nifty fifty" corporate stocks. Then mix in a little "social proof" (from other experts), and brains (including ours) often turn to mush. It would be nice if 8399 great old models never tricked us, but, alas, "some dreams are not to be." Even Einstein got tricked in his later years... 8400 8401 We think current accounting for many high-interest-rate loans has terrible consequences in the banking system. In essence, it "front ends" into reported income revenues that would have been deferred until 8402 much later, after risky bets were more clearly won, if more 8403 8404 268 8405 8406 conservative accounting had been employed. This practice turns many a banker into a human version of one of B.F. Skinner's pigeons, since he is "reinforced" into continuing and expanding bad lending through 8407 the pleasure of seeing good figures in the short term. The good figures substitute nicely in the mind for nonexistent underlying institutional good, partly through the process, originally demonstrated by 8408 Pavlov, wherein we respond to a mere association because it has usually portended a reality that would make the response correct. (Charles Munger, Wesco Financial Inc., 1990 Annual Report. Berkshire Hathaway 8409 Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1987-1995, pp.205-208.) 8410 8411 On the value of math 8412 8413 53% of the world's stock market value is in the U.S. Well, if U.S. GDP [gross domestic product] grows at 4-5% a year with 1-2% inflation - which would be a pretty good, in fact it would be a very good result 8414 - then I think it's very unlikely that corporate profits are going to grow at a greater rate than that. Corporate profits as a percent of GDP are on the high side already- and corporate profits can't 8415 constantly grow at a faster rate than GDP. Obviously, in the end, they'd be greater than GDP. 8416 8417 It's like somebody said about New York - that it has more lawyers than people. You run into certain conflicts as you go along if you say profits can get bigger than GDP. So if you have a situation where the 8418 best you can hope for in corporate profit growth over the years is 4-5%, how can it be reasonable to think that equities - which, after all, are a capitalization of those corporate profits - can grow at 15% a 8419 year? It's nonsense, frankly... 8420 8421 The other day, I looked at the Fortune 500. And the companies on that list earned $334 billion and had a market capitalization of $9.9 trillion at year end - which would probably be up to at least $10.5 8422 trillion now. Well, the only money investors are going to make in the long run is what the businesses make. There's nothing added. The government doesn't throw in anything. Nobody's adding to the pot. People 8423 take out from the pot in terms of frictional costs - investment management fees, brokerage commissions and all of that. But $334 billion is all that the investment earns. 8424 8425 If you own a farm, what the farm produces is all you're going to get from the farm. If it produces $50 an acre of net profit, you'll get $50 an acre of net profit. And there's nothing about it that transforms 8426 that in some miraculous form. If you owned all of the Fortune 500 8427 8428 - if you owned 100% ofit -you'd be making $334 billion. And if you paid $10.5 trillion for that, well, that's not a great return on investment. 8429 8430 Then you might say, "Can that $334 billion double in five years?" Well, it can't double in five years with GDP growing at 4% a year or some number like that. It would just produce things so out of whack in 8431 terms of experience in the American economy that it won't happen. Any time you get involved in these things where if you trace out the mathematics of it, you bump into absurdities, then you better change your 8432 expectations somewhat. (Warren Buffett, Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1999, Outstanding Investor Digest, December 10, 1999, p.52.) 8433 8434 On advantages of scale 8435 8436 In terms of which businesses succeed and which businesses fail, advantages of scale are 8437 8438 269 8439 8440 ungodly important. For example, one great advantage of scale taught in all of the business schools of the world is cost reductions along the so-called experience curve. Just doing something complicated in 8441 more and more volume enables human beings, who are trying to improve and are motivated by the incentives of capitalism, to do it more and more efficiently. The very nature of things is that if you get a whole 8442 lot of volume through your joint, you get better at processing that volume. That's an enormous advantage. And it has a lot to do 8443 8444 with which businesses succeed and fail.... 8445 8446 Let's go through a list - albeit an incomplete one of possible advantages of scale. Some come from simple geometry. If you're building a great spherical tank, obviously as you build it bigger, the amount of 8447 steel you use in the surface goes up with the square and the cubic volume goes up with the cube. So as you increase the dimensions, you can hold a lot more volume per unit area of steel. And there are all 8448 kinds of things like that where the simple geometry - the simple reality- gives you an advantage of scale. 8449 8450 For example, you can get advantages of scale from TV advertising. When TV advertising first arrived - when talking color pictures first came into our living rooms - it was an unbelievably powerful thing. And 8451 in the early days, we had three networks that had whatever it was - say 90% of the audience. 8452 8453 Well, if you were Proctor & Gamble, you could afford to use this new method of 8454 8455 advertising. You could afford the very expensive cost of network television because you were selling so damn many cans and bottles. Some little guy couldn't. And there was no way of buying it in part. 8456 Therefore, he couldn't use it. In effect, if you didn't have a big volume, you couldn't use network TV advertising - which was the most effective technique. 8457 8458 So when TV came in, the branded companies that were already big got a huge tail wind. 8459 8460 Indeed, they prospered and prospered and prospered until some of them got fat and foolish, which happens with prosperity- at least to some people.... 8461 8462 And your advantage of scale can be an informational advantage. If I go to some remote 8463 8464 place, I may see Wrigley chewing gum alongside Glotz's chewing gum. Well, I know that Wrigley is a satisfactory product, whereas I don't know anything about Glotz's. So if one is 8465 8466 $.40 and the other is $.30, am I going to take something I don't know and put it in my mouth 8467 8468 which is a pretty personal place, after all - for a lousy dime? 8469 8470 Another advantage of scale comes from psychology We are all influenced - subconsciously 8471 8472 and to some extent consciously- by what we see others do and approve. Therefore, if everybody's buying something, we think it's better. We don't like to be the one guy who's out of step. 8473 8474 Again, some of this is at a subconscious level and some of it isn't. Sometimes, we consciously and rationally think, "Gee, I don't know much about this. They know more than I do. Therefore, why shouldn't I 8475 follow them?" 8476 8477 The social proof phenomenon which comes right out of psychology gives huge advantages to scale - for example, with very wide distribution, which of course is hard to get. One advantage of Coca-Cola is that 8478 it's available almost everywhere in the world. 8479 8480 Well, suppose you have a little soft drink. Exactly how do you make it available all over the Earth? The worldwide distribution setup - which is slowly won by a big enterprise - gets to be a huge advantage 8481 And if you think about it, once you get enough advantages of that 8482 8483 type, it can become very hard for anybody to dislodge you. 270 8484 8485 There's another kind of advantage to scale. In some businesses, the very nature of things is to sort of cascade toward the overwhelming dominance of one firm. 8486 8487 The most obvious one is daily newspapers. There's practically no city left in the U.S., aside from a few very big ones, where there's more than one daily newspaper. 8488 8489 And again, that's a scale thing. Once I get most of the circulation, I get most of the advertising. And once I get most of the advertising and circulation, why would anyone want the thinner paper with less 8490 information in it? So it tends to cascade to a winner-take-all situation. And chat's a separate form of the advantages of scale phenomenon. 8491 8492 Similarly, all these huge advantages of scale allow greater specialization within the firm. Therefore, each person can be better at what he does... 8493 8494 On the subject of advantages of economies of scale, I find chain stores quite interesting. Just think about it. The concept of a chain store was a fascinating invention. You get this huge purchasing power - 8495 which means chat you have lower merchandise costs. You get a whole bunch oflittle laboratories out there in which you can conduct experiments. And you get specialization. If one little guy is trying to buy 8496 across 27 different merchandise categories influenced by traveling salesmen, he's going to make a lot of dumb decisions. But if your buying is done in headquarters for a huge bunch of stores, you can get very 8497 bright people chat know a lot about 8498 8499 refrigerators and so forth to do the buying. 8500 8501 The reverse is demonstrated by the little store where one guy is doing all the buying. It's like the old story about the little store with salt all over its walls. And a stranger comes in and says to the 8502 store owner, "You must sell a lot of salt." And he replies, "No, I don't. But you should see the guy who sells me salt." (Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor Guilford Babcock at the 8503 University of Southern California School of Business on April 14, 1994, Outstanding Investor Digest, May 5, 1995, pp.52-54.) 8504 8505 On disadvantages of scale 8506 8507 For example, we - by which I mean Berkshire Hathaway - are the largest shareholder in Capital Cities/ABC. And we had trade publications there that got murdered - where our competitors beat us. And the way 8508 they beat us was by going to a narrower specialization. 8509 8510 We'd have a travel magazine for business travel. So somebody would create one which was addressed solely at corporate travel departments. Like an ecosystem, you're getting a narrower and narrower 8511 specialization. 8512 8513 Well, they got much more efficient. They could tell more to the guys who ran corporate travel departments. Plus, they didn't have to waste the ink and paper mailing out stuff that corporate travel departments 8514 weren't interested in reading. It was a more efficient system. And they beat our brains out as we relied on our broader magazine. 8515 8516 That's what happened to The Saturday Evening Post and all chose things. They're gone. What we have now is Motorcross- which is read by a bunch of nuts who like to participate in tournaments where they turn 8517 somersaults on their motorcycles. But they care about it. For them, it's the principal purpose of life. A magazine called Motorcross is a total necessity to those people. And its profit margins would make you 8518 salivate. Just think of how narrowcast chat kind of publishing is. So occasionally, scaling down and intensifying gives you the big advantage. Bigger is not always better. 8519 8520 271 8521 8522 The great defect of scale, of course, which makes the game interesting - so that the big people don't always win - is that as you get big, you get the bureaucracy. And with the bureaucracy comes the 8523 territoriality- which is again grounded in human nature. 8524 8525 And the incentives are perverse. For example, if you worked for AT&T in my day, it was a great bureaucracy. Who in the hell was really thinking about the shareholder or anything else? And in a bureaucracy, 8526 you think the work is done when it goes out of your in-basket into somebody's else's in-basket. But, of course, it isn't. It's not done until AT&T delivers what it's supposed to deliver. So you get big, fat, 8527 dumb, unmotivated bureaucracies. 8528 8529 They also tend to become somewhat corrupt. In other words, ifl've got a department and you've got a department and we kind of share power running this thing, there's sort of an unwritten rule: "If you won't 8530 bother me, I won't bother you and we're both happy." So you get layers of management and associated costs that nobody needs. Then, while people are justifying all these layers. It takes forever to get 8531 anything done. They're too slow to make decisions and nimbler people run circles around them. 8532 8533 The constant curse of scale is that it leads to big, dumb bureaucracy - which, of course, reaches its highest and worst form in government where the incentives are really awful. That doesn't mean we don't 8534 need governments - because we do. But it's a terrible problem to get big bureaucracies to behave. (Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor Guilford Babcock at the University of Southern 8535 California School of Business on April 14, 1994, Outstanding Investor Digest, May 5, 1995, p.53.) 8536 8537 On how to get worldly wisdom 8538 8539 I've long believed that a certain system - which almost any intelligent person can learn - works way better than the systems that most people use. As I said at the U.S.C. Business School, what you need is a 8540 latticework of mental models in your head. And you hang your actual experience and your vicarious experience (that you get from reading and so forth) on this latticework of powerful models. And, with that 8541 system, things gradually get to fit together in a way that enhances cognition. 8542 8543 And you need the models - not just from one or two disciplines, but from [3mall [0mthe important disciplines. You need the best 100 or so models from microeconomics, physiology, psychology particularly, elementary 8544 mathematics, hard science and engineering [and so on]. 8545 8546 You don't have to be a huge expert in any of those fields. All you've got to do is take the really big ideas and learn them early and well. 8547 8548 You can't learn those 100 big ideas you really need the way many students do - where you learn 'em well enough to bang 'em back to the professor and get your grade and then you empty them out as though you 8549 were emptying a bathtub so you can take in more water next time. If that's the way you learn the 100 big models you're going to need, [you'll be] an "also ran" in the game of life. You have to learn the 8550 models so that they become part of your ever used repertoire. (Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, December 29, 1997, 8551 p.24.) 8552 8553 On what something really mean 8554 8555 By its nature, the U.S. is running a substantial merchandise trade deficit. If you buy more 8556 8557 272 8558 8559 from the rest of the world than you're selling them - which is what happens by definition when you're running a trade deficit - you have to balance the books. They have to get something - some capital asset - 8560 in exchange: They may get a government bond. They may get a piece of a U.S. business. But they have to get something. 8561 8562 The key thing in economics, whenever someone makes an assertion to you, is to always 8563 8564 ask, "And then what?" Actually, it's not such a bad idea to ask it about everything. But you should always ask, "And then what?" 8565 8566 So when you read that the merchandise trade deficit is $9 billion, what else does that mean? It means that somehow we must also have traded $9 billion of capital assets - (future) claims on our production - 8567 and given them to somebody else in the world. So they have to invest. They don't have any choice. And when somebody says, "Won't it be terrible if the Japanese sell all of their government bonds?" Well, they 8568 can't without getting another American asset in exchange. There's simply no other way to do it. They could sell it to the French, but then the French have the same problem. 8569 8570 So trace through the transactions on the circle whenever you talk about any specific action in economics. (Warren Buffett, Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1997, Outstanding Investor Digest, August 8, 1997, 8571 p.23.) 8572 8573 On 3 timeless ideas for investing 8574 8575 His [Benjamin Graham] three basic ideas - and none of them are complicated or require any mathematical talent or anything of that sort - are: 8576 8577 that you should look at stocks as part ownership of a business, 8578 8579 that you should look at market fluctuations in terms of his "Mr. Market" example and make them your friend rather than your enemy by essentially profiting from folly rather participating in it, and finally, 8580 8581 the three most important words in investing are "margin of safety" - ... always building a 15,000 pound bridge if you're going to be driving 10,000 pound truck across it ... 8582 8583 So I think that it comes down to those ideas - although they sound so simple and commonplace that it kind of seems like a waste to go to school and get a Ph.D. in Economics and have it all come back to that. 8584 It's a little like spending eight years in divinity school and having somebody tell you that the ten commandments were all that counted. There is a certain natural tendency to overlook anything that simple 8585 and important. (Warren Buffett, speech at New York Society of Security Analysts, December 6, 1994, Outstanding Investor Digest, May 5, 1995, p.3.) 8586 8587 On how to evaluate businesses 8588 8589 Leaving aside tax factors, the formula we use for evaluating stocks and businesses is identical. Indeed, the formula for valuing [3mall [0massets that are purchased for financial gain has been unchanged since it 8590 was first laid out bya very smart man in about 600 B.C. (though he wasn't smart enough to know it was 600 B.C.). 8591 8592 The oracle was Aesop and his enduring, though somewhat incomplete, investment insight was "a bird in the hand is worth two in the bush." To flesh out this principle, you must answer 8593 8594 273 8595 8596 only three questions. How certain are you that there are indeed birds in the bush? When will they emerge and how many will there be? What is the risk-free interest rate (which we consider to be the yield on 8597 long-term U.S. bonds)? If you can answer these three questions, you will know the maximum value of the bush - and the maximum number of the birds you now possess that should be offered for it. And, of course, 8598 don't literally think birds. Think dollars. 8599 8600 Aesop's investment axiom, thus expanded and converted into dollars, is immutable. It 8601 8602 applies to outlays for farms, oil royalties, bonds, stocks, lottery tickets, and manufacturing plants. And neither the advent of the steam engine, the harnessing of electricity nor the creation of the 8603 automobile changed the formula one iota - nor will the Internet. Just insert the correct numbers, and you can rank the attractiveness of all possible uses of capital throughout the universe. (Warren Buffett, 8604 Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2000 Annual Report, p.13.) 8605 8606 On commodity businesses 8607 8608 Businesses in industries with both substantial over-capacity and a "commodity" product (undifferentiated in any customer-important way by factors such as performance, appearance, service support, etc.) are 8609 prime candidates for profit troubles. These may be escaped, true, if prices or costs are administered in some manner and thereby insulated at least partially from normal market forces. This administration can 8610 be carried out (a) legally through government intervention (until recently, this category included pricing for truckers and deposit costs for financial institutions), (b) illegally through collusion, or (c) 8611 "extra legally" through OPEC-style foreign cartelization (with tag-along benefits for domestic non cartel operators). 8612 8613 If, however, costs and prices are determined by full-bore competition, there is more than 8614 8615 ample capacity, and the buyer cares little about whose product or distribution services he uses, industry economics are almost certain to be unexciting. They may well be disastrous. 8616 8617 Hence the constant struggle of every vendor to establish and emphasize special qualities of product or service. This works with candy bars (customers buy by brand name, not by asking for a "two-ounce candy 8618 bar") but doesn't work with sugar (how often do you hear, "I'll have a cup of coffee with cream and C & H sugar, please"). 8619 8620 In many industries, differentiation simply can't be made meaningful. A few producers in such industries may consistently do well if they have a cost advantage that is both wide and sustainable. By definition 8621 such exceptions are few, and, in many industries, are non-existent. For the great majority of companies selling "commodity" products, a depressing equation of business economics prevails: persistent 8622 over-capacity without administered prices (or costs) equals poor profitability. 8623 8624 Of course, over-capacity may eventually self-correct, either as capacity shrinks or demand expands. Unfortunately for the participants, such corrections often are long delayed. When they finally occur, the 8625 rebound to prosperity frequently produces a pervasive enthusiasm for expansion that, within a few years, again creates over-capacity and a new profitless environment. In other words, nothing fails like 8626 success. 8627 8628 What finally determines levels of long-term profitability in such industries is the ratio of supply-tight to supply-ample years. Frequently that ratio is dismal. (It seems as if the most 8629 8630 274 8631 8632 recent supply-tight period in our textile business - it occurred some years back - lasted the better part of a morning.) 8633 8634 In some industries, however, capacity-tight conditions can last a long time. Sometimes actual growth in demand will outrun forecasted growth for an extended period. In other cases, adding capacity requires 8635 very long lead times because complicated manufacturing facilities must be planned and built. (Warren Buffett, Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1982, pp.56-57.) 8636 8637 On paying cash out or keeping it in the business 8638 8639 When we have capital around, we have three questions... First, "Does it make more sense to pay it out to the shareholders than to keep it within the company?" The sub-question on that is, "If we pay it out, 8640 is it better off to do it via repurchases or via dividend?" The test for whether we pay it out in dividends is, "Can we create more than a dollar of value within the company with that dollar by retaining it 8641 rather than paying it out?" 8642 8643 And you never know the answer to that. But so far, the answer, as judged by our results, is, "Yes, we can". And we think that prospectively we can. But that's a hope on our part. It's justified to some extent 8644 by past history, but it's not a certainty. 8645 8646 Once we've crossed that threshold, then we ask ourselves, "Should we repurchase stock?" 8647 8648 Well, obviously, if you can buy your stock at a significant discount from conservatively calculated intrinsic value and you can buy a reasonable quantity, that's a sensible use for capital. 8649 8650 Beyond that, the question becomes, "If you have the capital and you think that you can create more than a dollar, how do you create the most value with the least risk?" And that gets to business risk.. .I can 8651 determine it by looking at the business, the competitive environment in which it operates and so on. 8652 8653 So once we cross the threshold of deciding that we can deploy capital so as to create more than a dollar of present value for every dollar retained, then it's just a question of doing the most intelligent 8654 thing you can find. And the cost of every deal that we do is measured by the second best deal that's around at a given time - including doing more of some of the things we're already in. (Warren Buffett, 8655 Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2001, Outstanding Investor Digest, Year End 2001 Edition, pp.38-39.) 8656 8657 On how to avoid problems 8658 8659 We handle negotiations way different than anybody. When we bought See's Candy, I spent an hour there. Every business we've bought on one call. On the Borsheim's deal, I dropped over to Ike Friedman's house 8660 for half an hour. He showed me some figures that weren't audited penciled on a piece of paper. 8661 8662 lfl need a team oflawyers and accountants, it isn't going to be a good deal. We've never 8663 8664 had an extended negotiation with anybody about anything. That's just not our style. If it's going to be that way, I don't want to deal with them - because it's going to ruin my life sooner or later. So we 8665 just walk away. (Warren Buffett, lecture at Stanford Law School, March 23, 1990, Outstanding Investor Digest, April 18, 1990, p.18.) 8666 8667 275 8668 8669 Buffett: Some businesses are a lot easier to understand than others. And Charlie and I don't like difficult problems. If something is difficult to figure... We'd rather multiply by 3 than by1t. Munger: That's 8670 such an obvious point. Yet so many people think that if they just hire somebody with the appropriate labels, they can do something very difficult. That is one of the most dangerous ideas a human being can 8671 have. All kinds of things can create problems by causing complexity. The other day I was dealing with a problem - it was a new building. And I said, "This problem has three things I've learned to fear- an 8672 architect, a contractor and a hill." If you go through life like that, I think you'll at least make fewer mistakes than people who think they can do anything, no matter how complex, by just hiring somebody 8673 with a credible 8674 8675 label. You don't have to hire out your thinking if you keep it simple... 8676 8677 Buffett: If you get into some complicated business, you can get a report that's 1,000 pages thick and you can have Ph.D.'s working on it. But it doesn't mean anything. What you'll have is a report. But you 8678 won't have any better understanding of that business and what it's going to look like in 10 or 15 years. The big thing to do is to avoid being wrong. (Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1994, Outstanding 8679 Investor Digest, June 23, 1994, p.23.) 8680 8681 On the real risk of investing 8682 8683 In our opinion, the real risk that an investor must assess is whether his aggregate after-tax receipts from an investment (including those he receives on sale) will, over his prospective holding period, give 8684 him at least as much purchasing power as he had to begin with, plus a modest rate of interest on that initial stake. Though this risk cannot be calculated with engineering precision, it can in some cases be 8685 judged with a degree of accuracy that is useful. The primary factors bearing upon this evaluation are: 8686 8687 The certainty with which the long-term economic characteristics of the business can be evaluated; 8688 8689 The certainty with which management can be evaluated, both to its ability to realize the full potential of the business and to wisely employ its cash flows; 8690 8691 The certainty with which management can be counted on to channel the rewards from the business to the shareholders rather than to itself; 8692 8693 The purchase price of the business: 8694 8695 The levels of taxation and inflation that will be experienced and that will determine the degree by which an investor's purchasing power return is reduced from his gross return. (Warren Buffett, Berkshire 8696 Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1993, p.135.) 8697 8698 On the difficulty of developing a fair social system 8699 8700 Let's just say, Sandy, that it was 24 hours before you were born, and a genie appeared, and said "Sandy, you look like a winner. I have enormous confidence in you, and what I'm going to do is let you set the 8701 rules of the society into which you will be born. You can set the economic rules, thesocial rules, and whatever rules you set will apply during your lifetime, and your children's lifetimes." 8702 8703 And you'll say, "Well, that's nice, but what's the catch?" 8704 8705 And the genie says, "Here's the catch. You don't know if you're going to be born rich or poor, white or black, male or female, able-bodied or infirm, intelligent or retarded. All you 8706 8707 276 8708 8709 know is that you're going to get one ball out of a barrel with, say, 5.8 billion balls in it." You're going to participate in what I call the Ovarian Lottery. And it's the most important thing that will 8710 happen to you in your life, but you have no control over it. It's going to determine far more than your grades at school or anything else that happens to you. 8711 8712 Now, what rules do you want to have? I'm not going to tell you the rules, and nobody will tell you; you have to make them up for yourself. But they will affect how you think about what you do in your will and 8713 things of that sort. That's because you're going to want to have a system that turns out great quantities of goods and services, so that your kids can live better than you did, and so that your grandchildren 8714 can live better than your kids. You're going to want a system that keeps Bill Gates and Andy Grove and Jack Welch working long, long after they don't need to work. You're going to want the most able people 8715 working more than 12 hours a day. So you've got to have a system that incentives them, and that turns out goods. 8716 8717 But you're also going to want a system that takes care of the bad balls, the ones that aren't lucky. If you have a system that is turning out enough goods and services, you can take care of them. You want a 8718 system where people are free of fear to some extent. You don't want people worrying about being sick in their old age, or fearful about going home at night. So you'll try to design something, assuming you 8719 have the goods and services to solve that sort of thing. You'll want equaliry of opportunity- a good public school system - to make you feel that every piece of talent out there will get the same shot at 8720 contributing. And your tax system will follow from your reasoning on that. And what you do with the money you make is another thing to think about it. As you work through that, everybody comes up with 8721 something a little different. I just suggest you play that little game. (Warren Buffett, "Buffett & Gates on Success", KCTS/Seattle, May 1998, transcript p.12.) 8722 8723 For other issues regarding investing, business economics and managing, read the annual reports of Berkshire Hathaway Inc. (www.berkshirehathaway.com) and subscribe to Outstanding Investor Digest. 8724 (www.oid.com) 8725 8726 277 8727 8728 - APPENDIX THREE - 8729 8730 PROBABILITY 8731 8732 Blaise Pascal and Pierre Fermat developed the fundamental principles of probability in a series ofletters exchanged starting in the year 1654. 8733 8734 Definitions 8735 8736 Experiment is the process of obtaining an observation. For example: Toss a coin twice and observe what happens. 8737 8738 Outcome is the possible result of the experiment. All possible outcomes of the experiment are called the sample space. The experiment of tossing a coin twice results in one of four possible outcomes - 8739 Tail/Tail Head/Head, Head/Tail, or Tail/Head. 8740 8741 Event is a set of outcomes of the experiment. One event would be: Observe at least one head. This event consists of the three outcomes HH, HT, TH A compound event is an event composed of two or more separate 8742 events. 8743 8744 Independent events - two events A and Bare independent if no event can influence the probability of the other. Event A: observe one head when flipping a coin. Event B: observe one tail when flipping another 8745 coin. Each flip is independent of the other since whatever happens to the first coin cannot influence the flip of the second or tell us what outcome is likely to happen when we flip the second coin. 8746 8747 Mutually exclusive events - two events are mutually exclusive if they cannot happen at the same time i.e. they have no outcomes in common. A single coin is tossed. There are two events: observing a head or 8748 observing a tail. Observing a head excludes the possibility of observing a tail. Two events are non-mutually exclusive if they have one or more outcomes in common. A single die is tossed. Event A: observe a 8749 four. Event B: observe an even number. These events have one outcome in common since an "even number" consists of the numbers 2, 4, and 6. 8750 8751 Probability - a number between O and I that measures how likely an event is to happen over the long run. A probability of I means an event happens with certainty and a probability of O means it is impossible 8752 for an event to happen. 8753 8754 Arithmetic mean of a set of outcomes is usually called the average value of these outcomes. To 8755 8756 find the mean of the numbers 1,8,6,4,7, we add the numbers together-26-and divide by 5 = 5.2. 8757 8758 Variability shows how concentrated or spread out the outcomes are around the arithmetic mean. 8759 8760 Expectation is the average value we expect to observe if we perform a large number of experiments. Also called expected value- the probability-weighted sum of all possible outcomes. 8761 8762 Population - the total number of something - outcomes, objects, events, etc. It is a group that has at least one characteristic in common from which our sample of data is selected. 8763 8764 278 8765 8766 Sample - a representative and randomly taken part of the population that is studied in order to draw conclusions about the population. The larger the sample, the better our estimate of the probability. But 8767 observe that what is essential is the absolute size of the sample (e.g. the number of people who've been asked), not its proportion of the population. A random sample of 3,000 from the entire U.S. is more 8768 predictive than a sample of 40 from a particular university. A random sample is one in which every item in the population is equally likely to be chosen. 8769 8770 How do we decide the probability of an event? 8771 8772 The laws of probability tell us what is likely to happen over a large number of trials. This means we can expect to make reasonable predictions what on average are likely to happen over the long run, but we 8773 can't predict the outcome of a particular event. 8774 8775 There are three ways to measure probability: the logical way, the relative frequency way, and the subjective way. 8776 8777 The logical way 8778 8779 The logical way can be used in situations where we know the number of outcomes and where all these outcomes are equally likely. For example in games of chance, we find the probability by dividing the number 8780 of outcomes that are favorable to the event (yield the outcome we look for) with the total number of possible outcomes. Observe that this definition can only be applied if we can analyze a situation into 8781 equally likely outcomes. 8782 8783 What is the probability that we observe one head when tossing a coin? The number of equally likely favorable outcomes is one (head) and the total number of possible equally likely outcomes is two (head and 8784 tail) and therefore the probability is½ or 50%. 8785 8786 Relative frequency 8787 8788 When an experiment can be repeated many times, probability is the proportion of times the event happened in relation to an infinite number of experiments. In most cases we don't know the probability of an 8789 event. Why? Because we can't know all the outcomes. We must then try to estimate the long-term relative frequency by performing experiments or by finding representative information about how often an event 8790 happened in the past. 8791 8792 By representative we mean that the information must be based on the relative frequency of historical data over a large number of independent experiments or observations of the same reference class under 8793 essentially the same conditions. The reference class is the one for which the distribution of outcomes is known or can be reasonable estimated. The more relevant cases we examine, the better our chance is to 8794 estimate correctly the underlying probability. 8795 8796 Conduct an experiment to test how likely it is that you toss head. Toss a coin 1000 times and observe what happens. Jfyou got heads 400 times the relative frequency or the fraction between the number of 8797 tossed heads (number of times the events happened) and the total number of tosses (number of experiments) is 400/1000. Toss a coin 2000 times and observe what happens. If you got heads 900 times the relative 8798 frequency is 900/2000. The more tosses, the less the difference will be between an events theoretical probability and the relative frequency with which it happens. In this case it will move towards the value 8799 ½. 8800 8801 279 8802 8803 What is the frequency of losses? How are losses distributed over time? What is their magnitude? Insurance companies use relative frequencies. They base their premiums on an estimate of how likely it is that a 8804 specific event that cause them to pay happen. If they assume the past is a representative guide for the future they try to find out the relative frequency of a specific "accident" by observing past 8805 frequencies of specific accidents. 8806 8807 Suppose the probability that a given house will burn is 0.3%. This means that the insurance company found historical data and other indicators about a large number of houses (for example the reference class 8808 is "50 years of data of fires in a given area'') and discovered that, in the past, 3 out of 1,000 houses in a given area will burn. It also means that, assuming there are no changes in the causes of these 8809 fires, we can predict approximately the same proportion of fires in the foture. An insurance company knows that in a given year a certain percentage of their policyholders will have an accident. They don't 8810 know which ones, but they diversify their risk by insuring many individuals. What is unpredictable for one person can be predictable for a large population. But they must make sure the events are independent 8811 and that not a single event or a confluence ofindependent events affects multiple policyholders causing the insurer to pay out on many claims at one time. For example, an insurance company who provides fire 8812 insurance to a number of buildings in a single block may face ruin if a large fire happens. 8813 8814 Subjective probability 8815 8816 If an experiment is not repeatable or when there is no representative historical relative frequency, or comparable data, the probability is then a measure of our personal degree of belief in the likelihood of 8817 an event happening. We have to make a subjective evaluation or a personal estimation using whatever information is available. But we can't just assign any number to events. They must agree with the rules of 8818 probability. 8819 8820 A New York Rangers supporter might say, "I believe that the NY Rangers have a 90% chance of winning their next match since they have been playing so well. " 8821 8822 Rules of probability 8823 8824 When two events are independent (no event can influence the probability of the other), the probability that they both will happen is the product of their individual probabilities. We can write this as: Both A 8825 and B will happen= P(A) x P(B). 8826 8827 A company has two independent manufacturing processes. In process one, 5% of the produced items are defective, and in process two, 3 %. If we pick one item from each process, how likely is it that both items 8828 are defective? 0.15% (0.05 x 0.03). 8829 8830 This rule is changed if the events are dependent. In many situations the probability of an event depends on the outcome of some other event. Events are often related in a way so that if one event happens, it 8831 makes the other event more or less likely to happen. For example, if we toss a die and event A is: observe an even number, and event B: observe a number less than 4, then given we know B has happened, the 8832 probability is 1/3. This is called a conditional probability or the probability that an event happen given that some other event has happened. Conditional probabilities involve dependent events. The 8833 conditional probability of A given B is 1/3 since we know B was either 1,2 or 3 and only 2 implies event A. 8834 8835 280 8836 8837 What is the probability that there are two boys in a two-child family given that there is at least one boy? Ask: What can happen or what are the number of outcomes that are equally likely to happen? Boy/Boy- 8838 Girl/Girl - Boy/Girl - Girl/Boy. Since we already know that there is "at least one boy'; we can rule out scenario "Girl/Girl" The probability is therefore 113 or 33%. 8839 8840 What is the probability that there are two boys in a two-child family given that the first-born is a boy? The number of outcomes that are equally likely to happen are: Boy/Boy - Girl/Girl - Boy/Girl - 8841 Girl/Boy. Since we already know that the older child is a boy, we can rule out scenario GB and GG. The probability is 50%. 8842 8843 A problem in conditional probability that has caused many mathematics professors problems, is the Monty Hall Dilemma. The columnist Marilyn vos Savant (Parade 1990, Sept 9, p. 13.) asked the following 8844 problem: 8845 8846 "Suppose you're on a game show, and you're given the choice of three doors. Behind one door is a car; behind the others, goats. You pick a door, say No. l, and the host, who knows what's behind the doors, 8847 opens another door, say No. 3, which has a goat. He then says to you, 'Do you want to pick door No. 2?' Is it to your advantage to switch your choice?" 8848 8849 How would you answer? Assume we always have the opportunity to switch. Make a table of possible outcomes and test in how many outcomes it pays to switch doors. 8850 8851 Door 1 8852 8853 Door2 8854 8855 Door3 8856 8857 Car 8858 8859 Goat 8860 8861 Goat 8862 8863 Goat 8864 8865 Car 8866 8867 Goat 8868 8869 Goat 8870 8871 Goat 8872 8873 Car 8874 8875 Assume you choose door number 1. What are then the consequences if the car is in door 1, 8876 8877 2 or 3? 8878 8879 Car behind door 8880 8881 Host 012ens door 8882 8883 You switch 8884 8885 You don't switch 8886 8887 1 8888 8889 2 8890 8891 Lose 8892 8893 Win 8894 8895 2 8896 8897 3 8898 8899 Win 8900 8901 Lose 8902 8903 3 8904 8905 2 8906 8907 Win 8908 8909 Lose 8910 8911 2/3 8912 8913 1/3 8914 8915 We should always switch doors since we win 2/3 of the time. They key to this problem is that we know ahead of the game (conditional) that the host knows what is behind each door and always opens a door with a 8916 goat behind it. 8917 8918 When two events are mutually exclusive (can't both happen at the same time), the probability that one or the other will happen is the sum of their respective probabilities. We can write this as: Either A or B 8919 will happen = P(A) + P(B). 8920 8921 What is the probability that we get either a two or a four when a single die is tossed once? There are 6 outcomes and the two events ("getting a two" and ''getting a four") have no outcomes in common. We 8922 can't get both a two and a four on the same toss. How many favorable outcomes are 8923 8924 281 8925 8926 there or in how many ways can we get a two? In one out of six. In how many ways can we get a four? In one out of six. The probability that we get a four or a six is 1/6 + 1/6 = 33%. 8927 8928 When two events are non-mutually exclusive (both can happen at the same time), the probability that at least one of them will happen is equal to the sum of the probabilities of the two events minus the 8929 probability that both events happen. We can write this complementary rule as: P(A) + P(B) - P(A and B). 8930 8931 Assume that the probability a Los Angeles teenager ownsa surfing board is 25%, a bicycle 85%, and owning both 20%. If we randomly choose a Los Angeles teenager, the probability that he or she owns a surfing 8932 board or a bicycle is (0.25 + 0.85) - 0.20 = 90%. These events had two outcomes in common since the teenager could have both a surfing board and a bicycle. 8933 8934 Sometimes it is easier to deal with problems if we turn them backwards. The probability of an event not happening is 1 minus the probability it will happen. If the probability of an event A is 30%, then the 8935 probability that the event won't happen is 70% because "not event A" is the complement of the event A. The sum of probability of an event happening and probability of the same event not happening is always 1. 8936 8937 What is the probability that we get at least one six in four rolls of a single die? We turn the question around and calculate the probability of "not getting any sixes in four rolls ofa die''. There are four 8938 independent events - not getting a six on the first throw... second... The probability of each one is 516 since there are five outcomes (1,2,3,4,5) which results in the event "no six" and each is independent 8939 of what happened before. This means that the probability of not getting any sixes are 516 x 516 x 516 x 516 or 48.2%. Therefore "the probability ofgetting at least one six" is 1 8940 8941 - [3m0.482 or 51.8%. [0mCounting possible outcomes 8942 8943 The multiplication principle says that if one event can happen in "n" different ways, and a second event can happen independent of the first in "m" different ways, the two events can happen in nm different 8944 ways. 8945 8946 Suppose there are 4 different flights between Los Angeles and New York, 3 between New York and Boston and 5 between Boston and Bermuda. The number of itineraries assuming we can connect between any of the 8947 stated flights are 4 x 3 x 5 = 60. 8948 8949 Permutations or rearrangements mean the different ways we can order or arrange a number of objects. 8950 8951 We have 3 hats to choose from - one black, one white and one brown. In how many ways can we arrange them if the order white, black and brown is different from the order black, white and brown? This is the 8952 same as asking how many permutations there are with three hats, taken three at a time. We can arrange the hats in 6 ways: Black-White-Brown, Black-Brown-White, White Black-Brown, White-Brown-Black, 8953 Brown-White-Black, Brown-Black-White. 8954 8955 Another way to think about this: We have three boxes in a row where we put a different hat in each box. We can fill the first box in three ways, since we can choose between all three hats. We can then fill 8956 the second box in two ways, since we now can choose between only two hats. We can fill 8957 8958 282 8959 8960 the third box in only one way, since we have only one hat left. This means we can fill the box in 3 x 2 x 1 = 6 ways. 8961 8962 Another way to write this is 3!If we haven (6) boxes and can choose from all of them, there are n (6) choices. Then we are left with n-1 (5) choices for box number two, n-2 (4) choices for box number three 8963 and so on. The number of permutations of n boxes is n!. What n! - Factorial- means is the product of all numbers from 1 ton. 8964 8965 Suppose we havea dinner in our home with 12 people sitting around a table. How many seating arrangements are possible? The first person that enters the room can choose between twelve chairs, the second 8966 between eleven chairs and so on, meaning there are 12! or 479,001,600 different seating arrangements. 8967 8968 The number of ways we can arrange r objects from a group of n objects is called a permutation of n objects taken rat a time and is defined as n! / (n-r)! 8969 8970 A safe has 100 digits. To open the safe a burglar needs to pick the correct 3 different numbers. Is it likely? The number ofpermutations or ways ofarranging 3 digits from 100 digits is 970,200 8971 8972 (100!/(J 00-3J!). If every permutation takes the burglar 5 seconds, all permutations are tried in 8973 8974 56 days assuming a 24-hour working day. 8975 8976 Combinations means the different ways we can choose a number of different objects from a group of objects where no order is involved, just the number of ways of choosing them. 8977 8978 In how many ways can we combine 2 flavors of ice cream if we can choose from strawberry (SJ, 8979 8980 vanilla (V), and chocolate (CJ without repeated flavors?We can combine them in 3 ways: SV,SC, VC. VS and SVare a combination of the same ice creams. The order doesn't matter. Vanilla on the top is the same as 8981 vanilla on the bottom. 8982 8983 The number of ways we can select r objects from a group of n objects is called a combination of n objects taken rat a time and is defined as n! / r!(n-r)! 8984 8985 The numberof ways we can select 3 people taken from agroup of 10 people is 120 (10!/3!(10-3J!). 8986 8987 The binomial distribution 8988 8989 Suppose we take a true-false test with 10 questions. We don't know anything about the subject. All we can do is guess. To pass this test, we must answer exactly 5 questions correct. Are we likely to do that 8990 by guessing? 8991 8992 How should we reason? Ask: How many equally likely independent outcomes are there when we guess? There are 2 possible outcomes. Either we are right or wrong. If the test only had one question, the probability 8993 that we guess the right answer is 50%. The probability that we guess the wrong answer is also 50% {1- the probability of guessing the right answer). 8994 8995 What is the total number of equally likely outcomes? Since every question has 2 possible outcomes and there are 10 questions there are a total of 210 outcomes or 1,024 possible true false combinations. We can 8996 answer the test in 1,024 different ways. What is the number of favorable outcomes? There is only one way we can answer all 10 questions right (or wrong). They all have to be right (or wrong). The chance of 8997 getting all 10 answers right or wrong by guessing is therefore 1 in 1024. This means that if we took the test 1,024 times and guessed 8998 8999 283 9000 9001 randomly at the answers each time, just once in 1,024 times should we expect to get all 10 9002 9003 answers right or wrong. 9004 9005 In how many ways can we be right on 5 questions? Let's go back to combinations and ask: in how many ways can we select 5 questions if we can choose from 10 questions? There are 252 ways (10!/5!(10-5)!) we can 9006 answer 10 questions to get exactly a score of 5. Since each guess has a 50% probability of being right and there are 10 questions and we want to be right on exactly 5 of them and there are 252 equally likely 9007 ways we can answer 5 questions, then the probability that we answer exactly 5 questions right is (0.5)5 x (0.5)5 x 252 = 24.6% 9008 9009 How likely is it then that we answer at least 5 questions correctly? This probability must be higher since we also can answer 6, 7, 8, 9 or 10 questions correct. Therefore we must add the probability that we 9010 guess 6, 7, 8, 9, and 10 questions correct. 9011 9012 In how many ways can we be right on 5 questions? 10!/5!(10-5)! = 252 ways In how many ways can we be right on 6 questions? 10!/6!(10-6)! = 210 ways In how many ways can we be right on 7 questions? 9013 10!/7!(10-7)! = 120 ways In how many ways can we be right on 8 questions? 10!/8!(10-8)! 45 ways In how many ways can we be right on 9 questions? 10!/9!(10-9)! = 10 ways Inhowmanywayscanweberighton 9014 lOquestions? 10!/10!(10-10)!= 1 way 9015 9016 Total = 638 ways 9017 9018 Since each guess has a 50% probability of being right and there are 10 questions and we want to be right on at least 5 of them and there are 638 equally likely ways we can answer at least 5 questions, the 9019 probability that we answer at least 5 questions right is (0.5)5 x (0.5) 5 x 638 = 62.3%. 9020 9021 The example illustrated a binomial experiment. The probability distribution for a binomial experiment is: Number of possible ways of selecting k things from n things (observing k successes inn trials) x 9022 (probability of success)k (1 - probability of success)n-k 9023 9024 If we put in the above figures we get: 252 x (0.5)5 x (0.5)5 + 210 x (0.5)6 x (0.5)4 + 120 x 9025 9026 (0.5)7 x (0.5)3 + 45 X (0.5)' X (0.5)2 + 10 X (0.5)9 X (0.5)' + lx (0.5)' 0 X (0.5)0 = 62.3% 9027 9028 Binomial experiments have the following characteristics: An event that is repeatable or the experiment consists of n number of identical and independent trials. There are only two outcomes in every trial - 9029 success/failure, right/wrong, present/absent, 0/1 etc. and the probabilities of success and failure are constant in every trial. 9030 9031 Examples of binomial experiments are firing a projectile at a target (hit/miss), developing a new drug (effective/not effective), dosing a sale (sale/no sale) etc. 9032 9033 We toss a single die 5 times. How likely is it that you will roll exactly 3 sixes? What is success? Rolling a 6 on a single die. What's the probability of rolling a 6 on a single die? 1/6 (there are 6 9034 outcomes and one of them is a success). What is the probability of failure? 1-1/6 = 516. What is the number of trials? 5. What is the number of successes out of those trials? 3. In how many ways can you roll 9035 three sixes (successes) in 5 trials? 5!/3!(5-3)! = JO Probability= JO x (116)3 x (5/6J = 3.2% 9036 9037 A boat has three independent engines and needs at least two to work properly. The probability that each engine works properly is 98%. The probability that all three engines work is 94.1% 9038 9039 284 9040 9041 ) . 9042 9043 (0.983 The probability that at least one engine fails (either engine 1, 2 or 3) is therefore 5.9% 9044 9045 (this is the same as the probability that exactly 1 engine fail + exactly 2 engines fails + exactly 3 engines fails). 9046 9047 What is the probability that at least 2 engines work? Let's go back to combinations and the binomial distribution: probability (3 engines work) + probability (2 engines work) = 3!/3!(3-3)! x (0.98)3 x (0.02)" 9048 + 3!/2!(3-2)! x (0.98J x (0.02)1 = 99.8816%. The probability that at least two engines will fail is therefore 0.1184%. The boat will fail to work in 1 out of 845 times. 9049 9050 Let's add a backup engine. What is now the probability that at least 2 engines work? Probability (4 engines work) + probability (3 engines work) + probability (2 engines work) = 4!/4!(4-4)! x (0.98)4 X 9051 (0.02)" + 4f/3f(4-3)! X (0.98)3 X (0.02)1 + 4f/2f(4-2)f X (0.98/ X (0.02/ = 9052 9053 99.996848%. The probability that at least three engines will fail is therefore 0.003152%. The boat will now only fail in 1 out o/31,726 times. 9054 9055 Binomial probabilities assume independence. It may be that the failure of one engine increases the failure probability of a second engine. For example, the failure of one engine increases the load on which 9056 the second engine is run. Using one engine causes more stress and wear to the second engine, etc. 9057 9058 Calculations to some of the examples 9059 9060 Page 9061 9062 150 The possible number of ways we can choose 6 numbers out of 49 are 49!/(49-6)!6! 9063 9064 = 13,983,816. 9065 9066 24 hours equals 1,440 minutes. One 365-day year equals 525,600 minutes. 14 million minutes equals about 27 years. 9067 9068 The probability we succeed is (0.8) 6 or 26%. 9069 9070 ) 9071 9072 The probability that IO mutually independent start-ups all succeed is 0.01% (0.410 9073 9074 ) . 9075 9076 but the probability that at least one succeeds is 99.4% (I - 0.610 9077 9078 ) . 9079 9080 The probability that at least one of the parts don't work is 86.5% (1 - 0.999 2000 Assuming independence, the probability of system failure (where at least one part must fail for the system to fail) is 1 9081 minus the reliability of the system. 9082 9083 161 Assuming independence, the probability of system failure (where both navigation systems must fail for the system to fail) is the product of the probabilities of primary and back up system failing. 9084 9085 162 An event that has one chance in 20 of happening in any given year is nearly certain to happen over 50 years (I - 0.95 50 = 92.3%). If there is a 5% chance that an event happens in any given year, then the 9086 chance that it won't happen is 95%. The chance that it won't happen over 50 years is 7.7%. This means that the probability that the event happens at least once is 92.3%. 9087 9088 285 9089 9090 162 The probability that at least one accident will happen in any given year is 3.9% {1- 9091 9092 0.99940). The probability that at least one accident will happen during the next 10 years is 33% (1 - 0.96110 ). 9093 9094 162 The probability of a major earthquake happening in any given year (assumed to be a constant) is therefore 3.2% ((1-p)30 = 38%). The probability that a major earthquake 9095 9096 ) . 9097 9098 will happen at least once during the next 5 years is 15% (1 - 0.9685 9099 9100 165 In a group of 1,048,576 (220) people it happens to someone. In fact, in the U.S. a country with 280 million people, one in a million chance events happen 280 times a day (1/1,000,000 x 280 million). 9101 9102 165 1 person has 365 possible birthdays if we assume that there are 365 days to choose from and that all birthdays are equally likely to happen. When there are 2 persons in a group the second person can 9103 choose among 364 possible birthdays that are not shared with the first person. The second person only shares 1 day with the first person. The chance that 2 persons share birthdays is therefore 1 out of365 or 9104 0.27%. When there are 3 people in a group it is easier to find the likelihood that 2 of them share a birthday by first finding out how likely it is that no one of these 3 people share birthdays. When there 9105 are 3 people in a group the third person can choose among 363 possible birthdays that are not shared with any of the first 2 persons. This means that the chance that the third person will not share birthday 9106 with any of the first 2 persons is 363 out of365 or 99.45%. 9107 9108 To find the probability that multiple events happen, we multiply the individual probabilities together. The probability that no one in a group of 3, share birthday is therefore: 365/365 x 364/365 x 363/365 = 9109 99.18%. Therefore, the probability that 2 people in a group of 3 share birthdays is 1 - 0.9918 or 0.82%. Let's repeat this procedure for a group of 23 people: 9110 9111 365 X 364 X 363 X ••••••343 = 49.30/o. 9112 9113 365 23 9114 9115 Therefore, the probability that 2 people in a group of 23, share birthdays is 1 - 0.493 or 50.7%. 9116 9117 178 At the end of 10 predictions, one monkey has a perfect record of predicting the direction of interest rates (1,000 x 0.510). 9118 9119 180 The number of ways to get 2 successes in 10 trials are 10!/ (10-2)!2! or 45. The probability is 45x (O.8 )2 x (O. 2)8 or 0.007%. 9120 9121 286 9122 9123 - APPENDIX FOUR - 9124 9125 CHECKLISTS 9126 9127 Helpful for achieving goals, making choices, solving problems, evaluating what is likely to be true or false etc. 9128 9129 Use notions 9130 9131 Use the big ideas that underlie reality 9132 9133 Understand what something really means 9134 9135 Simplify 9136 9137 Use rules and filters 9138 9139 Know what I want to achieve 9140 9141 Find and evaluate alternatives 9142 9143 Understand consequences and their consequences on the whole 9144 9145 Quantify 9146 9147 Search for and base things on evidence 9148 9149 Think things through backward 9150 9151 Remember that big effects come from large combinations of factors 9152 9153 Evaluate the consequences ifI'm wrong 9154 9155 What is the issue? 9156 9157 What's the question? What is this really about? 9158 9159 What's the essence or nub of the issue? What is then the key question? 9160 9161 Relevant? Solvable? Important? Knowable? Utility- applicability? 9162 9163 Do I understand what the subject is all about? In order to have an opinion on a subject I need some relevant data and basic knowledge about the subject, otherwise just say: "I don't know". 9164 9165 Is my judgment here better than others? 9166 9167 What must I predict here and is it predictable? 9168 9169 Is a decision needed? What happens if I don't deal with this? Is this something I can do anything about? Should "I" do this? 9170 9171 Over what period of time am I considering this issue? Where am I at present? From whose point of view? 9172 9173 Simplify by deciding big "no-brainer questions" first and begin from where I am. 9174 9175 Understand what it means 9176 9177 Translate words and ideas in terms I understand. Do I understand what words and statements really mean and imply? Does it mean anything? Will it help me make useful predictions on what is likely to happen? 9178 9179 287 9180 9181 - Do I understand how and why something works and happens? What is it doing? Why does it do that? What is happening? How and why is this happening? What is the consequence of this (observation, finding, 9182 event, experience...)? 9183 9184 - Definitions and implications? 9185 9186 Filters and Rules 9187 9188 - Use filters incl. rules and default rules - what test(s) can I make? 9189 9190 - Adapt to my psychological nature, abilities, advantages, and limitations 9191 9192 - Consider values and preferences and therefore priorities and what I want to avoid 9193 9194 What do I specifically and measurable want to achieve and avoid and when and why? 9195 9196 - What future "value" do I want to achieve? Target numbers? Target effects? Time horizon? 9197 9198 - Assume I have already reached my target. What would this imply in numbers and effects? What must then have been achieved? Is it (target) reasonable? Is it reasonable ifI reverse this to the present? 9199 9200 - Do I have ways to measure to what degree my goal is being achieved? Key variables or components of yardstick? 9201 9202 - IfI achieve this what will happen? Do I want that to happen? 9203 9204 - Can I break my goal into short-term goals with deadlines? 9205 9206 - What is my real reason for doing this? Is it because I want to or because I have to? Have I stated my goal from internal and external realities or am I biased now or influenced by some psychological forces? 9207 9208 - Can I express my goal in a way that makes it easier to see how it is going to be achieved? 9209 9210 - Is this the true goal for what I want to achieve? 9211 9212 What is the cause of that? 9213 9214 - To achieve my goal I must understand what causes my goal to be achieved 9215 9216 - What is the equation for goal and what evidence do I have for that? 9217 9218 - What don't I want to achieve? What causes non-goal and what can I do to avoid that? What must I not do or what must I avoid? 9219 9220 - What variables influence the system? What are the critical forces and variables, the ones that account for the main outcome? What is the key unknown? What is the certainty with which I can evaluate, 9221 optimize ... the different variables? 9222 9223 - Which variables are dependent on other variables (or situation, environment, context, timing, behavior) and which ones act independently of each other? 9224 9225 - What force causes a variable to be achieved? What produces the force(s)? Are there short and long-term forces? What is their relative strength? How do they combine and interact and what are the effects? How 9226 can I get many forces to operate together in the same direction? What lack of force would destroy the system? What produces this force? How predictable are they? What can the forces in place rationally expect 9227 to cause? What forces are temporary and which ones are permanent? How will the system change as the forces that act on the variable change? 9228 9229 - How resistant is the system to a change in the variables and/or forces? What are the likely 9230 9231 288 9232 9233 wanted and unwanted short- and long-term consequences (on numbers and effects) of changes (up/down) - scale, size or mass, strength, intensity, length, time horizon, environment, participants etc. - in the 9234 variables or forces? What happens when a number of small causes operate over a long time? What are the consequences if a force acts on the variable over a long time? Which force could change it? What is 9235 needed to create a critical mass? What forces when added can create a critical mass? How? Will something else happen when I change a variable or force? What must happen for a force to change? Can a change 9236 produce other consequences (observe that I am interested in effects on the whole system and the final outcome)? Does a change in one variable make a dramatic difference in outcome? Will the properties also 9237 change? What are the consequences if the relation between the variables changes? What is the change point? Barriers? Catalyst? Tipping point? Inflection point? Break point? Limits? Is there a time lag before 9238 effects happen? Feedback? What can speed up the cause? What are the critical points when the effects get reversed? What can I change in the equation and what can others change? How? Who? When? Which variables 9239 must I change to achieve goal? How can I measure the amount of change? Degree of sensitivity ifl change the assumptions? Effects on goal and path? What will happen ifl hold one variable constant? Ifl at the 9240 same time increase one variable and decrease another? Net effect? Ifl change one variable or force at a time? What is it in the environment that can change the situation? What other advantages and 9241 disadvantages can I achieve if I optimize one of the variables? What must happen to cause a change in outcome? Is it still a variable ifl change the conditions? 9242 9243 - Are there exceptions to the equation and why? What conditions are required to achieve goal? Has my goal different cause short-term and long-term? Is the cause time-dependent? Can I deduce the cause by 9244 observing the effects? Have I looked upon the system from different angles and viewpoints? What does the measurement of the subject depend on? 9245 9246 - What is the major constraint that limits the goal from being achieved? 9247 9248 What available alternatives do I have to achieve my goal? 9249 9250 - Judge alternatives in terms of goal, subject in question, rules and filters, cause and effect, human behavior, evidence, counter evidence, simplicity and opportunity cost of money, time, other resources, 9251 effort, understanding, risk and mental stress. 9252 9253 - What evidence (incl. models) do I have that these alternatives are most likely to achieve goal? 9254 9255 - Are they depending on time horizon or event? 9256 9257 - What are the likely consequences of each action? What possible outcomes can happen? Likelihood? How desirable is each consequence? 9258 9259 - Do I forego any future opportunities ifl make a specific action now? 9260 9261 What are the consequences? 9262 9263 - Find out which alternative are most likely to achieve my goal by estimating their likely consequences 9264 9265 - If I do this, what will happen? Why will this not happen? 9266 9267 - What are the likely (logical) wanted and unwanted (or unintended) consequences 9268 9269 289 9270 9271 (quantitative and qualitative) and consequences of consequences (immediate and over the course ofa long period) of each alternative/event (proposition) factoring in relevant variables? 9272 9273 - What are the different scenarios and outcomes that can happen? What is likely to happen short and long-term based on the evidence? 9274 9275 - What can help me make predictions on consequences or if something is likely to be true or false? 9276 9277 - What must happen for the goal to be achieved? How likely is it that the necessary events will happen and happen to me? What does the probabilities favor? What will happen ifI reverse the proposition? 9278 9279 - What are the uncertainties that can significantly influence the outcome? What unintended consequences are there due to repeating effects, complications ... ? Is the net effect positive? Does the 9280 consequences predict anything else? What else does this mean? 9281 9282 - What are the consequences if this is true or false? 9283 9284 - Have I considered the whole system from different viewpoints? Have I considered social, financial, physical and emotional consequences? What are others likely to do? What are my experiences of earlier 9285 behavior? What happens when others do the same? 9286 9287 Bias 9288 9289 - Is there any reason for bias due to self-interest or psychological influences that may cause misjudgment? 9290 9291 - Is this a biased statement or a fact? What are factual judgments and what are value judgments? 9292 9293 - How reliable is he? Is he competent enough to judge? Credentials? What is his purpose with this? Does he have any motive to lie? How does he know that this is true? 9294 9295 The hypothesis 9296 9297 - Based on what I want to achieve; test statement implied by goal or statement for consequences. 9298 9299 - For every alternative ask: Is this alternative likely to achieve my goal (true)? For proposition ask: Is this proposition likely to be true? 9300 9301 - How can I test (testability) if this is true? Can I try to prove it is false before I try to see if it's true? 9302 9303 - What do I need to know ifI shall test this statement? I must first find out the equation for what causes the statement to be true so I know what is the most important I need to know the future true outcome 9304 of and then search for the evidence for and against that this will be achieved. What is the statement that should be proved? 9305 9306 - What is the simplest hypothesis? 9307 9308 Look for evidence and judge the evidence 9309 9310 - How likely is it that the key cause (for goal, non-goal, and proposition) will be achieved? 9311 9312 - When evaluating statements or true/false, look for meaning, motives, causes, consequences and evidence for and against. 9313 9314 - If this were true what would the consequences then imply? Are the consequences of it not 9315 9316 being true illogical or unbelievable? Does it have any predictability? 9317 9318 290 9319 9320 - How and where can I find the representative evidence if this is true? What is given? What are unquestionable truths? Will the test or other ways of measure give the same results when repeated (reliable)? 9321 Can I test for consequences (verifiable)? Is the evidence based on what is known and have I interpreted the data correct (valid)? What evidence do I have? Evidence against? What grounds do I have for 9322 accepting that evidence? Weight of evidence? What is the quality of the evidence? How credible is the evidence? Dependent on time, environment? Too small sample? Does the statement agree with the available 9323 evidence? Does it violate any scientific laws or laws of nature? 9324 9325 - What representative information do I have? What is happening by observation? Can I do an experiment to confirm my guess? Does it agree with experiment? 9326 9327 - What is the track record (case rate, base rate frequency, variability, average rate, degree of randomness, my own experiences, environment, players, and other relevant factors for the case) on what happened 9328 (worked and not) in the past? Is there any reason to believe that this record isn't representative for what is likely to happen in the future? What can make the future a lot different than the past? What's 9329 been permanent and what hasn't? 9330 9331 - How long can this continue? What is the major cause(s) now? What force(s) can make it continue, initiate a change, or stop it and why? Is it likely? 9332 9333 - Ifl get evidence that is the opposite of my previous convictions I must ask: How does this happen? What is going on here? What evidence do I have? What grounds do I have for accepting the evidence? 9334 9335 Disprove my (or others) conclusion by thinking like a prosecutor 9336 9337 - Consider causes for misjudgments 9338 9339 How can I test and prove that my idea and conclusion is wrong? What reasons are there why I might be wrong? Where can I find the evidence that suggest I am wrong? How credible is my evidence? What facts and 9340 evidence disagree with my conclusion/idea? 9341 9342 What major assumptions have I built the case on? Are they built on reality? Are their consequences logical? Has anyone proved that my assumptions are right? What are the consequences if my beliefs and 9343 assumptions are wrong? 9344 9345 What have I ignored or overlooked? Better alternatives? Have I ignored evidence? Have I taken into account the limitations when humans are involved? What factors are uncertain and why? Have I just projected 9346 present trends? What have I misinterpreted? Have I used the right definitions? Did I consider and combined all the relevant factors? Have I used the appropriate measure/yardstick? Did I go wrong in the 9347 measurement? Have I confused cause and correlation? What about if my goal is shaped by what I believe is true but it isn't? Are there random or systematic errors? What other causes can explain my results? 9348 Have I considered the whole system and that interacting parts sometimes can vary in unexpected and unwanted ways? 9349 9350 - Bias for my own ideas? Is my ego getting in the way of making an intelligent decision? Will I really beat the historical average/record? Have I looked for contrary effects? 9351 9352 - What do I not see? What is the significance of this? Does an inversion of the assumption lead to a logical absurdity? Is the opposite more likely? Is there any contrary evidence? What evidence can prove it 9353 is false (or not achieving goal)? What experimental (or experience, 9354 9355 291 9356 9357 observation... ) evidence are there that it's false? More evidence in favor of that? What causes it to be false? 9358 9359 - Meaning? Can I show that the consequences ofit being true are unbelievable? What is the implied effect ifl trace it out mathematically? Would the opposite of the statement be more likely? If yes, the 9360 proposition is probably false. 9361 9362 What is the downside? 9363 9364 - How can I be hurt? What could possible go wrong? What can turn this into a mistake? What would the consequences be? 9365 9366 - How often do things go wrong? Surprise factors? What can happen that will dramatically change the outcome? 9367 9368 - What is the worst thing that could happen - the nightmare scenario? How likely is that? What will I do if it does? What are the consequences if things go from bad to worse? And what are then the 9369 consequences? 9370 9371 - What are the consequences ifI get two or three forces acting in concert against me? Which alternatives net effects are least worse? 9372 9373 - Execution risk? 9374 9375 - What do I least like? What am I least sure of? 9376 9377 - Can an advantage give me unwanted consequences? How do I lose an advantage? 9378 9379 - How can I structure the "system" to minimize the influence of negatives? Antidotes to what I don't want happen? Do I have a backup plan for surprises? Can I correct it? What rules can I install to achieve 9380 goal and avoid non-goal? Is there a built-in safety factor? 9381 9382 What are the consequences if I am wrong? 9383 9384 - What key thing am I betting on? Do I risk what is important for me for something of relative low utility for me? 9385 9386 What is the cost (dollars, time, mental stress etc) of being wrong weighted against the benefit or value of being right compared to the next best available opportunity? 9387 9388 Ifl do this because I believe the consequences are in my best interest/it's true but I turn out wrong/it is false, what are the short- and long-term consequences (actual loss and opportunity cost loss) for my 9389 goal and can I handle them and/or reverse them? 9390 9391 IfI don't do this because I believe the consequences is not in my best interest/it's false but I turn out wrong/it's true, what are the short- and long-term consequences for my goal and can I handle them 9392 and/or reverse them? 9393 9394 - If I don't take a decision at all now because I don't believe it is necessary but I am wrong, 9395 9396 what are the short- and long-term consequences for my goal and can I handle them and/or reverse them? 9397 9398 What is the value? 9399 9400 What is the utility or preference of each of these alternatives to me? Which alternative is most likely to achieve my goal and ultimate objective? Is it really more attractive than the other choices I have? 9401 9402 What can I use as criteria to judge my alternatives against each other? 9403 9404 292 9405 9406 - What do I like best if I weigh the alternatives against each other by assigning their characteristics numerical values? 9407 9408 - Will it make a difference? Make an impact? How willing am I to accept certain outcomes? 9409 9410 What yardstick can be used to measure progress or to measure things against? 9411 9412 - What yardstick(s) do I use? What is the yardstick by which the decision is made? 9413 9414 - How can I easily measure to what degree my goal are being achieved? What indicators can I track? 9415 9416 - Does the "system" give people an incentive to behave in a way so that my goal will be achieved? Or does it work against the goal? 9417 9418 How act now? 9419 9420 - Can I execute? What specific action(s) do I have to do (must do) now? What do I need to do first? 9421 9422 Who is going to do what, where, when, why and how? 9423 9424 Have I decided on where the critical points (time and effects) are? 9425 9426 Have I installed some kind of control stations and rules? Why is this the right rule? What are the consequences if I don't install chis rule (or change my way of doing something)? What administrative and 9427 practical actions must I do due to the rule? How much time will it take to follow the rule? Can I control how I follow the rule? Can I install a time-limited rule? Where does the rules not work? 9428 9429 Have I made an active decision? 9430 9431 - Am I prepared to change the decision to reflect new information or new insights on what works and not? 9432 9433 Is another decision contingent on a specific event happening? Have I evaluated the issue as it exists today? Is the underlying rationale for the decision still there? What new evidence is there that can 9434 change the likelihood? Does my way of measuring progress give any clue of what is likely to happen in the future? Events - relevant or irrelevant? Does it make any difference for my goal (independent of time 9435 horizon)? 9436 9437 Post mortem or learning from mistakes 9438 9439 How well did it or didn't it work out? Did I act? Did I do what I said? What did I think at the time? Original reasons compared to reality? 9440 9441 Why did I go wrong? How? Where? Opportunity cost? 9442 9443 How can I figure out if this is going to continue? Have I acted on my mistakes? How act to not repeat? What should I have done and didn't do? What should I concentrate on? What must I improve? What must I 9444 learn? 9445 9446 What exactly is the problem? 9447 9448 What do I want to achieve? Why don't I achieve my goal? What happen? How does it happen? Where does it happen and not? When does it happen and not? Who's affected? 9449 9450 What causes my goal? What interferes with the factors chat cause my goal? Symptoms or 9451 9452 293 9453 9454 core cause? What is the single most important limiting factor for reaching my goal? What principles or assumptions do I base this on? What are the consequences if they are wrong? Assuming no limitations, what 9455 would be the best course of action? Other consequences? 9456 9457 WHAT ARE THE LIKELY CONSEQUENCES CONSIDERING HUMAN BEHAVIOR? 9458 9459 What is causing me to do this? 9460 9461 What are my present environment and my state of mind? What is rewarding for me to do/say ifl want to avoid pain? What do I perceive to be the consequences for me? Are they painful or pleasurable? What 9462 psychological tendencies will influence me? Are they likely to cause a misjudgment? 9463 9464 What is the context? 9465 9466 What does the environment and participants (incl. size) look like? Who is the decision-maker and what are his criteria for making decisions? Who benefits and who pay? Who is responsible for outcome? Who and 9467 what are influencing the participant's perception of reality? 9468 9469 Can I judge him? 9470 9471 Can I judge his character? What are his experiences? What temporary or permanent characteristics influence him (age, cultural background, health, mood... )? What environmental (present internal and external) 9472 or situational factors influence him? Does he want to sell me something? 9473 9474 What is in his self-interest to do? 9475 9476 What is logical for him to do? What is rewarding for him to do ifhe want to avoid pain? What does he perceive as painful? What does he fear and why? What does he want more of or what does he not want to be 9477 taken away? What "resources" motivates him? His health, job, family, position, reputation, status, power? What would give him an incentive or disincentive? What reward or penalty system causes his behavior? 9478 What is he rewarded (perceived) for doing? What is he punished (perceived) for doing? How is he measured? How does he perceive the consequences of non-goal? Is it to his advantage/interest to believe (or not 9479 to believe) something? 9480 9481 What are the psychological tendencies and shortcuts that influence him and can cause misjudgment? 9482 9483 What bias affects his conclusions? What external influences is there, that will likely influence him? What temptations are there that appeal to his self-interest? What activates his behavior? 9484 9485 What are the consequences? 9486 9487 What are the consequences for me? Will my goal still be achieved? Is what is rewarding for him also rewarding for me? Is the system set up so that the relevant participant's interest coincides with my goal? 9488 Does it "pay him" to make the wrong decision? Does he understand 9489 9490 294 9491 9492 the consequences of his behavior? What are the short-and long-term consequences for him? What are the lines of responsibility? Does he have the responsibility for the consequences? What happens when others do 9493 the same? 9494 9495 What system would I like to have if the roles were reversed? 9496 9497 How would I like to be treated if the roles were reversed? What would cause me to do the things I want him to do? What are the behavioral tendencies I can use to change his behavior? How shall I behave ifl 9498 want to guarantee non-goal? Can I now turn around and avoid chose? 9499 9500 Is this the right system? 9501 9502 Can I appeal to his self-interest? Can I appeal to fear of losing reputation, money, status, family..? Can I change his present associations to pain? How can I organize the system to minimize certain 9503 influences? Have I cold him what I expect? Have I inspected what is done? Have I supported things done well? Does he have the necessary skills, knowledge and the relevant information? Does he know what is 9504 expected of him? Does he know the goal, how he will reach it and why that is the best path? Can he measure his progress? Is it related to his daily activities? Does he have the responsibility and the 9505 authority? Is his reward aligned with the goal? What rules can I install that will consider human weaknesses? Can I install a reverse rule? What changes must be made? Who will call for them? How likely is 9506 that? What are his values? His goals? What does he consider to be resulc? What is his perception of the consequences if he behave like we want him to and if he doesn't? 9507 9508 BUSINESS EVALUATION 9509 9510 Filter 1 - Can I understand the business - predictability? 9511 9512 - [3mReasons for demand [0m- How certain am I chat (and can explain why) people are likely to continue buy this type of product or service in the future? What has happened in the past and what is likely to happen 9513 in the future? Cyclically in demand? Capacity versus demand? 9514 9515 - [3mReturn characteristics [0m- Industry and company return characteristics and change over the last ten years? 9516 9517 - [3mIndustry structure [0m- No of competitors and size? Who dictate the terms in chis industry? What is needed to make money in chis industry? Position within the industry? Do I know who is going to make the money 9518 in this market and why? 9519 9520 - Real Customer- Who decides what to buy and what are his decision-criteria? 9521 9522 Filter 2 - Does it look like the business has some kind of sustainable competitive advantage? 9523 9524 - Competitive Advantage - How certain am I that (and can explain why) they are likely to buy the product or service from the company rather than from someone else? Are the reasons virtually unchanged from 9525 what they were ten years ago? Are these motivations likely to be unchanged over the next ten years? 9526 9527 - Value - How strong and sustainable is chis advantage? Have the advantages become stronger and more durable over the years? What can destroy or reduce them? Barriers to entry? Brand loyalty? Vulnerable to 9528 change in demand or prices? Easy to copy? Short 9529 9530 295 9531 9532 product life cycle? Customer cost and incentive to switch supplier? Annual cost differential against competition? Capital investments needed? Bargaining power? Obsolescence risk? New customer alternatives? 9533 Change in buying habits or power? Competitor potential to undercut prices assuming same cost structure? What is needed to make sure the advantages stay sustainable? Growth opportunities left? Is the demand 9534 for the product likely to grow? Untapped unit volume demand? Pricing power? 9535 9536 Profitability - Can the advantage be translated into profitability and why? How does the 9537 9538 company make money? How much capital is needed to produce incremental revenues? Financial characteristics-return on capital (operating margins and capital turnover), gross margins, sales growth, cost-and 9539 capital structure and efficiency? Normalized free cash flow? Advantages of scale? Critical variable? 9540 9541 Filter 3 - Able and honest management? 9542 9543 Is the management composed of competent and honest people that understands and focuses on creation of value? 9544 9545 Filter 4 - Is the price right? 9546 9547 Can I buy at a price that provides a good return with a huge margin of safety measured against other available alternatives and with evidence from facts and figures? 9548 9549 Filter 5 - Disprove 9550 9551 How can the business get killed? If the company could kill one of its competitors, who would it be and why? If the company would go away for 5 years which competitor would they bet on and why? How resistant 9552 is the business to adversity? Assume the company paid out all its equity capital, would it still have any value? Could someone with the access to billions of dollars and talent, successfully compete with the 9553 company? How much damage could a competitor do if he doesn't care about returns? Recession sensitivity? Execution risk? Will new technology help or hurt? 9554 9555 Filter 6 - What are the consequences ifl'm wrong? 9556 9557 296 9558 9559 - SOURCE NOTES - 9560 9561 Introduction 9562 9563 Page 9564 9565 11 "I think that I am... " Francis Darwin (editor), [3mThe Autobiography of Charles Darwin and Selected Letters, [0mDover Publications, New York, 1958, p.55. 9566 9567 Part One 9568 9569 Page 9570 9571 4 "The brain is the... " Gerald Edelman, [3mBrainMatters, [0mThe NeuroSciences Institute, Fall 2000. 9572 9573 7 "although in some sense... " Ralph Greenspan, [3mPerception, Selection and the Brain, [0mJournal of Neuroaesthetics, July, 2004. 9574 9575 7 "Isaac Newton might have... " Ralph Greenspan, [3mNature Reviews, [0mVolume 2, May 2001, p.386. 9576 9577 18 "In no sense... " Ra!ph Greenspan, [3mPerception, Selection and the Brain, [0mJournal ofNeuroaesthetics, July, 2004. 9578 9579 21 "Why should a man... " Charles Darwin, 1871, [3mThe decent of man, and selecion in relation to sex. [0mLondon: John Murray, 1st edition. Volume 1. Chapter IV (On The Manner of Development of Man from Some Lower 9580 Form). [3mFrom The Complete Work of Charles Darwin Online, [0mUniversity of Cambridge, Cambridge. http://darwin-online.org.uk/ 9581 9582 21 "powerful stimulus... " Charles Darwin, 1871, [3mThe decent of man, and selecion in relation to sex. [0mLondon: John Murray, 1st edition. Volume 1. Chapter V (On the Development of the Intellectual and Moral 9583 Faculties During Primeval and Civilised Times). [3mFrom The Complete Work of Charles Darwin Online, [0mUniversity of Cambridge, Cambridge. http:/ /darwin-online.org.ukl 9584 9585 23 "At the moment ... " Charles Darwin, 1871, [3mThe decent of man, and selecion in relation to sex. [0mLondon: John Murray, 1st edition. Volume 1. Chapter III (Comparison of the Mental Powers of Man and the Lower 9586 Animals). [3mFrom The Complete Work of Charles Darwin Online, [0mUniversity of Cambridge, Cambridge. http://darwin-online.org.uk/ 9587 9588 "At a small dinner gathering... " Lee Alan Dugatkin, [3mCheating Monkeys and Citizen Bees: The Nature of Cooperation in Animals and Humans, [0mThe Free Press, Simon & Schuster Inc., New York, 1999, p.101. 9589 9590 "Fear of disapproval is... " 59 words, p. 77 from [3mThe Ostrich Factor: Our Population Myopia, [0mby Hardin Garrett (1999). By permission of Oxford University Press, Inc. 9591 9592 Part Two 9593 9594 Page 9595 9596 45 "If the laws of... " 31 words, p. 61 from [3mThe Ostrich Factor: Our Population Myopia, [0mby Hardin Garrett (1999). By permission of Oxford University Press, Inc. 9597 9598 88 "His [Jones] masterstroke was... " Robert Cialdini, [3mInfluence: The Psychology of Persuasion, [0mQuill 9599 9600 William Morrow and Company Inc, New York, 1984,1993, p.156. 9601 9602 88 "In a country like... " Robert Cialdini, [3mInfluence: The Psychology of Persuasion, [0mQuill William Morrow and Company Inc, New York, 1984,1993, p.154. 9603 9604 88 "Have the courage... " Benjamin Graham, [3mThe Intelligent Investor: A Book of Practical Counsel, [0mHarper & Row, Publishers, New York, 1973, Fourth Revised Edition, p.287. 9605 9606 297 9607 9608 Part Three 9609 9610 Page 9611 9612 125 "A complex system... " Gerald Edelman, BrainMatters, The NeuroSciences Institute, Fall 2002. 9613 9614 132 ''As a colony grows... " 63 words, pp. 266-267 from Living Within Limits: Ecology, Economics, and Population Taboos by Hardin Garrett (1995). By permission of Oxford University Press, Inc. 9615 9616 152 "It is said to be... " Henry Howard Harper, The Psychology of Speculation: The Human Element in Stock Market Speculations, Fraser Publishing Company, Burlington, Vermont, 1966, p.44. 9617 9618 Part Four 9619 9620 Page 9621 9622 193 "If, in some cataclysm, all... ", Richard Feynman & Robert Leighton & Matthew Sands The Feynman Lectures on Physics, Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, Reading, Massachusetts, 1963, Sixth printing, 1977, 9623 p.1.2. Copyright by California Institute ofTechnology. 9624 9625 199 "See that bird?... " Richard Feynman, "What is Science?", The Physics Teacher, Vol. 7, Issue 6, pp.313-320, 1969. 9626 9627 199 "There is a picture... " Richard Feynman, "What is Science?", The Physics Teacher, Vol. 7, Issue 6, pp.313-320, 1969. 9628 9629 200 "the soles of your... " Richard Feynman, "What is Science?", The Physics Teacher, Vol. 7, Issue 6, 9630 9631 pp.313-320, 1969. 9632 9633 200 "Without using the... " Richard Feynman, "What is Science?", The Physics Teacher, Vol. 7, Issue 6, pp.313-320, 1969. 9634 9635 203 "If earnings not paid... " John Burr Williams, The Theory of Investment Value, Fraser Publishing 9636 9637 Company, Burlington, 1997 and originally published in 1938 by Harvard University Press, pp.57-58. 9638 9639 212 "You can't believe... " Noel Tichy and Ram Charan, "Speed, Simplicy, Self-Confidence: An 9640 9641 Interview with Jack Welch," Harvard Business Review, September-October 1989, p.112. 9642 9643 217 "In nearly every detective... " Albert Einstein & Leopold Infeld, The Evolution of Physics: The Growth of Ideas from Early Concepts to Relativity and Quanta, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1938, 9644 Reprinted 1978, p.4. 9645 9646 228 "In the department... " Claude Frederic Bastiat, That Which ls Seen, and That Which Is Not Seen, 9647 9648 http:/ /bastiat.org/ 9649 9650 239 "It does not make any... " Richard Feynman, The Character of Physical Law, The Modern Library, Random House, Inc., New York, 1965, 1994 Modern Library Edition, p.150. 9651 9652 239 "About thirty years ago... " Charles Darwin to Henry Fawcett (18 September 1861), Letter No. 133 in Francis Darwin (editor), More Letters of Charles Darwin, Vol. 1 D. Appleton, New York, 1903. 9653 9654 242 "I had also... " Francis Darwin (editor), The Autobiography of Charles Darwin and Selected Letters, 9655 9656 Dover Publications Inc, Mineola, New York, 1958, pp.45,52-53. 9657 9658 252 "Why do we complain ... " Seneca Lucius Annaeus, On the Shortness of Life, translated by John 9659 9660 W. Basore, Loeb Classical Library London, William Heineman, 1932, from The Forum Romanum, The Corpus Scriptorum Latinorum 9661 9662 256 "I rejoice that... " Francis Darwin (editor), The Autobiography of Charles Darwin and Selected Letters, Dover Publications Inc., Mineola, New York, 1958, pp.46,279. 9663 9664 Source notes - Charles Munger and Warren Buffett Introduction 9665 9666 Page 9667 9668 "All I want to... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 1996 Annual Report, p.9. 9669 9670 "I believe in the... " Lecture by CharlesT. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, p.63. 9671 9672 298 9673 9674 111 "I chink it's a huge... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, p.63. 9675 9676 Part One 9677 9678 18 "There was a great... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2004, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9679 9680 December 31, 2004, p.32. 9681 9682 "It's ego. It's greed... " Adam Smith's Money Game, Transcript #105, Air Date: May 15, 1998. 9683 9684 "I always look at. .. " Buffett &Gates on Success, KCTS/Seatcle, May 1998 transcript p. 4. 9685 9686 Part Two 9687 9688 Page 9689 9690 39 "I came to the... " Andrew Kilpatrick, Of Permanent Value: The Story of Warren Buffett, 9691 9692 Birmingham: AKPE, 2000, p.873. 9693 9694 39 "If you want co... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1991, Outstanding Investor Digest, May 24, 1991, p.32. 9695 9696 "We only give... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1995, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9697 9698 August 10, 1995, p.4. 9699 9700 "The iron rule of nature... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2001. 9701 9702 "The worst abuses ... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 1994, Outstanding Investor Digest, June 23, 1994, p.15. 9703 9704 "In the New York... Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2004, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9705 9706 December 31, 2004, p.45. 9707 9708 "From all business... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor Guilford Babcock at the University of Southern California School of Business on April 14, 1994, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9709 May 5, 1995, p.59. 9710 9711 "The food value... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, December 29, 1997, p.27. 9712 9713 "Well, che customer. .. " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to che students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, December 29, 1997, p.29. 9714 9715 "As you occupy some... " Wesco Financial Inc., 1990 Annual Report, (Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 9716 9717 Letters to Shareholders, 1987-1995, p.203.) 9718 9719 "Goals should be... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 1996 Annual Report, p.l 0. 9720 9721 "lc's very hard to change... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1998, Outstanding Investor Digest, September 24, 1998, p.55. 9722 9723 "An example of a... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1993, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9724 9725 June 30, 1993, p.29. 9726 9727 "without the help of... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1994, p.149. 9728 9729 "All commissioned salesmen ... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 1988, Outstanding Investor Digest, April 30, 1988, p.21. 9730 9731 "They were paid... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 1992, Outstanding Investor Digest, June 9732 9733 22, 1992, p.8. 9734 9735 "Mark Twain used to say... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1995, Outstanding Investor Digest, August 10, 1995, p.11. 9736 9737 52 "I have no use... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1995, Andrew Kilpatrick, Of Permanent 9738 9739 Value: The Story ofWarren Buffett, Birmingham: AKPE, 2000, p.l 074. 9740 9741 "I do not understand... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1994, Outstanding Investor Digest, June 23, 1994, pp.23-24. 9742 9743 "When they make... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1989, p.60. 9744 9745 53 "I would say that... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2002. 9746 9747 "I'd say chat... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2001, Outstanding Investor Digest, Year End 2001 Edition, p.24. 9748 9749 299 9750 9751 "We want the manager... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1998, Outstanding Investor Digest, September 24, 1998, pp.55-56. 9752 9753 "Any investor can ... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 1997 Annual Report, p.3. 9754 9755 "Arco was celebrating ... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2004, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9756 9757 December 31, 2004, p.51. 9758 9759 "Well if you stop... " The Psychology of Human Misjudgment, Talk at the Cambridge Center for Behavioral Studies, April 24, 1995. 9760 9761 'Tm not saying that... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1998, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9762 9763 September 24, 1998, p.54. 9764 9765 58 "It is remarkable... " Wesco Financial Inc., 1989 Annual Report, (Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1987-1995, p.196.) 9766 9767 58 "We won't do anything... " Lecture at Stanford Law School, March 23, 1990, Outstanding Investor Digest, April 18, 1990, p.14. 9768 9769 "What the human being... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2002. 9770 9771 "We do have a... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1995, p.162. 9772 9773 "We have very much... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 1989, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9774 9775 July 26, 1989, pp.6-7. 9776 9777 "I chink it was... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1998, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9778 9779 September 24, 1998, p.40. 9780 9781 65 "Heavy ideology is... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, p.47. 9782 9783 "We've done a... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2000, Outstanding Investor Digest, Year 9784 9785 End 2000 Edition, p.60. 9786 9787 "The most important. .. " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1990, p.74. 9788 9789 66 "Berkshire extracted a... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 1989, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9790 9791 July 26, 1989, p.9. 9792 9793 "Charlie and I believe... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1998, Outstanding Investor Digest, September 24, 1998, p.40. 9794 9795 "(A) You're facing deprival. .. " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, p.53. 9796 9797 "The deprival super-reaction... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, p.52. 9798 9799 "One reason why... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, p.52. 9800 9801 "Buffett: A very important ... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1995, Outstanding Investor Digest, August 10, 1995, p.6. 9802 9803 "In Captain Cook's... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, p.50. 9804 9805 72 "Predicting rain... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2001 Annual Report, p.9. 9806 9807 72 "It rook Noah... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1991, Outstanding Investor Digest, May 24, 1991,p.31. 9808 9809 75 "In my generation ... " The Psychology of Human Misjudgment, Talk at the Cambridge Center for Behavioral Studies, April 24, 1995. 9810 9811 75 "One of the problems... " 1994 Lecture ofThe E. J. Faulkner Lecture Series, A Colloquium with University of Nebraska-Lincoln Students by Warren E. Buffett, p.21. 9812 9813 80 "Three quarters of..." 1994 Lecture ofThe E. J. Faulkner Lecture Series, A Colloquium with University of Nebraska-Lincoln Students by Warren E. Buffett, pp.15-16. 9814 9815 84 ''As happens in... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1989, p.59. 9816 9817 "This friend, who ran... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1995, p.148. 9818 9819 "Most managers have very... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1984, p.96. 9820 9821 85 "Grown-up people... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 1995, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9822 9823 300 9824 9825 August 10, 1995, p. 62. 9826 9827 "We derive no comfort ... " Letter to partners, January 18, 1965. 9828 9829 "Techniques shrouded in... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1987, p.12. 9830 9831 92 "Around here... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1998, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9832 9833 September 24, 1998, p.49. 9834 9835 "His rule for all... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor Guilford Babcock at the University of Southern California School of Business on April 14, 1994, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9836 May 5, 1995, p.50. 9837 9838 "You can't really... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor Guilford Babcock 9839 9840 at the University of Southern California School of Business on April 14, 1994, Outstanding Investor Digest, May 5, 1995, p.49. 9841 9842 99 "The sad fact... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1994, pp.147-148. 9843 9844 "We hear a great... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1979, pp.20-21. 9845 9846 "We've got great... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2000, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9847 9848 December 18, 2000, p.60. 9849 9850 100 "There's no use... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1993, p.129. 9851 9852 104 "I have no stress... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2001, Outstanding Investor Digest, Year End 2001 Edition, p.46. 9853 9854 I 04 "All the businesses... " Warren Buffett interview, Outstanding Investor Digest, June 23, 1989, p.12. 9855 9856 105 "When you get two... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1991, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9857 9858 May 24, 1991, p.32. 9859 9860 105 "A very significant... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, pp.51-52. 9861 9862 106 "The psychological... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1993, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9863 9864 June 30, 1993, p.32. 9865 9866 "When people meet. .. " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2005, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9867 9868 March 9, 2006, p.55. 9869 9870 "Buffett: When certain boards... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting 1993, Outstanding Investor Digest, June 30, 1993, p.31. 9871 9872 "willingness to... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2003 Annual Report, p.9. 9873 9874 108 "In addition ... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2003 Annual Report, p.10. 9875 9876 108 "The correct system... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2005, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9877 9878 March 9, 2006, p. 56. 9879 9880 112 "I don't want to... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, p.55. 9881 9882 113 "I've gotten so that... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor Guilford Babcock at the University of Southern California School of Business on April 14, 1994, Outstanding Investor 9883 Digest, May 5, 1995, p.51. 9884 9885 113 "Take all the main ... " Lecture by CharlesT. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, pp.48-49. 9886 9887 114 "One of the things... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 1998, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9888 9889 December 29, 1998, pp.46-47. 9890 9891 Part Three 9892 9893 Page 9894 9895 120 "They had all... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2001, Wesco Special Report, Outstanding Investor Digest, OID.COM Edition, 2003, p.10. 9896 9897 121 "An excess of what ... " Charles T. Munger, speech at Miramar Sheraton Hotel, Santa Monica, CA, on October 14, 1998 to a meeting of the Foundation Financial Officer Group, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9898 1998 Bonus Edition. p.2. 9899 9900 301 9901 9902 125 9903 9904 'Tm all for fixing... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 1998, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 9905 9906 13, 1998, p.57. 9907 9908 126 9909 9910 "We try and predict..." Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2001, Wesco Special Report, 9911 9912 Outstanding Investor Digest, OID.COM Edition, 2003, p.l. 9913 9914 127 9915 9916 "We believe the... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 1996 Annual Report, p.9. 9917 9918 127 9919 9920 "Economics involves too... " Academic Economics: Strengths and Faults After Considering 9921 9922 Interdisciplinary Needs, Herb Key Undergraduate Lecture, University of California, Santa Barbara, 9923 9924 Economics Department, October 3, 2003, http://www.tilsonfimds.com/MungerUCSBspeech.pd£ 9925 9926 131 9927 9928 "The proposal should... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2004 Annual Report, p.8. 9929 9930 132 9931 9932 "Both we and our... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2001 Annual Report, p.14. 9933 9934 132 9935 9936 "In some businesses... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor Guilford 9937 9938 Babcock at the University of Southern California School of Business on April 14, 1994, 9939 9940 Outstanding Investor Digest, May 5, 1995, pp.52-54 9941 9942 134 9943 9944 "It is not necessary..." Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1994, p.147. 9945 9946 137 9947 9948 "For years it was... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier 9949 9950 at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, p.48. 9951 9952 145 9953 9954 "Catastrophe insurers... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1992, p.113. 9955 9956 146 9957 9958 "Even if perfection... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 1996 Annual Report, p.9. 9959 9960 146 9961 9962 "Given the risks... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1994, p.153. 9963 9964 146 9965 9966 "We do, though,... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1995, p.169. 9967 9968 146 9969 9970 "In setting prices and... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2001 Annual Report, p.8. 9971 9972 147 9973 9974 "No one knows... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2001 Annual Report, p.8. 9975 9976 157 9977 9978 "Here were 16 extremely... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1999, Outstanding Investor 9979 9980 Digest, December 31, 1999, pp.55-56. 9981 9982 160 9983 9984 "How many of these... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1999, Outstanding Investor Digest, 9985 9986 December 10, 1999, p.56. 9987 9988 160 9989 9990 "You may consciously... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1993, p.136. 9991 9992 160 9993 9994 "We expect all... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2000 Annual Report, p.7. 9995 9996 169 9997 9998 "If you're going... " The Psychology of Human Misjudgment, Talk at the Cambridge Center for 9999 10000 Behavioral Studies, April 24, 1995. 10001 10002 176 10003 10004 "People like to look... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1989, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10005 10006 June 23, 1989, p.9. 10007 10008 176 10009 10010 "Conditions relating to... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1992, Outstanding Investor 10011 10012 Digest, June 22, 1992, p.45. 10013 10014 176 10015 10016 "The same mistake... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1988, p.23. 10017 10018 177 10019 10020 "The water system... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 1990, Outstanding Investor Digest, June 10021 10022 28, 1990, pp.20-21. 10023 10024 179 10025 10026 "It is assumed by... " Wesco Financial Inc., 1989 Annual Report, (Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 10027 10028 Letters to Shareholders, 1987-1995, p.193.) 10029 10030 185 10031 10032 "You rend to forget. .. " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 1998, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10033 10034 December 29, 1998, p.50. 10035 10036 185 10037 10038 "Triumphs are trumpeted ... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2000 Annual Report, p. 10. 10039 10040 185 10041 10042 "Managers rend to... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1999, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10043 10044 December 31, 1999, p.60. 10045 10046 185 10047 10048 "Berkshire is basically... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1994, Outstanding Investor 10049 10050 Digest, June 23, 1994, p. 31. 10051 10052 Part Four 10053 10054 Page 10055 10056 189 "If you ask not... " Wesco Financial annual meeting 1999, Outstanding Investor Digest, December 31, 1999, p.37. 10057 10058 302 10059 10060 190 10061 10062 "If you get... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at 10063 10064 190 10065 10066 Stanford Law School, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mDecember 29, 1997, p. 25. 10067 10068 "Disney is an... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier at 10069 10070 191 10071 10072 Stanford Law School, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mMarch 13, 1998, pp.55-56. 10073 10074 'The models that come... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor Guilford 10075 10076 Babcock at the University of Southern California School of Business on April 14, 1994, 10077 10078 191 10079 10080 Outstanding Investor Digest, May 5, 1995, pp.50-51. 10081 10082 "In most messy human... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2000, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0m191 10083 10084 December 18, 2000, p.52. 10085 10086 "Suppose you want... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier 10087 10088 192 10089 10090 at Stanford Law School, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mDecember 29, 1997, p.26. 10091 10092 "If you don't... " Wesco Financial annual meeting 1999, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mDecember 10093 10094 192 10095 10096 31, 1999,p.40. 10097 10098 "Have a full kit... "Academic Economics: Strengths and Faults After Considering Interdisciplinary 10099 10100 192 10101 10102 Needs, Herb Key Undergraduate Lecture, University of California, Santa Barbara, Economics Department, October 3, 2003, http://www.tilsonfunds.com/MungerUCSBspeech.pd£ 10103 10104 "You get [3mlollapalooza ... " [0mLecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William 10105 10106 Lazier at Stanford Law School, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mDecember 29, 1997, p.25. 10107 10108 199 10109 10110 "Bad terminology is... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2001 [3mAnnual Report, [0mp.10. 10111 10112 201 10113 10114 "We use the... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1997, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mAugust 10115 10116 202 10117 10118 8, 1997, p.18. 10119 10120 "In the end... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2001, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mYear End 10121 10122 202 10123 10124 2001 Edition, p.37. 10125 10126 'These numbers routinely... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., [3mLetters to Shareholders, [0m1986, p.142. 10127 10128 202 10129 10130 "When companies or... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2001 [3mAnnual Report, [0mp.10. 10131 10132 203 10133 10134 "Trumpeting EBITDA... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2002 [3mAnnual Report, [0mp.21. 10135 10136 203 10137 10138 "If somebody's reinvesting... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1998, Outstanding Investor 10139 10140 203 10141 10142 Digest, September 24, 1998, p.36. 10143 10144 "Intrinsic value is an... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc.2001 Annual Report, [3mAn Owner's Manual, [0mp.67. 10145 10146 204 10147 10148 "Using precise numbers... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2000 [3mAnnual Report, [0mp.13. 10149 10150 204 10151 10152 "What you're trying to... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2002. 10153 10154 204 10155 10156 "Growth can destroy... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2000 [3mAnnual Report, [0mp.13. 10157 10158 204 10159 10160 "First, we try to... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., [3mLetters to Shareholders, [0m1992, p.117. 10161 10162 205 10163 10164 "We try... to keep... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2000 [3mAnnual Report, [0mp.14. 10165 10166 205 10167 10168 "take all of the... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2004, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0m205 10169 10170 December 31, 2004, p.34. 10171 10172 "If we're trying... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2004, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10173 10174 205 10175 10176 December 31, 2004, p.34. 10177 10178 "You'd try to ... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1994, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mJune 10179 10180 205 10181 10182 23, 1994, p.26. 10183 10184 "For our discount ... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1996, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0m206 10185 10186 August 8, 1996, p.28. 10187 10188 "And that discount... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1998, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0m206 10189 10190 September 24, 1998, p.36. 10191 10192 "We love owning... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2002 [3mAnnual Report, [0mp.16. 10193 10194 206 10195 10196 "We believe that... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1995, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0m206 10197 10198 August 10, 1995, p.12. 10199 10200 "We are very inexact. .. " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1990, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0m206 10201 10202 May 31, 1990,p.25. 10203 10204 "When we look... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1998, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mSeptember 24, 1998, p.37. 10205 10206 303 10207 10208 208 10209 10210 "If you and I..." Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1999, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10211 10212 December 10, 1999, p.48. 10213 10214 208 10215 10216 "I would say... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2005, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 10217 10218 209 10219 10220 9, 2006, p.60. 10221 10222 "One friend of mine... " 1994 Lecture ofThe E. J. Faulkner Lecture Series, A Colloquium with 10223 10224 University of Nebraska-Lincoln Students by Warren E. Buffett, p.6. 10225 10226 209 10227 10228 "My conclusion from... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1985, p.108. 10229 10230 212 10231 10232 "We have a passion... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2002. 10233 10234 212 10235 10236 We haven't succeeded ... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2005, Outstanding Investor 10237 10238 Digest, March 9, 2006, p.62. 10239 10240 212 10241 10242 "If something is... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2006. 10243 10244 212 10245 10246 "I generally try... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2006. 10247 10248 213 10249 10250 "Charlie and I decided... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1993, p.134. 10251 10252 213 10253 10254 "Part of that... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2004, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10255 10256 December 31, 2004, p.32. 10257 10258 213 10259 10260 "Yeah, we don't... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2004, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10261 10262 December 31, 2004, p.32. 10263 10264 213 10265 10266 "The harder you... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2006. 10267 10268 214 10269 10270 'Tm a follower... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2002, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10271 10272 December 31, 2002, p.38. 10273 10274 214 10275 10276 "There are things... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2002, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10277 10278 December 31, 2002, p.26. 10279 10280 214 10281 10282 "Easy does it. .. " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1989, p.62. 10283 10284 215 10285 10286 "We basically have... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1995, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10287 10288 August 10, 1995, p.20. 10289 10290 215 10291 10292 "I've heard Warren... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1997, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10293 10294 September 24, 1998, p.38. 10295 10296 215 10297 10298 "A... serious problem... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 1996 Annual Report, pp.15-16. 10299 10300 216 10301 10302 "I love focused ... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1996, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10303 10304 August 8, 1996, pp.24-25. 10305 10306 216 10307 10308 "There are two questions... " Berkshire Hathaway, press conference, May 2001. 10309 10310 217 10311 10312 "In allocating capital. .. " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 1998 Annual Report, p.12. 10313 10314 217 10315 10316 "If you feel like... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1996, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10317 10318 August 8, 1996, pp.23-24. 10319 10320 217 10321 10322 "A few major opportunities... " Wesco Financial Inc., 1996 Annual Report, p.6. 10323 10324 218 10325 10326 "Any time anybody... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor Guilford 10327 10328 Babcock at the University of Southern California School of Business on April 14, 1994, 10329 10330 Outstanding Investor Digest, May 5, 1995, p.62. 10331 10332 218 10333 10334 "What counts in this... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2001 Annual Report, pp.7-9. 10335 10336 219 10337 10338 "We really can... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1998, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10339 10340 September 24, 1998, p.48. 10341 10342 220 10343 10344 "Our definition of... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2000, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10345 10346 December 18, 2000, pp.39-40. 10347 10348 222 10349 10350 "Generally speaking... ", Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2002, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10351 10352 December 31, 2002, p.26. 10353 10354 225 10355 10356 "If you've got two... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1997, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10357 10358 August 8, 1997,p.16. 10359 10360 227 10361 10362 "Look for someone... " Meeting with Warren Buffett May 23, 2005 - University of Maryland 10363 10364 Student Trek to Omaha. 10365 10366 228 10367 10368 "The key thing... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1997, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10369 10370 August 8, 1997, p.23. 10371 10372 304 10373 10374 228 10375 10376 "All of the advantages... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor Guilford 10377 10378 Babcock at the University of Southern California School of Business on April 14, 1994, 10379 10380 Outstanding Investor Digest, May 5, 1995, p. 56. 10381 10382 229 10383 10384 "Many of our..." Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1985, p.108. 10385 10386 230 10387 10388 "If you're a captain ... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier 10389 10390 at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, pp.60-61. 10391 10392 231 10393 10394 "You've got a ... "Academic Economics: Strengths and Faults After Considering Interdisciplinary 10395 10396 Needs, Herb Key Undergraduate Lecture, University of California, Santa Barbara, Economics 10397 10398 Department, October 3, 2003, http:/ /www.tilsonfunds.com/MungerUCSBspeech.pdf. 10399 10400 232 10401 10402 "Leaving the question... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1992, p.116. 10403 10404 232 10405 10406 "While an increase ... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1985, p.109. 10407 10408 232 10409 10410 "return on beginning... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1980, p.27. 10411 10412 233 10413 10414 "Over the long term... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor Guilford 10415 10416 Babcock at the University of Southern California School of Business on April 14, 1994, 10417 10418 Outstanding Investor Digest, May 5, 1995, p.61. 10419 10420 233 10421 10422 "Examine the record... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2000 Annual Report, p.18. 10423 10424 233 10425 10426 "Finally, be suspicious ... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2002 Annual Report, p.21. 10427 10428 234 10429 10430 "A few years ago... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters to Shareholders, 1991, pp.94-95. 10431 10432 235 10433 10434 "Ofone thing, however. .. " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 1997 Annual Report, p.15. 10435 10436 237 10437 10438 "When we buy a stock... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2000, Outstanding Investor 10439 10440 Digest, December 18, 2000, pp.34-35. 10441 10442 237 10443 10444 "Value is destroyed ... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2000 Annual Report, p.14. 10445 10446 237 10447 10448 "There's plenty of magic..." Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting 1993, Outstanding Investor 10449 10450 Digest, June 30, 1993, p.37. 10451 10452 240 10453 10454 "... you have to have... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 1998, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10455 10456 December 29, 1998, p.47. 10457 10458 240 10459 10460 "The best judgment. .. " Warren Buffett from a speech at the Emory Business School as reported 10461 10462 243 10463 10464 in, "Track record is everything", Across the Board, October 1991, p.59. 10465 10466 'The mental habit of... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William 10467 10468 Lazier at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, December 29, 1997, pp.24. 10469 10470 244 10471 10472 "A lot of success... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2000, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10473 10474 244 10475 10476 December 18, 2000, p.60. 10477 10478 "If you were hired... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier 10479 10480 at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, December 29, 1997, p.24. 10481 10482 245 10483 10484 "Let's say you have... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier 10485 10486 at Stanford Law School, Outstanding Investor Digest, March 13, 1998, pp.51-52. 10487 10488 248 10489 10490 "The simple fact. .. " Robert Lenzner and David S. Fondiller, "The not-so-silent partner," Forbes 10491 10492 Magazine, January 22, 1996, p.83. 10493 10494 248 10495 10496 "When we look at... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2000, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10497 10498 December 18, 2000, p.43. 10499 10500 249 10501 10502 "the best way... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2004, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10503 10504 December 31, 2004, p.32. 10505 10506 249 10507 10508 "In stocks, we expect. .. " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2002 Annual Report, p.16. 10509 10510 249 10511 10512 "I had a relative... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2002, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10513 10514 December 31, 2002, p.28. 10515 10516 250 10517 10518 "If we can't... " Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 1996 Annual Report, p.9. 10519 10520 250 10521 10522 "We try to arrange... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2002, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10523 10524 December 31, 2002, p.33. 10525 10526 251 10527 10528 "If you understand... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1997, Outstanding Investor Digest, 10529 10530 August 8, 1997, p.17. 10531 10532 251 10533 10534 "Charlie drummed in... " Janet Lowe, Damn Right: Behind the Scenes with Berkshire Hathaway 10535 10536 305 10537 10538 253 10539 10540 Billionaire Charlie Munger, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 2000, p.54. 10541 10542 "You have to stick... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1993, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mJune 30, 1993, p.24. 10543 10544 253 10545 10546 "We'd rather deal... " Lecture by Charles T. Munger to the students of Professor William Lazier 10547 10548 at Stanford Law School, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mMarch 13, 1998, p.55. 10549 10550 254 10551 10552 "If you tell... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2004, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mDecember 10553 10554 31, 2004, p.42. 10555 10556 254 10557 10558 "More often we've... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2004, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mDecember 31, 2004, p.42. 10559 10560 254 10561 10562 "We think there... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2004, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mDecember 31, 2004, p.42. 10563 10564 255 10565 10566 "Good character is... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 1993, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mJune 30, 1993, p.29. 10567 10568 255 10569 10570 ''A person who... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2006 10571 10572 255 10573 10574 "You don't want... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2005, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mMarch 9, 2006, p.61. 10575 10576 255 10577 10578 "One of the things... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2005, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mMarch 9, 2006, p.61 10579 10580 255 10581 10582 "I think the best... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2004, [3mOutstanding Investor Digest, [0mDecember 31, 2004, p.50. 10583 10584 256 10585 10586 'The only way... " Berkshire Hathaway annual meeting, 2003 10587 10588 257 10589 10590 "I do think enthusiasm ... " Buffett & Gates on Success, KCTS/Seattle, May 1998 transcript p. 20. 10591 10592 257 10593 10594 "Do what turns..." Speech to University of Nevada students, 2006 10595 10596 257 10597 10598 "Don't look for... " Speech to University of Tennessee students, 2006 10599 10600 257 10601 10602 "Whenever you think... " Wesco Financial annual meeting, 2001, Wesco Special Report, 10603 10604 Outstanding Investor Digest, OID.COM Edition, 2003, p.20. 10605 10606 306 10607 10608 - BIBLIOGRAPHY - 10609 10610 Adams John, Risk, UCL Press, London, 1995 10611 10612 Allison Graham & Zelikow Philip, Essence Of Decision: Explaining the Cuban Missile Crisis, Addison- Wesley Educational Publishers, New York, 1999 10613 10614 Aronson Elliot, The Social Animal, W:H. Freeman and Company, New York, 1996 10615 10616 Asimov Isaac, Asimov on Physics, Avon Books, New York, 1976 10617 10618 Ayer A.J., The Problem of Knowledge, Penguin Books, Middlesex, England, 1956 10619 10620 Baars Bernard J, In the Theater of Consciousness: The Workspace of the Mind, Oxford University Press, New York, 1997 10621 10622 Badcock Christopher, PsychoDarwinism: The New Synthesis of Darwin & Freud, Flamingo, 10623 10624 HarperCollins, London, 1995, 1994 10625 10626 Bak Per, How NatureWorks: The Science ofSe/forganized Criticality, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1997 Baron Jonathan, Thinking and Deciding, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1988, 1994 Barrow John 10627 D., Impossibility: The Limits of Science and the Science of Limits, Oxford University Press, 10628 10629 Oxford, 1998 10630 10631 Bastiat Frederic, Economic Fallacies, Simon Publications, Safety Harbor, Florida, 1934, 2001 Bateson M., Nettle D., Roberts G., Cues ofbeing watched enhance cooperation in a real-world setting, The 10632 10633 Royal Society, Biology Letters, 2006, 2 10634 10635 Bazerman Max H.,judgment In Managerial Decision Making, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1998 Bell E.T, Men of Mathematics, A Touchstone Book, Simon & Schuster, New York, 1937, 1965 10636 10637 Belsky Gary & Gilovich Thomas, Why Smart People Make Big Money Mistakes - and How to Correct Them: Lessons From The New Science of Behavioral Economics, Simon & Schuster, New York, 1999 Beltrami Edward, What 10638 is Random: chance andorder in mathematics and life,Springer-Verlag, New York, 10639 10640 New York, 1999 10641 10642 Bennett, Deborah J., Randomness, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1998 Bernstein Peter L., Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story Of Risk,John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1996 Blank Robert H., 10643 Brain Policy: How the New Neuroscience Will Change Our Lives and Our Politics, 10644 10645 Georgetown University Press, Washington, D.C., 1999 10646 10647 Bloom Howard, The Lucifer Principle: A Scientific Expedition into the Forces of History, The Atlantic Monthly Press, New York, 1995 10648 10649 Bond Charles F. Jr. and DePaulo Bella M., Accuracy of Deception judgments, Personality and Social Psychology Review, 2006, Vol. 10, No. 3 10650 10651 Bonner John Tyler, Why Size Matters: From Bacteria To Blue Whales, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 2006 10652 10653 Boole George, An Investigation ofThe Laws ofThought on Which are Founded The Mathematical Theories of Logic and Probabilities, Dover Publications, New York, 1958, (Macmillan 1854) 10654 10655 le Bon Gustave, The Crowd: AStudy OfThe Popular Mind, Cherokee Publishing Company, Atlanta, 1982 Bostrom Nick, Anthropic Bias: Observation Selection Effects in Science and Philosophy, Routledge, New 10656 10657 York, 2002 10658 10659 Boyd Robert and Silk Joan B, How Humans Evolved, W.W. Norton & Company, New York, 1997 Brian Denis, Einstein: A Life, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1996 10660 10661 Brian Denis, The Voice of Genius: Conversations with Nobel Scientists and Other Luminaries, Perseus Publishing, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1995 10662 10663 Brocas Isabelle and Carrillo Juan D. (editors), The Psychology of Economic Decisions: Volume I Rationality and Well-Being, Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK, 2003 10664 10665 307 10666 10667 Brown Andrew, [3mThe Darwin Wtm: How Stupid Genes Became Selfish Gods, [0mSimon &Schuster, London, 1999 Brown Laurie M. and Rigden John (editors), [3mMost of the Good Stuff Memories of Richard Feynman, [0m 10668 Springer-Verlag, New York, 1993 10669 10670 Browne Janet, [3mCharles Darwin Voyaging: Volume Iofa Biography, [0mPimlico, Random House, London, 1995 Bunzeck N. and Duzel E., [3mAbsolute Coding of Stimulus Novelty in the Human Substantia Nigra/VTA, [0mNeuron 51, 10671 August 3, 2006 10672 10673 Burnham Terence and Hare Brian, [3mEngineering Human Cooperation: Does Involuntary Neural Activation Increase Public Goods Contributions?, June 2005, [0mIn press, Human Nature 10674 10675 Buss David M., [3mEvolutionary Psychology: The New Science of the Mind, [0mAllyn & Bacon, Boston, 1999 Caine Donald B., [3mWithin Reason: Rationality and Human Behavior, [0mPantheon Books, New York, 1999 Calvin William 10676 H, [3mHow Brains Think: Evolving Intelligence, Then and Now, [0mBasic Books, HarperCollins 10677 10678 Publishers, New York, 1996 10679 10680 Capen E.C., Clapp R.B. and Campbell WM., [3mCompetitive Bidding in High Risk Situations, journal of Petroleum Technology, [0m23,June 1971 10681 10682 Carroll Lewis, [3mThe Best of Lewis Carroll, [0mCastle, New Jersey 10683 10684 Casti John L, [3mParadigms Lost: Images of Man in the Mirror of Science, [0mWilliam Morrow and Company, NewYork, 1989 10685 10686 Casti John L, [3mSearching for Certainty: What Science Can Know About the Future, [0mAbacus, Little, Brown and Company, London 1993 10687 10688 Casti John L. [3mComplexification: Explaining a Paradoxical World Through the Science of Surprise, [0mAbacus, Little, Brown and Company, London 1994 10689 10690 Casti John L., [3mParadigms Regained: A Further Exploration of the Mysteries of Modern Science, [0mHarper Collins Publishers, New York, 2000 10691 10692 Caudill Edward, [3mDarwinian Myths: the Legends and Misuses of a Theory, [0mThe University of Tennessee Press, Knoxville, 1997 10693 10694 Cavalli-Sforza Luigi Luca, [3mGenes, Peoples, and Languages, [0mNorth Point Press, New York, 2000 Chernoff Herman & Moses Lincoln E., [3mElementary Decision Theory, [0mDover Publications, New York, 10695 10696 1959, 1986 10697 10698 Cialdini Robert B., [3mInfluence: The Psychology of Persuasion, [0mQuill William Morrow and Company, New York, 1984,1993 10699 10700 Cialdini Robert B., [3mInfluence: Science and Practice, [0mHarper Collins College Publishers, New York, 1993 10701 10702 Claxton Guy, [3mHare Brain, Tortoise Mind: Why Intelligence Increases When You Think Less, [0mThe Ecco Press, New Jersey, 1997 10703 10704 Coyne Jr. William F., [3mThe Case for Settlement Counsel [0mOhio State Journal on Dispute Resolution, Vol. 10705 10706 14, No.2, 1999 10707 10708 Crew Henry & de Salvio Alfonso (translators), [3mGalileo Galilei, Dialogues Concerning Two New Sciences, [0mDover Publications, Inc., New York, 1914, 1954 10709 10710 Damasio Antonio R., [3mDescartes' Error: Emotion, Reason, and the Human Brain, [0mHarperCollins Publishers, New York, 2000 10711 10712 Damasio Antonio R., [3mLookingfor Spinoza:Joy, Sorrow, and the Feeling Brain, [0mHarcourt Inc., Orlando, 2003 Darwin Charles, [3mThe Origin of Species, [0mGramercy Books, New York, 1979 10713 10714 Darwin Charles, [3mThe Expression of the Emotions in Man and Animals, [0mThird Edition, Oxford University Press, New York, 1998 10715 10716 Darwin Francis (ediror), [3mThe Autobiography of Charles Darwin and Selected Letters, [0mDover Publications, NewYork, 1958 10717 10718 David F.N., [3mGames, Gods and Gambling: A History of Probability and Statistical Ideas, [0mDover Publications, Mineola, New York, 1998 10719 10720 Dawes Robyn M., [3mPrediction of the future versus an understanding of the past: A basic asymmetry, [0mAmerican Journal of Psychology, Spring 1993, Vol. 106, No. 1 10721 10722 Dawes Robyn M., Everyday Irrationality: [3mHow Pseudo-Scientists, Lunatics, and the Rest of Us Systematical/,y Fail to Think Rationally, [0mWestview Press, Boulder, Colorado, 2001 10723 10724 308 10725 10726 Dawes Robyn M. Rational Choice in an Uncertain World: The Psychology ofJudgment and Decision Making, 10727 10728 Sage Publications, Inc. Thousand Oaks, California, 2001 10729 10730 Dawkins Richard, The Selfish Gene, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1976, 1989 Dawkins Richard, The Blind Watchmaker, Penguin Books, London, 1986, 1991 Dawkins Richard, Climbing Mount Improbable, Viking, 10731 Penguin Books, London, 1996 10732 10733 Dawkins Richard, River out of Eden: A Darwinian View of Life, Weidenfeld & Nicolson, London, 1995 Dawkins Richard, Unweaving the Rainbow: Science, Delusion and the Appetite for Wonder, Allen Lane, 10734 10735 Penguin Books, London, 1998 10736 10737 Deci Edward L, Why We Do What We Do: Understanding Self-Motivation, Penguin Books USA, New York, 1995 10738 10739 Dennett Daniel C, Kinds of Mind: Toward an Understanding of Consciousness, Weidenfeld & Nicolson, London, 1996 10740 10741 Dennett Daniel C, Breaking The Spell- Religion Asa Natural Phenomenon, Viking Penguin, New York, 2006 Diamond Jared, The Rise and Fall ofthe Third Chimpanzee, Vintage Books, Random House, London, 1991 Diamond 10742 Jared, Why is Sex Fun?: The Evolution of Human Sexuality, Basic Books, HarperCollins 10743 10744 Publishers, New York, 1997 10745 10746 Diamond Jared, Guns, Germs, and Steel: The Fates Of Human Societies, W.W. Norton & Company, New York, 1998 10747 10748 Dineen Tana, Manufacturing Victims: What the Psychology Industry is Doing to People, Constable and Company, London, 1999 10749 10750 van Doren Carl, Benjamin Franklin, Penguin Books USA, New York, 1938, 1966 10751 10752 van Doren Charles, A History of Knowledge: Past, Present, and Future, Ballantine Books, New York, 1991 Doyle Arthur Conan, The Adventures and Memoirs of Sherlock Holmes, The Modern Library, Random 10753 10754 House, New York, 2001 10755 10756 Dozier W. Rush, Fear Itself The Origin and Nature of the Powerful Emotion That Shapes Our Lives and Our World, St. Martin's Press, New York, 1998 10757 10758 Dreifus Claudia, Scientific Conversations: Interviews on Science from The New York Times, Times Books, Henry Holt and Company, New York, 2001 10759 10760 Dugatkin Lee, Cheating Monkeys and Citizen Bees: The Nature of Cooperation in Animals and Humans, 10761 10762 The Free Press, Simon & Schuster, New York, 1999 10763 10764 Dugatkin Lee, The Imitation Factor: Evolution Beyond The Gene, The Free Press, New York, 2000 Eccles John C., The Human Mystery: The GIFFORD Lectures University of Edinburgh 1977-1978, 10765 10766 Routledge & Kegan Paul, London, 1984, 1979 10767 10768 Edelman Gerald, Bright Air, Brilliant Fire: On the Matter of the Mind, Penguin Books, London, England, 1992 10769 10770 Edelman Gerald M., and Tononi Giulio, A Universe of Consciousness: How Matter Becomes Imagination, 10771 10772 Basic Books, New York, 2000 10773 10774 Edelman Gerald M. and Gally Joseph A., Degeneracy and complexity in biological systems, Proceedings National Academy of Sciences PNAS, November 21, 2001 Vol. 98, No. 24 10775 10776 Einstein Albert and Infeld Leopold, The Evolution of Physics: The Growth of Ideas from Early Concepts to Relativity and Quanta, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1938 10777 10778 Ekeland Ivar, Mathematics and the Unexpected, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1988. Eldredge Niles, The Pattern of Evolution, W.H. Freeman and Company, New York, 1999 10779 10780 Ehrlich Paul R., Human Natures: Genes, Cultures, and the Human Prospect, Island Press, Washington, DC, 2000 Englich B., Musswt;iler T., Strack F., Playing Dice With Criminal Sentences: The Influence of 10781 Irrelevant Anchors on Experts'judicial Decision Making, Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, Vol. 32, No. 10782 10783 2, February 2006 10784 10785 Fabian A.C. (editor), Evolution: Society, Science and the Universe, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1998 10786 10787 Feynman Richard & Leighton Robert & Sands Matthew, The Feynman Lectures on Physics, Addison Wesley, Reading, Massachusetts, 1963, 1964, 1965 10788 10789 309 10790 10791 Feynman Richard P, Six Easy Pieces: Essentials of Physics Explained by Its Most Brilliant Teacher, Helix Books, Addison-Wesley, Reading, Massachusetts, 1963, 1989, 1995 10792 10793 Feynman Richard P, Six Not-So-Easy Pieces: Einstein's Relativity, Symmetry, and Space-Time, Helix Books, Addison-Wesley, Reading, Massachusetts, 1963, 1989, 1997 10794 10795 Feynman Richard, The Character of Physical Law, The Modern Library, New York, 1965, 1994 Feynman Richard P & Leighton Ralph, "Surely You're joking, Mr. Feynman!": Adventures of a Curious 10796 10797 Character, W.W. Norton & Company, New York, 1985 10798 10799 Feynman P Richard, QED: The Strange Theory Of Light And Matter, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 1985 10800 10801 Feynman Richard P & Leighton Ralph, "What Do You Care What Other People Think?''.· Further 10802 10803 Adventures of a Curious Character, W.W. Norton & Company, New York, 1988 10804 10805 Feynman Richard P, The MeaningofitA!l: Thoughts ofa Citizen Scientist, Helix Books, Addison-Wesley, Reading, Massachusetts, 1998 10806 10807 Feynman Richard & Weinberg Steven, Elementary Particles and the Laws of Physics: The 1986 Dirac Memorial Lectures, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1987 10808 10809 Feynman Richard P, The Pleasure of Finding Things Out: The Best Short Works of Richard P. Feynman, 10810 10811 Helix Books, Perseus Books, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1999 10812 10813 Fishman Scott, The War on Pain: How Breakthroughs in the New Field of Pain Medicine Are Turning the Tide Against Suffering, HarperCollins Publishers, New York, 2000 10814 10815 Flyvbjerg B., Bruzelius N., Rothengatter W., Megaprojects and Risk: An Anatomy of Ambition, 10816 10817 Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2003 10818 10819 Flyvbjerg Bent, Policy and Planning for Large Infrastructure Projects: Problems, Causes, Cures, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3781, December 2005 10820 10821 Folkes J. and Morris P.W.G., Pharmaceutical drug development project management, in Morris P.W.G. and Pinto J.K. (editors). The Wiley Guide to Managing Projects, Hoboken, New Jersey, Wiley, 2004 Foster 10822 Kenneth R. and Huber PeterW.,judging Science: Scientific Knowledge and the Federal Courts,The 10823 10824 MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1997 10825 10826 Frank Robert H., Luxury Fever: Money and Happiness in an Era of Excess, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 1999 10827 10828 Freedman D.A. and Stark P.B., What is the Chance of an Earthquake, Department of Statistics, University of California Berkeley, Technical Report 611, 2003 10829 10830 Garnham Alan and Oakhill Jane, Thinking and Reasoning, Blackwell Publishers, Oxford, UK, 1994 GawandeAtul, Complications:ASurgeon's Notes on an Imperfect Science, Metropolitan Books, New York, 2002 Gazzaniga 10831 Michael S. (editor), Conversations in the Cognitive Neurosciences,The MIT Press, Cambridge, 10832 10833 Massachusetts, 1997 10834 10835 Gazzaniga Michael S., The Mind's Past, Universiry of California Press, Berkeley and Los Angeles, 1998 Gigerenzer Gerd, Todd M. Peter and the ABC Research Group, Simple Heuristics That Make Us Smart, 10836 10837 Oxford University Press, New York, 1999 10838 10839 Gigerenzer Gerd,Adaptive Thinking: Rationality in the Rea/World, Oxford University Press, New York, 2000 Gigerenzer Gerd, Calculated Risks: How To Know When Numbers Deceive You, Simon & Schuster, New 10840 10841 York, 2002 10842 10843 Gilbert Daniel T., How Mental Systems Believe, American Psychologist, Vol. 46, No. 2, February 1991 Gilbert D.T., Tafarodi R.W., Malone P.S., You Can't Not Believe Everything You Read, Journal of 10844 10845 Personality and Social Psychology, August 1993, Vol. 65, No. 2 10846 10847 Gilbert Daniel T., Stumbling on Happiness, Alfred A. Knopf, New York, 2006 10848 10849 Gilovich Thomas, How We Know What Isn't So: The Fallibility of Human Reason in Everyday Life, The Free Press, New York, 1991 10850 10851 Gilovich Thomas, Griffin Dale, and Kahneman Daniel (editors), Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive judgment, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom, 2002 10852 10853 Glassner Barry, The Culture of Fear: Why Americans Are Afraid of the Wrong Things, Basic Books, New York, 1999 10854 10855 310 10856 10857 Gleick James, [3mGenius: The Lift and Science of Richard Feynman, [0mVintage Books, New York, 1992 Gleick James, [3mIsaac Newton, [0mPantheon Books, New York, 2003 10858 10859 Godin Seth, [3mAll Marketers are Liars: The Power o/Telling Authentic Stories in a Low-Trust World, [0mPenguin Books Ltd, London, 2005 10860 10861 Goldberg Elkhonon, [3mThe Wisdom Paradox: How Your Mind Can Grow Stronger As Your Brain Grows Older, [0mPenguin Group Inc., New York, 2005 10862 10863 Goldratt Eliyahu M., [3mWhat is this thing called theory of constraints and how should it be implemented?, [0mNorth River Press, Great Barrington, Massachusetts, 1990 10864 10865 Goldsmith Timothy H., [3mThe Biological Roots of Human Nature: Forging Links between Evolution and Behavior, [0mOxford University Press, New York, 1991 10866 10867 Goldstein William M and Hogarth Robin M (editors), [3mResearch on judgment and Decision Making: Currents, connections, and controversies, [0mCambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1997 10868 10869 Goodstein David L. & Goodstein Judith R., [3mFeynman's Lost Lecture: The Motion of Planets Around the Sun, [0mVintage, Random House, London, 1997 10870 10871 Gould Stephen Jay, [3mWonderfol Lift: The Burgess Shale and the Nature of History, [0mWW Norton & Company, New York, 1989, Norton paperback 1990 10872 10873 Gould Stephen Jay, [3mFull House: The Spread of Excellence From Plato to Darwin, [0mThree Rivers Press, New York, 1996 10874 10875 Gower Barry, [3mScientific Method: An historical and philosophical introduction, [0mRoutledge, London, 1997 Graber M.L., Franklin N., Gordon R., [3mDiagnostic Error in Internal Medicine, [0mArch Intern Med/Vol. 10876 10877 165, July 11, 2005 10878 10879 Graham Benjamin, [3mThe Intelligent Investor: A Book of Practical Counsel, [0mHarper & Row, Publishers, New York, 1973 10880 10881 Greenfield Susan A, [3mThe Human Brain: A Guided Tour, [0mBasic Books, HarperCollins Publishers, New York, 1997 10882 10883 Greenspan Ralph J., [3mThe flexible genome, [0mNature Reviews, Vol. 2, May 2001 Greenspan Ralph J., [3mDarwinian uncertainty, [0mKronoscope 3, 2003 10884 10885 Greenspan Ralph J., [3mPerception, Selection and the Brain, [0mJournal ofNeuroaesthetics, July, 2004 Greenspan Ralph J. and van Swinderen Bruno, [3mCognitive consonance: complex brain fanctions in the fruit [0mfly and 10886 its relatives, Trends in Neurosciences, Vol. 27, No. 12, December 2004 10887 10888 Gribbin Mary & John, [3mRichard Feynman: A Lift In Science, [0mPenguin Books, London, 1997 10889 10890 Gribbin Mary & John, [3mBeing Human: Putting people in an evolutionary perspective, [0mPhoenix, Orion Books,London, 1993 10891 10892 Gribbin Mary & John, [3mIce Age, [0mThe Penguin Press, London, 2001 10893 10894 Gribbin John, [3mDeep Simplicity: Chaos, Complexity and the Emergence of Life, [0mPenguin Books Ltd., London,2004 10895 10896 Griffiths Paul E, [3mWhat Emotions Really Are: The Problem of Psychological Categories, [0mThe University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1997 10897 10898 Gullberg Jan, [3mMathematics: From the Birth of Numbers, [0mWW Norton & Company, New York, 1997 Haigh John, [3mTaking Chances: Winning with Probability, [0mOxford University Press, Oxford, 1999 Hallowell Edward M, [3mWorry: [0m 10899 [3mControlling It and Using It Wisely, [0mPantheon Books, New York, 1997 Hamer Dean and Copeland Peter, [3mLiving with Our Genes: Why They Matter More Than You Think, [0mBantam Doubleday Dell Publishing Group, New York, 10900 1998 10901 10902 Hardin Garrett, [3mFilters Against Folly: How to Survive Despite Economists, Ecologists, and the Merely Eloquent, [0mPenguin Books USA, New York, 1985 10903 10904 Hardin Garrett, [3mLiving Within Limits: Ecology, Economics, and Population Taboos, [0mOxford University Press, New York, 1993 10905 10906 Hardin Garrett, [3mThe Ostrich Factor: Our Population Myopia, [0mOxford University Press, New York, 1998 Harper Henry Howard, [3mThe Psychology of Speculation: The Human Element in Stock Market Speculations, [0mFraser 10907 Publishing Company, Burlington, Vermont, 1966 10908 10909 Hardy, G.H., [3mA Mathematician's Apology, [0mCambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1940, 1967 10910 10911 311 10912 10913 Hayward Matthew L.A. and Hambrick DC, Explaining the Premiums Paid in Large Acqusitions: Evidence of CEO Hubris, Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 1997 10914 10915 Hayward M.L.A.,Rindova V:P., Pollock T.G., Believing One's Own Press: The Causes and Consequences 10916 10917 of CEO Celebrity, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 25, No. 7, 2004 10918 10919 Hazen Robert M. and Trefil James, Science Matters: Achieving Scientific Literacy, Bantam Doubleday Dell Publishing Group, New York, 1991 10920 10921 Henriksen K., Kaplan H., Hindsight bias, outcome knowledge and adaptive learning, Qua! Saf Health 10922 10923 Care 2003;12 (Suppl II) 10924 10925 Hock R. Roger, Forty Studies that Changed Psychology: Explorations into the History of Psychological Research, Prentice-Hall, New Jersey, 1999,1995,1992 10926 10927 Hoffer Eric, The True Believer: Thoughts on the Nature ofMass Movements, Harper & Row, New York, 1951 Hoffman Paul, The Man who Loved only Numbers: The Story Of Paul Erdos And The Search For 10928 10929 Mathematical Truth, Hyperion, New York, 1998 10930 10931 Horgan John, The End of Science: Facing the Limits of Knowledge in the Twilight of the Scientific Age, 10932 10933 Broadway Books, New York, 1996, 1997 10934 10935 Horgan John, The Undiscovered Mind: How the Human Brain Defies Replication, Medication, and Explanation, The Free Press, Simon & Schuster, New York, 1999 10936 10937 Horner John R. and Dobb Edwin, Dinosaur Lives: Unearthing an Evolutionary Saga, Harcourt Brace & 10938 10939 Company, New York, 1997 10940 10941 Ioannidis, John, P.A., Why Most Published Research Findings Are False, PloS Medicine, August 2005, Volume 2, Issue 8 10942 10943 Ioannidis, John, P.A., Claims that do not replicate in medical trials, Presentation at the AAAS meeting, February 16, 2007 10944 10945 James William, The Principles of Psychology, Dover Publications, New York, 1890, 1918 10946 10947 James William, Selected Writings, Everyman, J.M. Dent, Orion Publishing Group, London 1995 Janis Irving L., Groupthink: Psychological Studies of Policy Decisions and Fiascoes, Houghton Millin 10948 10949 Company, Boston, 1982 10950 10951 Jeans James, Physics and Philosophy, Dover Publications, New York, 1981 10952 10953 Jin Ginger Zhe and Leslie Philip, The Case in Support of Restaurant Hygiene Grade Cards, Choices, 2nd Quarter 2005, 20(2) 10954 10955 Johnson Phillip E., Defeating Darwinism by Opening Minds, lnterVarsiry Press, Downers Grove, Illinois, 10956 10957 1997 10958 10959 Johnson Eric J. and Goldstein Daniel, Do Defaults Save Lives?, Science, 21 November 2003, Vol. 302 Jones Steve, Almost Like A Whale: The Origin Of Species Updated, TransWorld Publishers, London, 1999 Joung W, 10960 Hesketh B., Neal A., Using "War Stories" to Train for Adaptive Pe,formance: Is it Better to Learn 10961 10962 ftom Error or Success?, Applied Psychology: An International Review, 2006, 55 (2) 10963 10964 Joyce James M., The Foundations of Causal Decision Theory, Cambridge Universiry Press, Cambridge, 1999 Kahneman Daniel, Slovic Paul and Tversky Amos (editors),Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and 10965 10966 biases, Cambridge Universiry Press, Cambridge, 1982 10967 10968 Kahneman Daniel and Tversky Amos (editors), Choices, Values and Frames, Cambridge Universiry Press, Cambridge, 2000 10969 10970 Kardes Frank R., and Sanbonmatsu David M., Omission Neglect: the importance of missing information, 10971 10972 Skeptical Enquirer, March/April 2003 10973 10974 Kassin S., Meissner C., Norwick R., 'Td Know a False Confession if I Saw One''.· A Comparative Study of College Students and Police Investigators, Law of Human Behavior, Vol. 29, No. 2, April 2005 10975 10976 Keynes Randal, Annie's Box: Charles Darwin, his Daughter and Human Evolution, Fourth Estate, London, 2001 10977 10978 Kilpatrick Andrew, Of Permanent Value: The Story ojWarren Buffett, AKPE, Birmingham, 2000 Kindleberger Charles P., Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crisis, John Wiley & Sons, 10979 10980 Inc., New York, 1978, 1989, 1996, 2000 10981 10982 King Jerry P., The Art of Mathematics, Ballantine Books, New York, 1992 10983 10984 312 10985 10986 Klemm William R., Understanding Neuroscience, Mosby-Year Book, Inc., St. Louis, 1996 10987 10988 Kline Morris, Mathematics for the Nonmathematician, Dover Publications Inc., New York, 1967 10989 10990 Krauss Lawrence M., Fear Of Physics: A Guide for the Perplexed, Vintage, Random House, London, 10991 10992 1994, 1996 10993 10994 Kuhn Harold W and Nasar Sylvia (edirors), The Essential john Nash, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 2002 10995 10996 Kunda Ziva, Social Cognition: Making Sense of People, The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1999 10997 10998 Landes David, The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Wl:ry Some Are So Rich and Some so poor, WW Norton 10999 11000 & Company, Inc., New York, 1998 11001 11002 Laplace Marquis de, A Philosophical Essay on Probabilities, Dover Publications, Inc., New York, 1951. LeDoux Joseph, Synaptic Self How Our Brains Become Who We Are, Viking Penguin, New York, 2002 Lee Jeffrey 11003 A, The Scientific Endeavor: A Primer on Scientific Principles and Practice, Addison Wesley 11004 11005 Longman, Inc., San Francisco, 2000 11006 11007 Lerner J.S., Small D.A., Loewenstein G., Heart Strings and Purse Strings: Carryover Effects of Emotions on Economic Decisions, Psychological Science, Vol. 15, No. 5, 2004 11008 11009 Levinson Horace C, Chance, Luck and Statistics, Dover Publications, Inc., New York, 1939, 1050, 1963 11010 11011 Levie Stephen D., List John A., What Do Laboratory Experiments Tell Us About the Real World?, University of Chicago and NBER, 27 June 2006 11012 11013 Lewis H. W Why Flip a Coin: The Art and Science of Good Decisions, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1997 11014 11015 Lightman Alan, Great Ideas In Physics: The Conservation of Energy, The Second Law of Thermodynamics, The Theory of Relativity, and Quantum Mechanics, McGraw-Hill, New York, 2000 11016 11017 Lorenz Edward, The Essence Of Chaos, UCL Press, London, 1993, 1995 11018 11019 Lowe Janet, Damn Right!: Behind The Scenes With Berkshire Hathaway Billionaire Charlie Munger, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 2000 11020 11021 Loewenstein George, Hot-Cold Empathy Gaps and Medical Decision Making, Health Psychology, 2005, 11022 11023 Vol. 24, No. 4 (Suppl.) 11024 11025 Lowenstein Roger, Buffett: The Making ofan American Capitalist, Random House, New York, 1995 11026 11027 Lowenstein Roger, When Genius Failed: The Rise and Fall of Long-Term Capital Management, Random House, New York, 2000 11028 11029 Lynch Peter, One up on Wall Street, Simon & Schuster, New York, 1989 11030 11031 MacKay Charles, Extraordinary Popular Delusions & the Madness of Crowds, Crown Publishers, New York, 1980 11032 11033 Mahoney David and Restak Richard, The Longevity Strategy: How to Live to 100 using the Brain-Body Connection, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1998 11034 11035 Mandelbrot Benoit B., The Fractal Geometry of Nature, WH. Freeman and Company, New York, 1977, 1982, 1983 11036 11037 Mandler George, Human Nature Explored, Oxford University Press, New York, 1997 11038 11039 Manktelow Ken, Reasoning and Thinking, Psychology Press, Hove East Sussex, England, 1999 11040 11041 Margulis Lynn and Sagan Dorian, Acquiring Genomes: A Theory of the Origins of Species, Basic Books, New York, 2002 11042 11043 Marmot Michael, Status Syndrome: How Your Social Standing Directly Affects Your Health and Lift Expectancy, Bloomsbury Publishing Pie, London, 2004 11044 11045 Mayr Ernst, This Is Biology: The Science of the Living World, The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1997 11046 11047 Mayr Ernst, What Evolution ls, Basic Books, New York, 2001 11048 11049 McCloskey Donald M., The Art of Forecasting: From Ancient to Modern Times, Cato Journal, Vol. 12, 11050 11051 No. 1, 1992 11052 11053 McConnell James V. and Philipchalk Ronald P, Understanding Human Behavior, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich College Publishers, New York, 1992 11054 11055 Mehra Jagdish, The Beat ofa Different Drum: The Lift and Science of Richard Feynman, Clarendon Press, Oxford, 1994 11056 11057 313 11058 11059 Menzel R. et al. Honey bees navigate according to a map-like spatial memory, PNAS, February 22, 2005. Vol. 102, No. 8 11060 11061 Milgram Stanley, Obedience to Authority: An Experimental View, Harper and Row, New York, 1974 Milinski M., Semmann D., Krambeck HJ., Marotzke J., Stabilizing the Earth's climate is not a losing 11062 11063 game: supporting evidence from public goods experiments, Proceedings National Academy of Sciences PNAS, February 28, 2006 11064 11065 Miller David (editor), Popper Selections, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 1985 Minsky Marvin, The Society of Mind, Touchstone, Simon & Shuster, New York, 1985, 1986 Mitchell D.J., Russo 11066 J.E., Pennington N., Back to the Future: Temporal Perspective in the Explanation of 11067 11068 Events, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 2, 1989 11069 11070 Mlodinow Leonard, Feynman's Rainbow: A Search for Beauty in Physics and in Life, Warner Books, New York, 2003 11071 11072 Von Mises Richard, Probability, Statistics and Truth, Dover Publications, New York, 1957 11073 11074 Montaigne Michel de, The Complete Essays, translated by M.A. Screech, Penguin Books Ltd, London, 1987, 1991,2003 11075 11076 Moynihan Ray and Henry David, The Fight against Disease Mongering: Generating Knowledge for Action, 11077 11078 PloS Medicine, April 2006, Volume 3, Issue 4 11079 11080 Murphy Michael P. and O'Neill Luke A.J (editors), What is Life? The Next Fifty Years: Speculations on the Future of Biology, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1995 11081 11082 Myers David G., Social Psychology, The McGraw-Hill Companies, New York, 1983, 1987, 1990, 1993, 1996 11083 11084 Nesheim John, High Tech Startup: The Complete How-To Handbook for Creating Success.fa! New High 11085 11086 Tech Companies, 2000 11087 11088 Nesse Randolph M. and Williams George C., Why We Get Sick: The New Science of Darwinian Medicine, Vintage Books, Random House, New York, 1994, 1996 11089 11090 Newman James R.(editor), The World ofMathematics: Volume I-\17, Dover Publications, New York, 1956 Newman Mark E.J., Power laws, Pareto distributions and Zipf's law, Contemporary Physics 46, 2005 Newton, 11091 Roger G., The Truth Of Science: Physical Theories and Reality, Harvard University Press, 11092 11093 Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1997 11094 11095 Newton Roger G., Thinking about Physics, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 2000 Nicholson Nigel, Executive Instinct: Managing the Human Animal in the Information Age, Crown 11096 11097 Publishers, New York, 2000 11098 11099 Niven Ivan, Mathematics of Choice, or How to Count without Counting, The Mathematical Association of America, Washington, 1965 11100 11101 O'Hear Anthony, Beyond Evolution: Human Nature and the Limits of Evolutionary Explanation, 11102 11103 Clarendon Press, Oxford, 1997 11104 11105 Orkin Mike, What are the Odds: Chance in Everyday Life, W.H. Freeman and Company, New York, 2000 Packel Edward, The Mathematics of Games and Gambling, The Mathematical Association of America, 11106 11107 Washington, 1981 11108 11109 Paese Paul W., and Gilin Debra G., When an Adversary is Caught Telling the Truth: Reciprocal Cooperation Versus Self interest in Distributive Bargaining, PSPB, Vol. 26 No. 1, January 2000 11110 11111 Pascal Blaise, Pensees, translated by A.J. Krailsheimer, Penguin Books, London, 1966,1995 11112 11113 Paulos John Allen, Innumeracy: Mathematical Illiteracy and Its Consequences, Vintage Books, Random House, New York, 1988 11114 11115 Paulos John Allen, Beyond Numeracy: Ruminations OfA Numbers Man, Vintage Books, Random House, 11116 11117 NewYork, 1991 11118 11119 Paulos John Allen, A Mathematician Reads the Newspaper, An Anchor Book, Bantam Doubleday Dell Publishing Group, New York, 1995 11120 11121 Paulos John Allen, Once upon a number: The Hidden Mathematical Logic of Stories, Basic Books, New 11122 11123 York, 1998 11124 11125 Peirce Charles S., How to Make Our Ideas Clear, Popular Science Monthly 12, January 1878, pp.286-302 11126 11127 314 11128 11129 Peterson Ivars, The jungles of Randomness: A Mathematical Safari, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1988, 1998 11130 11131 Petroski Henry, To Engineer is Human: The Role of Failure in Successful Design, Vintage Books, Random 11132 11133 House, New York, 1992 11134 11135 Piattelli-Palmarini Massimo, Inevitable Illusions: How Mistakes of Reason Rule Our Minds, John Wiley 11136 11137 & Sons, New York, 1994 11138 11139 Pinker Steven, How the Mind Works, WW Norton & Company, New York, 1997 11140 11141 Pinker Steven, The Blank Slate: The Modern Denial of Human Nature, Viking Penguin, New York, 2002 Pious Scott, The Psychology of judgment and Decision Making, McGraw-Hill, New York, 1993 Pogarsky G. and 11142 Piquero A., Can Punishment encourage offending? Investigating the "resetting" effect, 11143 11144 Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency, 2003, 40(1) 11145 11146 Poincare Henri, The Value of Science: Essential Writings of Henri Poincare, The Modern Library, New York, 2001 11147 11148 Polya G, How to Solve it: A New Aspect of Mathematical Method, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 1948, 1988 11149 11150 Popper Karl R., The Open Universe: An Argument for Indeterminism, University Press, Cambridge, 1956, 1982, 1988 11151 11152 Popper Karl R., Quantum Theory and the Schism in Physics, Hutchinson Publishing Group, London, 1956, 1982 11153 11154 Popper Karl R., Objective Knowledge: An Evolutionary Approach, Clarendon Press, Oxford, 1972, 1979 11155 11156 Poundstone William, Prisoner's Dilemma, Bantam Doubleday Dell Publishing Group, New York, 1992 Poundstone William, Carl Sagan: a life in the cosmos, Henry Holt and Company, New York, 1999 Ramachandran V.S. 11157 and Blakeslee Sandra, Phantoms in the Brain: Probing the Mysteries of the Human 11158 11159 Mind, William Morrow and Company, New York, 1998 11160 11161 Ridley Mark (editor), Evolution, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1997 11162 11163 Ridley Matt, The Origins Of Virtue: Human Instincts and the Evolution of Cooperation, Penguin Books USA, New York, 1996, 1997 11164 11165 Ridley Matt, Genome: The autobiography ofa species in 23 chapters, Fourth Estate Limited, London, 1999 Ridley Matt, Nature Via Nurture: Genes, Experience, and What Makes Us Human, Harper Collins 11166 11167 Publishers Inc., New York, 2003 11168 11169 Rota Gian-Carlo, Indiscrete Thoughts, Birkhauser, Boston, 1997 11170 11171 Rothman Tony & Sudarshan George, Doubt and Certainty, Perseus Books, Reading, Massachusetts, 1998 Ruelle David, Chance and Chaos, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 1991 11172 11173 Russell Bertrand, Logic and Knowledge: Essays 1901-1950, George Allen & Unwin, London, 1956 Russell Bertrand, Russell's Best: Silhouettes in Satire, Routledge, London, 1958 11174 11175 Russell Bertrand, The Problems of Philosophy, Oxford University Press, Oxford, New York, 1959 11176 11177 Ryan Frank, Darwin's Blind Spot: Evolution Beyond Natural Selection, Houghton Mifflin Company, New York, 2002 11178 11179 Sagan Carl, The Demon-Haunted World: Science asa Candle in the Dark, Ballantine Books, New York, 1996 Sapolsky Robert M., Why Zebras Don't Get Ulcers: And Updated Guide to Stress, Stress-related Diseases, 11180 11181 and Coping, WH. Freeman and Company, New York, 1994, 1998 11182 11183 Sargant William, Battle For The Mind: A Physiology of Conversion and Brain-Washing, Malor Books, ISHK, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1997 11184 11185 Sawyer WW, Mathematician's Delight, Penguin Books Ltd., Middlesex, England, 1943 11186 11187 Schacter Daniel L., The Seven Sins ofMemory: How the Mind Forgets and Remembers, Houghton MifRin Company, New York, 2001 11188 11189 Schick Jr. Theodore and Vaughn Lewis, How to Think about Weird Things: Critical Thinking for a New Age, Mayfield Publishing Company, Mountain View, CA, 1995 11190 11191 Schwartz Barry, The Paradox of Choice: Why More is Less, HarperCollins Publishers Inc., New York, 2004 Schwed Fred Jr., Where Are the Customers' Yachts?: or A Good Hard Look at Wall Street, John Wiley & 11192 11193 Sons, New York, 1940, 1955, 1995 11194 11195 315 11196 11197 Schweid Richard, [3mthe cockroach papers: a compendium of history and lore, [0mFour Walls Eight Windows, New York, 1999 11198 11199 Segre Emilio, [3mEnrico Fermi Physicist, [0mThe University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1970 Segre Gino, [3mA Matter of Degrees, [0mViking Penguin, Penguin Putnam Inc., New York, 2002 11200 11201 Selmer Ricardo, [3mThe Seven-Day Weekend: A Better Way to Work in the 21st Century, [0mThe Random House Group Ltd., London, 2003 11202 11203 Seneca Lucius Annaeus, [3mOn the Shortness of Life, [0mtranslated by John W Basore, Loeb Classical Library London, William Heineman, 1932, from The Forum Romanum, The Corpus Scriptorum Latinorum 11204 11205 Shaw Patrick, [3mLogic and its Limits, [0mOxford University Press, New York, 1981, 1997 11206 11207 Shefrin Hersh, [3mBeyond Greed and Fear: Understanding Behavioral Finance and the Psychology of Investing, [0mHarvard Business School Press, Boston, Massachusetts, 2000 11208 11209 Shermer Michael, [3mWhy People Believe Weird Things: Pseudoscience, Superstition, And Other Confusions Of Our Time, [0mWH. Freeman and Company, New York, 1997 11210 11211 Shermer Michael, [3mThe Borderlands of Science: Where Sense Meets Nonsense, [0mOxford University Press, New York, 2001 11212 11213 Shermer Michael, [3mThe Science of Good and Evil: Why People Cheat, Gossip, Care, Share, and Follow the Golden Rule, [0mTimes Books, Heney Holt & Company, LLC, New York, 2004 11214 11215 Shiller Robert J., [3mIrrational Exuberance, [0mPrinceton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 2000 Shojania K.G., Burton E.C., McDonald K.M., Goldman L., [3mChanges in Rates of Autopsy-Detected [0mDiagnostic Errors 11216 Over Time, Journal of American Medical Association, June 4, 2003 - Vol. 289, No 21 11217 11218 Simon Herbert A., [3mModels of My Life, [0mThe MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1996 11219 11220 Singh Simon, [3mFermat's Enigma: The Epic Quest to Solve the World's Greatest Mathematical Problem, [0mWalker and Company, New York, 1997 11221 11222 Skinner, B.F., [3m"Superstition" in the pigeon, [0mJournal of Experimental Psychology, 38, 1948 Skinner B.F, [3mAbout Behaviorism, [0mVintage Books, Random House, New York, 1976 11223 11224 Slater P.J.B. and Halliday T.R. (editors), [3mBehaviour and Evolution, [0mCambridge University Press, New York, 1994 11225 11226 Slovic Paul, [3mThe Perception of Risk, [0mEarthscan Publications, London, 2000 11227 11228 Smitley Robert L., [3mPopu/,ar Financial Delusions, [0mFraser Publishing Company, Burlington, Vermont, 1963 Sober Elliott, [3mThe Nature of Selection: Evolutionary Theory in Philosophical Focus, [0mThe University of 11229 11230 Chicago Press, Chicago, 1984 11231 11232 Sober Elliott (editor), [3mConceptual Issues in Evolutionary Biology, [0mBradford Book, The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1994 11233 11234 Sokal Alan and Bricmont Jean, [3mFashionable Nonsense: Postmodern Intellectuals' Abuse ofScience, [0mPicador USA, NewYork, 1998 11235 11236 Sternberg Robert J., [3mThinking Styles, [0mCambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 1997 11237 11238 Stewart Ian, [3mNature's Numbers: The Unreal Reality ofMathematical Imagination, [0mBasic Books, New York, 1995 11239 11240 Stewart Ian and Cohen Jack, [3mFigments of Reality: the evolution oft he curious mind, [0mCambridge University 11241 11242 Press, Cambridge, 1997 11243 11244 Sutherland Stuart, [3mIrrationality: The Enemy Within, [0mPenguin Books, London, 1992 11245 11246 Swets J.A., Dawes R.M., Monahan J., [3mBetter Decisions through Science, [0mScientific American, October 2000 11247 11248 Sykes Christopher (editor), [3mNo Ordinary Genius: The Illustrated Richard Feynman, [0mW.W Norton & Company, New York, 1994. 11249 11250 Taleb Nassim Nicholas, [3mFooled By Randomness: The Hidden Role of Chance in Life and in the Markets, [0mTrade Paperback Edition, Random House, Inc., New York, 2005 11251 11252 Taleb Nassim Nicholas, [3mThe B/,ack Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable, [0mRandom House, Inc., New York, forthcoming 2007 11253 11254 316 11255 11256 Teger Allan I., Too Much Invested to Quit: The Psychology of the Escalation of Conflict, Pergamon Press, New York, 1980 11257 11258 Tenner Edward, Why Things Bite Back: Technology And The Revenge Of Unintended Consequences, 11259 11260 Vintage Books, New York, 1996, 1997 11261 11262 Thaler Richard H., The Winners Curse: Paradoxes and Anomalies of Economic Lift, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 1992 11263 11264 Thaler Richard H. (editor), Advances in Behavioral Finance, Russell Sage Foundation, New York, 1993 Thompson WC., Taroni F., Aitken C.G.G., How The Probability ofa False Positive Affects the Value of DNA 11265 Evidence, Journal of Forensic Sciences, Jan 2003, Vol. 48, No. l Paper ID JFS2001171_481 11266 11267 Train John, The Money Masters, Harper & Row, New York, 1980 11268 11269 Train John, The Midas Touch: The Strategies That Have Made Worren Buffett Americas Pre-eminent Investor, Harper & Row, New York, 1987 11270 11271 Trefil James, The Edge of the Unknown: 101 Things You Don't Know About Science And No One Else Does Either, Houghton Miffiin Company, New York, 1996 11272 11273 Trefil James, Are we Unique: A Scientist Explores the Unparalleled Intelligence of the Human Mind, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1997 11274 11275 Tudge Colin, The Time Before History: 5 Million Years of Human Impact, Touchstone Book, Simon & 11276 11277 Schuster, New York, 1996 11278 11279 Vogel Steven, Cats' Paws and Catapults: Mechanical Worlds of Nature and People, WW Norton & 11280 11281 Company, New York, 1998 11282 11283 Vyse Stuart A., Believing in Magic: The Psychology of Superstition, Oxford University Press, New York, 1997 11284 11285 de Waal Frans, Good Natured: the Origins of Right and Wrong in Humans and Other Animals, Harvard 11286 11287 University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1996, 1997 11288 11289 de Waal Frans, Our Inner Ape: A Leading Primatologist Explains Why Wt, Are Who Wt, Are, Riverhead Books, New York, 2005 11290 11291 Wainer W, Palmer S., Bradlow E.T.,A Selection of Selection Anomalies, Chance Magazine, Vol. 11, No. 2, Spring 1998 11292 11293 Waller John, Einsteins Luck: The Truth Behind Some of the Greatest Scientific Discoveries, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2003 11294 11295 Weaver Warren, Lady Luck: The Theory of Probability, Dover Publications, New York, 1963 11296 11297 Weiner Jonathan, Time, Love, Memory: A Great Biologist And His Quest For The Origins Of Behavior, 11298 11299 Alfred A. Knopf, New York, 1999 11300 11301 Wentworth Thompson, D'Arcy, On Growth and Form: The Complete Revised Edition, Dover Publications, Inc., New York, 1942, 1992 11302 11303 White Michael, Isaac Newton: The Last Sorcerer, Helix Books, Addison-Wesley Reading, Massachusetts, 1997 11304 11305 White Michael, Leonardo: The First Scientist, Little, Brown and Company, London, 2000 White Michael and Gribbin John, Darwin: A Life in Science, Simon & Schuster, London, 1995 11306 11307 Whitehead Alfred North, The Aims of Education and Other Essays, The Free Press, New York, 1929, 1957 11308 11309 Williams John Burr, The Theory of Investment Value, Fraser Publishing Company, Burlington, 1997 and originally published in 1938 by Harvard University Press 11310 11311 Wills Christopher, Children of Prometheus, The Accelerating Pace of Human Evolution, Perseus Books, 11312 11313 Reading Massachusetts, 1998 11314 11315 Wilson Edward 0, In Search of Nature, Island Press, Washington D.C., 1996 11316 11317 Wilson Edward 0, Consilience: The Unity of Knowledge, Alfred A. Knopf, New York, 1998 11318 11319 Wolf Robert S., Proof Logic, and Conjecture: The Mathematicians Toolbox, WH. Freeman and Company, New York, 1998 11320 11321 Wolfson Richard, Simply Einstein: Relativity Demystified, W.W. Norton & Company, New York, 2003 11322 11323 317 11324 11325 Wright Robert, [3mThe Mora/Animal: Evolutionary Psychology and Everyday Life, [0mAbacus, Little Brown and Company, London, 1994, 1996 11326 11327 Yoerg Sonja, [3mClever asa Fox: Animal Intelligence and What It Can Teach Us About Ourselves, [0mBloomsbury Publishing, New York, 2001 11328 11329 Zeckhauser Richard J. (editor), [3mStrategy and Choice, [0mThe MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1991 Zimbardo Philip G, [3mThe Stanford Prison Experiment: A Simulation Study of the Psychology of [0mImprisonment, 11330 www.prisonexp.org 11331 11332 Berkshire Hathaway Inc., Letters ro Shareholders 1977-1986, 1987-1995, Annual Reports 1996-2006 Cardozo Law Review, [3mThe Essays ofWarren Buffett: Lessons for Corporate America, [0mVolume 19, Sept.-Nov. 1997 11333 Numbers 1-2 11334 11335 Daedalus, Journal of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences, Spring 1998, The Brain 11336 11337 The Complete Work of Charles Darwin Online, University of Cambridge, Cambridge, http://darwin online.org. uk/ 11338 11339 The Global Deception Research Team, [3mA World of Lies, [0mJournal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, Vol. 37, No. 1, 2006 11340 11341 Program on [3mInvestment Decisions and Behavioral Finance [0mat John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University 11342 11343 Mayoclinic.com 11344 11345 National Research Council, [3mCompleting the Forecast: Characterizing and Communicating Uncertainty for Better Decisions using Weather and Climate Forecasts, [0m2006, www.nap.edu/catalog/l1699.html 11346 11347 The Neurosciences Institute, Scientific Report and Catalog, 1981-2001 11348 11349 The Neurosciences Institute, Scientific Report, June 2004 11350 11351 Outstanding Investor Digest 1988 - 2006. 11352 11353 The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences: Advanced information on the Prize in Economic Sciences 2002, [3mFoundations of Behavioral and Experimental Economics: Daniel Kahneman and Vernon Smith [0m318 11354